1. Introduction
Forestry encompasses economic activities and social initiatives that are based on forest resources, including forest cultivation, protection, management, utilization, and associated ecological services. Its core components are forest cultivation, resource conservation, sustainable use, and ecological services. Forestry serves as a vital sector with ecological, economic, and social functions. It is a key component of terrestrial ecosystems and an essential industry for sustainable economic development.
In 2023, China’s GDP (gross domestic product, a concept introduced by Simon Smith Kuznets in 1934 [
1]) increased by 5.20%, which is below the average growth rate of 6.60% between 2016 and 2019 and significantly lower than the 10.60% growth rate in 2010. Meanwhile, the total output value of China’s forestry sector grew by 2.72%, trailing behind the average growth rate of 6.69% between 2016 and 2019 and the 3.50% growth rate in 2010.
The reasons are complex, but from the perspective of demand, the slowdown is primarily due to insufficient demand for economic development [
2]. The three main drivers of economic growth—investment, consumption, and net exports—have all encountered problems. These include declines in external demand and investment due to changes in the global economic environment, relatively low consumption levels among urban residents, and suboptimal investment returns. Meanwhile, on the production front, China’s position as the world’s second-largest economy contrasts with pervasive domestic industrial overcapacity and deepening structural imbalances across manufacturing sectors.
We must closely link the adjustment of the industrial production structure with the changes in the three key drivers of demand: investment, consumption, and net exports. Understanding the dynamic interplay and underlying mechanisms between these two aspects is crucial. Statistical analysis should be used to examine how shifts in investment, consumption, and net exports influence the restructuring of industrial production. This process also highlights the necessity for optimizing and upgrading the industrial production structure to meet the evolving demands of investment, consumption, and net exports. Similarly, by analyzing the patterns of change between these factors, we can explore the quantitative relationships and intrinsic mechanisms governing the interactive changes between China’s final demand structure and the forestry industry production structure. To achieve this, we will design three scenarios for simulation analysis, derive conclusions, and propose targeted strategies. This approach is of great theoretical and practical significance for strategically adjusting the production structure of China’s forestry and forestry industry chain as well as for effectively regulating the structure of investment, consumption, and net exports.
The conceptual distinction between final and intermediate products, foundational to modern GDP accounting, originated with American economist Simon Smith Kuznets’ 1930s national income accounting framework design, which explicitly segregated these categories to accurately capture national economic output and aggregate demand [
3]. Building on this foundation, Paul A. Samuelson’s seminal textbook
Economics systematically operationalized these concepts, defining final products as goods and services directly consumed or invested for end-use (e.g., automobiles purchased by consumers) versus intermediate products, which serve as production inputs (e.g., tires sold to automakers), thereby crystallizing analytical boundaries essential for macroeconomic measurement [
4]. Tang Wenli asserts that demand factors in national economic operations constitute a central focus of macroeconomic research. Demand growth drives production expansion through multiplier effects, functioning as the primary engine for economic development. From the expenditure perspective, GDP reflects the summation of final demand components—consumption, investment, and net exports. Hence, economists metaphorically term these three elements as the three engines propelling GDP growth, vividly encapsulating fundamental growth mechanisms. The balance of their proportional relationships critically determines economic stability and sustainable development [
5]. The American development economist Hollis Chenery (1975) applied a structuralist analytical approach, proposing a dynamic interdependence among investment, consumption, and economic growth throughout the industrialization process. Through comparative studies of developmental trajectories across nations, he demonstrated that during industrialization, the investment rate undergoes a cyclical evolution: initially rising from low to high, subsequently declining from the peak, and eventually stabilizing. For the majority of countries, upon attaining middle-income status, accelerated upgrading of consumption structures coupled with rising consumption rates transforms consumption into the primary engine propelling economic growth [
6]. Li Zhanfeng et al. posit that both input–output analysis and the demand-pull theory fundamentally demonstrate an intrinsic linkage between demand and economic growth, wherein demand stimulation serves as a viable catalyst for economic growth under specific conditions. Regarding the dynamic interactions among investment, consumption, and net exports, their research reveals a short-term trade-off: increases in investment typically result in contractive pressures on consumption, while increased consumption simultaneously generates inhibitory effects on investment. Over extended periods, however, investment growth exhibits cumulative effects—not only stimulating expansion in both consumption and net exports but also establishing a self-reinforcing cycle where increased consumption and export surpluses reciprocally drive further investment demand [
7]. Han Wenxiu argues that despite the substantial scale of consumption in China, its share in the national economy and aggregate demand remains relatively low, lagging approximately 20 percentage points behind that of developed countries [
8]. Li Chunding and colleagues’ analysis of the tripartite demand composition in the United States reveals three structural characteristics: Consumption demonstrates service dominance, with nondurable goods expenditures marginally exceeding durable goods. Investment exhibits private-sector predominance, where private capital formation substantially outweighs public investment. Exports maintain stable merchandise trade leadership. Among these demand components, consumption constitutes the largest GDP share. However, growth contribution rankings present a paradox: export expansion surpasses consumption in driving economic growth, which in turn exceeds investment’s developmental impetus [
9]. Hor et al. analyzed Cambodia’s import demand, identifying final consumption expenditure and export volume as significant determinants of import levels in both short- and long-term frameworks [
10]. Ivanova et al. employed a vector error correction model (VECM) to examine Bulgarian import behavior, establishing causal relationships among consumption, investment, and import demand driven by exports [
11].
The conceptual evolution of industry chains traces back to foundational economic theories. Adam Smith, the British classical economist, pioneered this intellectual trajectory in The Wealth of Nations by demonstrating how specialized labor division enhances productive efficiency, reduces costs, and stimulates economic expansion through coordinated production stages [
12]. Albert Otto Hirschman, the German development economist, advanced this paradigm in his 1958 treatise The Strategy of Economic Development, systematically articulating “forward linkages” (output utilization by downstream sectors) and “backward linkages” (input procurement from upstream sectors). His investment prioritization theory posits that strategic capital allocation in pivotal industries catalyzes vertical industrial integration, thereby forming cohesive production chains [
13]. Michael E. Porter of Harvard Business School redefined this framework through his 1985 Competitive Advantage introduction of the “value chain” concept, which conceptualizes manufacturing processes as sequential value-adding activities along production networks [
14]. Yan Feng et al. argue that the forestry industry chain is a complex and multidimensional system, encompassing various aspects, including technology, economics, and sustainability [
15].
According to the Swedish researcher Dick Carlsson, supply chain management and optimization are becoming increasingly crucial in the forestry sector. The entire wood flow starts with standing timber in the forest and progresses through felling, bucking, sorting, and transportation to terminals, sawmills, pulp mills, paper mills, and heating plants. Here, it is converted into products such as pulp, paper, and timber, eventually reaching a diverse range of customers. A multitude of planning challenges emerge along this supply chain, encompassing various time frames. Coordinating this wood flow is a top priority for many companies [
16]. Yang Jiameng and colleagues posit that the evolutionary dynamics of forestry value chains emerge through three interdependent mechanisms: (1) Specialized labor allocation stratifies the chain into germplasm cultivation and silvicultural management (upstream), midstream processing nodes, and downstream logistics and distribution sectors, creating an indispensable symbiotic network. (2) Embedded within market economies, production configurations dynamically reconfigure in response to market demand signals. (3) The biological attributes of forest products necessitate vertically constrained partnerships across the chain, where changes in any node trigger systemic adaptations through tight technological coupling [
17]. This study defines the industrial chain as a structured network of intermediate product transactions between upstream and downstream sectors under specific economic and technological conditions, characterized by interdependent supply–demand relationships. The forestry industrial chain specifically embodies this framework through bidirectional market linkages: procuring inputs from external industries for forestry production activities while distributing forest products through downstream channels, forming vertically integrated value-adding pathways.
Methodologically, Áine NíDhubháin (Ireland) conceptualizes input–output models as analytical frameworks structured through tabular data matrices capturing the economic structure of a nation or region at specific points in time. In monetary terms, these matrices quantify the intricate flows of production inputs and corresponding outputs across sectors, thereby explicitly delineating interindustry linkages through rigorous mathematical formalization [
18]. F. Duchin’s industrial economics paradigm employs multidimensional methodologies to decode complex interactions within industrial ecosystems and their extended socioeconomic–environmental ramifications. Crucially, Duchin advances input–output analysis through dynamic evolutionary modeling, enabling systematic assessment of cumulative economic impacts from industrial transformations across macro systems [
19].
Luís Cruz and his colleagues in Portugal have noted that macroeconomic evaluations of forestry generally concentrate on the production, harvesting, and primary processing of wood products. This focus tends to undervalue the full economic impact of forests on regional economies. Their work proposes a broader framework: the forestry product value chain, which takes into account the contributions of downstream activities that rely directly and indirectly on forestry and afforestation. Using a multiregional input–output framework, they applied this approach to the Portuguese economy. Their research findings highlight the significance of eucalyptus in the pulp, paper and cardboard, and paper and hardboard products sectors. The study concludes with an assessment of the wider macroeconomic ramifications of reduced output in these sectors [
20].
Shen Lisheng (China) theorizes that the compositional dynamics of final demand (consumption, investment, exports) exhibit intrinsic structural couplings with trisectoral industrial configurations. His framework posits final demand structure as the proximate determinant of industrial structure formation, where demand-side reconfiguration directly propagates structural transformations across production systems. Operationally, input–output models anchored in sectoral transaction tables provide the empirical nexus for analyzing these demand-structure interdependencies [
21]. A.V. Cherniavsky has emphasized that the primary use of input-output models lies in analyzing and predicting how changes in the volume and structure of final consumption affect the production structure [
22]. Ye Hengjiang et al. utilized the OECD-ICIO (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development—intercountry Input–Output) database and applied a set of connected global value chain (GVC) methods to assess the upstream and downstream positions of China’s forestry industry [
23]. Shuya Wang et al. developed a multi-objective sustainable closed-loop supply chain network planning model to study a real case of the forestry supply chain in Northeast China [
24].
In the academic exploration of forestry’s contribution to economic development, scholars in China have predominantly concentrated on the multifaceted contributions of the forestry supply chain. Their research underscores the significance of forestry within global value chains, the dynamics of import and export activities, and the refinement of domestic-value-added calculations. Conversely, academic research in the United States has predominantly focused on the role of the US forestry sector within the global supply chain framework. This research stream prioritizes the analysis of trade imbalances and the sustainable management of forest resources. For example, Poudel and Dahal (2025) contend that the US forestry industry has exhibited uneven developmental patterns within the forestry supply chain, highlighting the challenges confronting specific subsectors, such as the decline observed in the wooden office furniture manufacturing industry [
25].
Applications of input–output analysis to forestry industrial chains have been limited in prior scholarly research. Jiang Yeheng et al.’s analysis [
26] of global input–output data demonstrates that China’s forestry sector exhibited the highest upstreamness and downstreamness indices among major economies in 2014, indicating a greater systemic distance from both final demand and primary inputs within the production ecosystem. This dual centrality manifests through two operational dimensions: extensive utilization of forestry outputs as intermediate inputs across industries, coupled with substantial intermediate input absorption from multiple sectors during production processes [
26]. In foundational research, Hussain Anwar’s 1996 University of Minnesota doctoral dissertation leveraged Minnesota’s 1977 and 1990 input–output tables to quantify intersectoral linkages between forest industries and broader economic systems. Through output growth decomposition, the study identified sectoral contributory weights and developed experimental frameworks with variable parameterization, enabling systematic evaluation of economic–environmental trade-offs under alternative forest product demand scenarios [
27]. Brian M. Cox and Ian A. Munn (2001) employed the IMPLAN input–output framework to compare the forest industry’s economic contributions in the U.S. South and the Pacific Northwest. Their study quantified the overall economic impacts and calculated, per additional dollar of forest-industry output, the marginal effects on regional gross output, employment, personal income, and value added. They further examined how shifts in the demand for timber products influence regional economies, thereby providing a precise assessment of the effects of national timber-harvest policy changes [
28].The present study’s methodological innovation lies in the systematic integration of final demand composition and industrial structure dynamics, employing structural decomposition analysis to quantify how China’s evolving demand structures reconfigure forestry production frameworks and industrial chain architectures. To the best of our knowledge, this represents the first scholarly endeavor bridging these analytical dimensions within forestry economics, constituting a novel inquiry into demand-driven structural changes in silvicultural systems.
Methodologically, this study departs from prior research by grounding its analysis in the theories of interindustry linkages and input–output analysis. Utilizing input–output methods and data, the input and distribution coefficients were calculated for the forestry sector based on the 2018 China Input–Output Table (153 sectors) and other value-based data from the National Bureau of Statistics [
29,
30]. This approach facilitates an in-depth examination of the forward and backward linkages within China’s forestry production. Furthermore, the input–output model was employed to design and simulate three distinct scenarios. The research involved a comprehensive assessment of how structural shifts in consumption, investment, and net export demand compositions reconfigure forestry production and industrial chain dynamics. The article provides a thorough analysis of how shifts in China’s demand structure—specifically in consumption, investment, and net exports—affect the forestry sector and the forestry industry chain, ultimately reaching well-supported conclusions.
Calculations and analyses were carried out to answer the following questions:
- (1)
Which industrial sectors are encompassed in the backward and forward linkages of China’s forestry industry?
- (2)
How has the quantitative composition of China’s final demand evolved?
- (3)
What is the current state of the production structure within China’s forestry industry chain?
- (4)
How does the production structure of China’s forestry industry chain quantitatively respond to shifts in demand structure?
- (5)
What are the proposed key areas for improvement?
4. Discussion
The structure of final demand shapes the production structure of industries. Investment changes can spur capital formation and technological upgrades across sectors, expand upstream industry chains, and boost employment and income levels, which in turn indirectly stimulate consumer demand and production. However, such changes may also lead to overcapacity and misallocation of resources, thereby reducing economic efficiency.
Variations in consumption directly drive the expansion of production scales. Upgraded consumption patterns can facilitate structural optimization and drive economic development from the demand side. Conversely, weak consumption can negatively impact production development.
An increase in exports can directly expand domestic production scales, while an increase in the import of raw materials or components can ensure the stability of domestic production chains and drive domestic economic development through external demand. However, negative shocks can occur; for example, the US–China trade war may restrict imports and exports, thereby disrupting the smooth operation of industry chains.
In light of these dynamics, we should optimize and adjust China’s final product structure in response to changes in market demand to promote the development of forestry production. Final demand structures fundamentally shape industrial production patterns, necessitating strategic alignment of China’s final goods composition with evolving market demand to drive socioeconomic development.
First, consumption exerts a slightly weaker influence on forestry output than investment. A rise in consumption increases demand for forestry intermediates, benefiting the agriculture-forestry-animal-husbandry-fishery services sector and the broader forestry industry. Although the marginal effect of consumption is smaller—evidenced by differing intermediate-goods elasticities (a one-percentage-point increase in the consumption share lifts forestry-chain intermediates by 1.86%, compared with 2.20% under an equivalent investment expansion)—this differential explains the divergent outcomes for intermediates: contraction under the consumption-oriented Scenario 1 and expansion under the investment-driven Scenario 2.
Rising consumption also reinforces the tertiary sector’s dominance within the forestry value chain (the primary, secondary tertiary sectors accounting for 2.75%, 5.12%, and 92.13% of total consumption demand). Respectively, and spurs the growth of agriculture-forestry-animal-husbandry-fishery services. Structurally, consumption acts as both a market activator for forestry products and a catalyst for tertiary industries, even though it is less potent than investment in directly expanding intermediate output. This underscores the need for balanced demand-side optimization strategies.
Second, investment exerts a slightly stronger influence on forestry production than consumption. An increase in investment raises output of forestry-chain intermediates, with the tertiary sector experiencing the largest impact, the secondary sector a moderate one, and the primary sector the smallest (the primary, secondary and tertiary sectors account for 2.27%, 14.64% and 83.09%, respectively, of total investment demand within the forestry value chain). Thus, additional investment disproportionately benefits tertiary-sector production across the forestry chain; from the narrower perspective of forestry’s own product output, it also boosts secondary-sector production.
Thirdly, changes in net exports have a relatively significant impact on the forestry industry and its supply chain. As illustrated in Scenario 3, the assumption of constant total final product volume in this study implies that a substantial expansion in the trade surplus. Driven by declines in consumption and investment, will inevitably lead to a significant reduction in intermediate products within the forestry supply chain and substantial changes in their structure. This outcome reflects declines in consumption and investment, together with a marked expansion of the trade surplus, will inevitably reduce the volume of intermediate products in the forestry supply chain and substantially alter their composition. It represents a scenario where external demand grows while domestic demand falls. This highlights that an increase in China’s trade surplus can only positively impact the production of the forestry sector and its supply chain if it is supported by growth in consumption and investment. Otherwise, it may result in negative consequences.
China is a major forestry country, however, in terms of the national economy’s demand for forest products, the domestic production of forest products is still far from sufficient, necessitating large-scale imports of forestry raw materials annually. In 2018, China was still in a net export deficit position, although the deficit has been gradually decreasing annually. China’s forestry sector is heavily reliant on imports due to a combination of factors: the scarcity of domestic forest resources, the substantial demand from industries such as industrial materials, furniture manufacturing, and papermaking, which exacerbates the supply–demand imbalance; the implementation of environmental policies that restrict logging in natural forests, leading to a significant decline in domestic timber supply, while most plantations are dominated by fast-growing species that fail to meet the demand for high-quality timber; and the encroachment on forestry land due to industrial expansion, urban sprawl, and rural construction [
35]. The import of forest products is a double-edged sword. While it can fulfill the raw material requirements for forestry and the forestry industry chain, thereby boosting both the national and forestry economies, it can also stifle the production and development of domestic forestry products. In extreme cases, it may result in an overdependence of the national economy on imported forest products [
36].
In recent years, significant events such as the Sino–US trade friction, the COVID-19 pandemic, and the Russia–Ukraine conflict have had a major impact on global supply chains. In particular, this year, the Sino–US trade war has disrupted China’s supply chains, including those in the forestry sector [
37]. If the trade war continues, it will directly impact forestry trade between the two countries and could potentially break the long-established pattern of China’s forestry supply chain, which is characterized by “global raw material procurement—domestic processing—supply to both domestic and international markets.”
In terms of China’s global forestry trade, the trade volume between China and the US has long been the highest. The US trade volume accounts for about 13.31% of China’s total forestry trade, but both the trade volume and its share are declining. China mainly exports wooden furniture, paper and paper products, and wood-based panels to the US, while it imports forestry raw materials such as wood pulp, logs, and lumber from the US [
38].
The Sino–US tariff war has affected both sides. It has impeded China’s forestry exports to the US, highlighting the need to diversify export markets and expand domestic demand to absorb the surplus. China’s retaliatory tariffs have also increased the cost of importing wood, which is detrimental to meeting the intermediate product needs of the forestry supply chain. Given the significant impact of forestry product imports on the development of China’s forestry supply chain, it is imperative to expedite import substitution strategies and adjust international import markets. The pressure from the US will inevitably lead to increased timber imports from forest-rich countries such as Russia. In summary, both export restrictions and rising import costs negatively affect the production of China’s forestry supply chain, highlighting the need to diversify international markets.
The China-US tariff war will also affect domestic consumption and investment in China. Since the data on consumption and investment includes portions allocated to imported products, domestic and international supply chains are interwoven and mutually influential. As previously discussed, forestry production is directly proportional to consumption and investment. Therefore, expanding domestic consumption and investment is crucial for the development of forestry.