Next Article in Journal
Network Activity and Ethereum Gas Prices
Next Article in Special Issue
Assessing the Maturity of Sustainable Business Model and Strategy Reporting under the CSRD Shadow
Previous Article in Journal
Does Capital Expenditure Matter for ESG Disclosure? A UK Perspective
Previous Article in Special Issue
Production Efficiency and Income Distribution with Competition Induced by Antitrust Measures
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

On the Direction of Causality between Business and Financial Cycles

1
Department of Economics and Finance, Lang School of Business and Economics, University of Guelph, Guelph, ON N1G 2W1, Canada
2
Anheuser-Busch InBev, 125 W 24th St, New York, NY 10011, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2023, 16(10), 430; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16100430
Submission received: 26 August 2023 / Accepted: 20 September 2023 / Published: 28 September 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Global Trends and Challenges in Economics and Finance)

Abstract

:
This paper investigates whether business cycles cause financial cycles or vice versa. We also assess whether the US plays a leading role in causing the domestic business and financial cycles of other countries. The literature has established that business and financial cycles are linked through several channels such as credit constraints, the real effects of financial information and the reversal of overoptimistic expectations. Our analysis evaluates the direction of Granger causality using a novel approach based on the mixed-frequency vector autoregression model for the G7 countries. Our approach exploits the fact that real economic activity measured by industrial production is observed at a higher frequency than aggregate credit. We find strong evidence of bidirectional causality between the business and financial cycles, especially in recessions. Furthermore, the US is a global leader since the US business cycle significantly affects other countries’ business cycles, especially in terms of expansions.

1. Introduction

Is Main Street the cause of what happens on Wall Street or vice versa? In other words, do business cycles cause financial cycles or vice versa? This is a central question in macroeconomic research, policy analysis and financial practice. It is well known that business cycles are closely linked with financial cycles (e.g., Borio 2014; Claessens et al. 2012). For example, expansions are good for both Main Street and Wall Street. Conversely, recessions are bad for both Main Street and Wall Street. When both the business and the financial cycles are close to their peak, business and financial conditions are especially good. When both the business and the financial cycles are close to their trough, business and financial conditions are especially tough. These stylized facts establish a correlation but not a causal relation between the business and financial cycles. Consequently, the direction of causality remains an important and yet unanswered question in the literature.1
The main objective of this paper is to fill this gap in the literature by evaluating the direction and timing of Granger causality between the business and financial cycles of the G7 countries. This allows us to evaluate the role of the financial sector in the propagation of economic fluctuations and vice versa, which has been at the heart of economic policy since the global financial crisis. Our analysis of Granger causality is based on a vector autoregression (VAR) model with one important innovation: data on business cycles, which are based on monthly industrial production, are at a higher frequency than data on financial cycles, which are based on quarterly aggregate credit. For this reason, we implement the mixed-frequency vector autoregression (MF-VAR) approach of Ghysels et al. (2016, 2020), which has several econometric advantages that we discuss in our analysis.
In addition to the mixed-frequency causality tests based on monthly industrial production and quarterly aggregate credit, we also perform same-frequency causality tests based on quarterly GDP and quarterly credit. The same-frequency analysis forms the benchmark against which the mixed-frequency results are assessed. The two approaches employ similar information since industrial production is highly correlated with GDP but are differentiated by data availability: industrial production data are available monthly, whereas GDP data are only available quarterly. Hence, the main advantage of mixed frequency is the use of more data for the same sample period, which, combined with the novel MF-VAR methodology of Ghysels et al. (2016, 2020), can lead to higher statistical power (Ghysels 2016). Specifically, mixed-frequency causality tests avoid data aggregation and hence preserve the dynamics of the monthly variable, thus lowering the risk of detecting spurious causality.2 In short, evaluating both the mixed-frequency and the same-frequency approach provides a comprehensive view of the causality between the real and financial sectors.
Our empirical investigation focuses on the G7 countries: USA, Canada, UK, Germany, France, Italy and Japan. The sample period ranges from 1962 to 2019. For each country, the mixed-frequency analysis evaluates whether the monthly industrial production index causes quarterly aggregate credit or vice versa. The same-frequency analysis evaluates whether quarterly GDP causes quarterly aggregate credit or vice versa. We also determine the timing of causality by identifying the periods when causality is statistically significant. We then assess the role of the US as a global leader in causing the domestic cycles of the other G7 countries. We do so by examining whether US industrial production (or credit) causes the industrial production (or credit) of each of the remaining G7 countries.3
In addition, we assess whether causality is related to the phase of the cycles, e.g., whether the causal relation between the two cycles is stronger in recessions or expansions. We then evaluate whether causality is related to the nominal interest rate, which is perhaps the most relevant economic fundamental for the two cycles. Finally, we enhance our understanding of financial cycles by exploring whether equity prices and housing prices have a causal relation with industrial production or GDP. Although aggregate credit is widely considered to be the primary determinant of financial cycles, equity and housing prices are also thought of as determinants of the financial cycle.
Our main finding is that, for the full sample period, there is strong causality between the business and financial cycles and it goes in both directions. Bidirectional causality is especially strong for the North American countries (USA and Canada). For the continental European countries (Germany post-1990, France and Italy), it is the business cycle that causes the financial cycle. For countries with strong financial centers (UK and Japan), it is the financial cycle that causes the business cycle. The exact timing of causality varies across countries, but for most countries causality is strong around the 2007-2008 global financial crisis. Moreover, causality tends to be a bit stronger during bad times, i.e., during business cycle recessions.
We also find that the US business cycle strongly causes the business cycles of five out of the six remaining G7 countries, with the exception being Japan. This causal relation is strong at all times but is slightly stronger during good times, i.e., during business cycle expansions. In contrast, there is little evidence that the US financial cycle is causing other countries’ business or financial cycles. Hence, US leadership is primarily based on its business cycle, not its financial cycle.
The strong bidirectional causality between the business and financial cycles is further confirmed when using the equity price index and the housing price index as alternative ways to describe the financial cycle. In particular, the evidence on the bidirectional causality between monthly industrial production and monthly equity prices is especially strong. Finally, for robustness, we separately assess causality for the four European countries for which monthly credit data are available for a shorter sample period beginning in the late 1990s. We find that the monthly credit results are generally consistent with the main analysis but a bit weaker due to the substantially shorter sample.
A general theme that pervades our findings is that mixed-frequency analysis provides stronger results. In some cases, the results are similar, but in many cases the mixed-frequency results are substantially stronger. For example, in assessing the US as a global leader, the US industrial production significantly causes another country’s credit for four out of six countries. In contrast, in evaluating whether quarterly US GDP causes other countries’ credit, there is no evidence of causality for any country. Similar findings are observed when using monthly equity price data, which delivers stronger results than quarterly equity price data. In conclusion, mixed-frequency analysis provides a crucial advantage in uncovering significant causal relations between the business and financial cycles.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we provide a literature review. Section 3 describes the data and defines the business and financial cycles. The empirical framework for the causality tests using both mixed-frequency and same-frequency data is set out in Section 4. In Section 5, we report the empirical results. In Section 6, we investigate the causal relation between housing prices, equity prices and credit. Policy implications are discussed in Section 7, and, finally, we conclude in Section 8.

2. Literature Review

Our empirical analysis is closely related to Claessens et al. (2012), who analyze the interaction between the business and financial cycles. Claessens et al. (2012) provide a methodology for dating financial cycles, which is then used to assess the overlap between the phases of the two cycles. For example, they assess whether financial cycle downturns coincide with business cycle recessions, as well as the extent to which this coincidence makes recessions worse. In contrast, our analysis takes a different approach by focusing on the direction and timing of the causal relation between the two cycles using a mixed-frequency methodology. In other words, our study concentrates on whether one cycle causes the other one for the G7 countries.
This paper is also related to several recent contributions to the literature, which we discuss briefly. Stockhammer et al. (2019) use annual data from seven OECD countries to study the interaction between the business and financial cycles based on a standard VAR approach. Yan and Huang (2020) use quarterly data from the US to assess the relation between the business and financial cycles both in the frequency domain using wavelet analysis and in the time domain using a standard VAR approach. Strohsal et al. (2019) use quarterly data from the US, UK and Germany to analyze financial cycles in the frequency domain using spectral analysis. Finally, Prabheesh et al. (2021) use quarterly data from India and Indonesia to study the relation between the business and financial cycles using a DCC-GARCH model and a structural VAR model.
Additionally, a recent strand of the literature examines the relation between credit, asset prices and real economic activity, based on the multivariate unobserved components time series model introduced by Harvey and Koopman (1997). For example, Galati et al. (2016) use this approach to extract financial cycles from quarterly time series of credit, the credit-to-GDP ratio and house prices for the US and five European countries for the sample period of 1970 to 2014. Runstler and Vlekke (2018) use an extended version of this model to estimate trend and cyclical components in real GDP, real credit, and real property prices using quarterly data from 1973 to 2014 for the US and five European economies. Finally, the WGEM Team on Real and Financial Cycles of the European Central Bank (2018) uses this approach to provide a comprehensive analysis that estimates financial cycles in 17 European Union countries and assesses their properties and relation to GDP cycles. Note that all these studies are based on quarterly data.
Our empirical focus on causality between the business and financial cycles is motivated by the theoretical framework of Bernanke and Gertler (1989) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997). In this work, a productivity shock in the real economy is amplified and propagated due to credit constraints. For example, consider a firm that is highly leveraged with secured loans against collateralized fixed assets (e.g., land). Suppose that this firm experiences a temporary productivity shock that lowers its net worth. Due to credit constraints, the firm will be unable to borrow more and, therefore, will have to cut its future investment expenditure in fixed assets against which it borrows. This will hurt the firm in the next period as it earns less revenue; its net worth falls further; and again, due to credit constraints, it reduces investment. This feedback effect continues so that an initial temporary shock is amplified and propagated over many periods in the future. In short, therefore, credit constraints can reduce real economic activity, thus ensuring that the credit (financial) cycle has a profound effect on the business cycle.4
The Bernanke and Gertler (1989) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) argument relates to the effect of primary financial markets on real economic activity. It is also possible that real economic activity is affected by secondary financial markets in which securities are traded among investors (as in the stock market) without any capital flowing back to firms. Bond et al. (2012) discuss three reasons why secondary financial markets not only reflect but can also affect economic fundamentals. First, real decision makers learn new information (e.g., firm value) from secondary market prices and use this information to guide their real decisions, in turn affecting the firm’s cash flow and value. For example, credit rating agencies are known to be influenced by stock prices, and their decisions can determine the availability of credit to firms. Second, managers might care about the firm’s stock price because their compensation is often tied to the stock price, which in turn affects their incentives in taking real actions. Third, managers may even irrationally follow the stock price and use it as an anchor because of their belief that prices are informative. In all these cases, there will be a feedback effect from secondary financial markets to the real economy, thus motivating the causal relation between the business and financial cycles.
In addition, Danielsson et al. (2018) investigate the role of low volatility over long periods in causing banking crises, which in turn have an effect on both the financial and the business cycle. Long-lasting periods of low volatility in financial markets breed overoptimism, leading to credit expansions, excessive lending and a reallocation from safer to riskier assets. This eventually leads to future financial crises providing support to Minsky’s (1977) instability hypothesis described by the dictum “stability is destabilizing”. In the same spirit, Lopez-Salido et al. (2017) argue that during credit booms investors form overoptimistic expectations about the future. When in the future investors receive disappointing economic news relative to optimistic expectations, there is an endogenous reversal of sentiment, leading to a decline in economic activity induced by a contraction in the supply of credit (see also Bordalo et al. 2018). In short, these arguments provide a theoretical motivation for the causal relation between the business cycle and the financial cycle that we empirically investigate in this paper.
Finally, there is a large literature on international finance, which motivates the direct effect of the US business and financial cycle in causing the domestic business and financial cycles of other countries. This literature assesses the determinants of international portfolio flows by making a distinction between push factors and pull factors. Push factors reflect the global economic forces that push bond and equity flows from the US to other countries, which are driven primarily by US GDP. Pull factors reflect the domestic economic forces that pull bond and equity flows into a country. In short, push factors are external to the economies receiving the flows and are typically the result of the US global leadership in determining bond and equity flows. This provides a direct economic mechanism through which the US business and financial cycle can affect other countries’ business and financial cycles. For a summary of this literature, see Sarno et al. (2016).

3. Business and Financial Cycles

We assess the causal relation between the business and financial cycles for the G7 industrialized countries: USA, Canada, UK, Germany, France, Italy and Japan. Our analysis determines the phase of the business cycle in each country in two distinct ways: using the monthly industrial production index or using quarterly GDP. Business cycles are typically determined by GDP, which, however, is only available at the quarterly frequency. In addition to GDP, we also use industrial production because it is available at the monthly frequency and hence more data are available for the same sample period. Other than the data frequency, the two variables provide similar information: industrial production is a standard measure of real economic activity and is near perfectly correlated with GDP. For example, the correlation between quarterly real US industrial production and quarterly real US GDP for our sample period is equal to 0.98 .5
The financial cycle is determined by quarterly aggregate credit, which is standard in the literature (e.g., Borio 2014; Claessens et al. 2012). Credit is a natural aggregate for analyzing the financial cycle because it constitutes the most important link between savings and investment. Credit data are only available at the quarterly frequency. In a subsequent section, we also consider equity and housing price indices as determinants of the financial cycle. In the robustness section, we also consider a short sample of European countries for which credit data are available monthly.

3.1. Data

The seasonally adjusted monthly industrial production index (IPI) is obtained from the FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The IPI data are in real terms. The sample period begins in January 1962 and ends in March 2019 for all countries.
The seasonally adjusted quarterly GDP is also obtained from the FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The GDP data are in real terms. The sample period begins in Q1 (first quarter) of 1962 and ends in Q1 of 2019 for all countries.
Quarterly data on aggregate credit are obtained from the Bank for International Settlements. These data are for nominal aggregate credit in domestic currency offered by domestic banks to the private non-financial sector. The credit data begin on the following dates: Q1 of 1962 for the US, Canada and Germany; Q1 of 1964 for the UK; Q1 of 1965 for Japan; Q1 of 1970 for France; and Q1 of 1975 for Italy. For all countries, the credit data sample ends in Q1 of 2019.
We convert the credit data to real terms by dividing nominal credit by the consumer price index (CPI) of each country. The CPI index is obtained from the FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. With this conversion, all business and financial cycle variables are expressed in real terms. In order to avoid potential seasonal effects, we follow Ghysels et al. (2016) in using the annual growth rate of industrial production (month-by-month), GDP (quarter-by-quarter) and credit (quarter-by-quarter). Table 1 reports summary statistics on the real annual growth rates of the three variables.

3.2. Defining Business Cycles

We define the business cycle for the US using the peak and trough dates determined by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) business cycle dating committee. For the other six countries, we define the business cycle using the OECD-based recession indicators obtained from the FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. In all cases, the recession phase is defined as the period from the peak (exclusive) to the trough (inclusive), and the expansion phase is the period from the trough (exclusive) to the peak (inclusive).

3.3. Defining Financial Cycles

Following Claessens et al. (2012), we identify the phases of the financial cycle based on contractions and expansions of real credit. We identify the turning points in the log of real credit using the algorithm introduced by Harding and Pagan (2002). This is a well-established and reproducible methodology for dating different phases of a cycle. The algorithm requires a complete cycle to last at least five quarters and each phase to last at least two quarters. Specifically, a peak in the quarterly log-credit series y t occurs at time t if:
( y t y t 2 ) > 0 , ( y t y t 1 ) > 0 , ( y t + 2 y t ) < 0 , ( y t + 1 y t ) < 0 .
Similarly, a trough occurs at time t if:
( y t y t 2 ) < 0 , ( y t y t 1 ) < 0 , ( y t + 2 y t ) > 0 , ( y t + 1 y t ) > 0 .
Using the terminology of Claessens et al. (2012), the recovery phase of the financial cycle (from trough to peak) is called the “upturn”, whereas the contraction phase (from peak to trough) is called the “downturn”.

3.4. Interaction of Business and Financial Cycles

Our analysis accounts for the interaction between the business and financial cycles by reporting results for three phases: (1) severe recessions, which we define as business cycle recessions that coincide with a financial cycle downturn; (2) recessions, which henceforth we define as business cycle recessions that do not coincide with a financial cycle downturn; and (3) business cycle expansions. Note that, by design, there is no overlap between severe recessions and recessions.6
Table 2 reports the growth rates for the monthly industrial production, quarterly GDP and quarterly aggregate credit during the three phases. In almost all cases, there is a monotonic relation of each variable with the three cycle phases: IPI, GDP and credit gradually improve as we move from a severe recession to a recession, and then to an expansion. This finding is consistent with previous literature (e.g., Borio 2014; Claessens et al. 2012) as it indicates that (1) IPI, GDP and credit display strong cyclical behaviour; and (2) there is a strong interaction between the two cycles since they seem to be moving in the same direction. The interaction between the two cycles is indicated by the fact that severe recessions tend to be substantially worse than recessions. Having thus established this cyclical behaviour, the natural question to consider next is whether one cycle causes the other one.

4. Testing for Causality

An important aspect of our analysis is the use of both same-frequency (quarterly) data and mixed-frequency (monthly plus quarterly) data. This is primarily driven by data availability: industrial production data are available monthly, but GDP and aggregate credit are available quarterly. Throughout our analysis, we consider two causality cases: (1) the mixed-frequency case, which investigates the causal relation between monthly industrial production and quarterly credit; and (2) the same-frequency case, which investigates the relation between quarterly GDP and quarterly credit. Considering both cases provides a comprehensive view of the causality between the real and financial sectors. If, for example, both cases provide evidence of a significant causal relation then we take this to be a strong result that holds irrespective of the data frequency.
The use of monthly industrial production, rather than just quarterly GDP, enriches our analysis because industrial production data are available at a higher frequency than GDP data. Industrial production is a natural alternative to GDP because these two variables are almost perfectly correlated. This is the reason why industrial production has become the standard monthly variable to capture fluctuations in the real economy. In contrast, aggregate credit, which is the standard determinant of the financial cycle, is only available quarterly.
The benchmark approach in our empirical analysis is using same-frequency data, i.e., quarterly GDP and quarterly credit. Assessing the causal relation between GDP and credit requires a standard methodology. In contrast, the mixed-frequency approach requires a new methodology that has only recently become available by Ghysels et al. (2016, 2020). Since the mixed-frequency approach has not been implemented in the study of business and financial cycles, it constitutes a novel contribution to the literature.
In what follows, we describe the two sets of causality tests. First, we describe the mixed-frequency tests followed by the benchmark tests based on the quarterly frequency. Note that the quarterly frequency causality tests are a simple case of the more general mixed-frequency causality tests.

4.1. Mixed Frequency

We begin by introducing formal notation that distinguishes between three frequencies: monthly, quarterly and mixed frequency. The monthly variable is defined as x M ( τ , k ) , where τ { 1 , , T } denotes the quarterly time index, k { 1 , , m } denotes the monthly time index, and m = 3 is the number of months in one quarter. The quarterly variable is simply defined as x Q ( τ ) .
The mixed-frequency process combines both the monthly and the quarterly variable by stacking them as follows:
X ( τ ) = [ x ˜ M ( τ ) , x Q ( τ ) ] ,
where x ˜ M ( τ ) = [ x M ( τ , 1 ) , x M ( τ , 2 ) , x M ( τ , 3 ) ] . Therefore, at each quarter τ , X ( τ ) contains three monthly observations for x ˜ M and one quarterly observation for x Q .

4.2. Definition of Granger Causality

In order to define causality, we first define the mixed-frequency information set in period τ as follows:
F ( τ ) = { X ( , τ ] } = { x ˜ M , τ , x Q , τ } .
In other words, F ( τ ) contains all the information in x ˜ M and x Q up to quarter τ .
Then, according to Granger (1969), we assert that x M does not cause x Q at the quarterly horizon h given F ( τ ) , a statement denoted as x M x Q ( τ + h ) | F ( τ ) , if:
P [ x Q ( τ + h ) | F ( τ ) ] = P [ x Q ( τ + h ) | x Q , τ ] τ .
Equation (5) implies that the h-quarter-ahead prediction of the quarterly variable x Q ( τ + h ) is uncorrelated with the past and present values of the monthly variable x ˜ M .
Similarly, x Q does not cause x ˜ M at horizon h given F ( τ ) , a statement denoted as x Q x ˜ M ( τ + h ) | F ( τ ) , if:
P [ x ˜ M ( τ ) | F ( τ ) ] = P [ x ˜ M ( τ + h ) | x ˜ M , τ ] τ .
Equation (6) implies that the h-quarter-ahead prediction of the monthly variable x ˜ M (a vector containing three months) is uncorrelated with the past and present values of the quarterly variable x Q .

4.3. The MF-VAR Model

We test for the causal relation between the high-frequency variable (monthly industrial production) and the low-frequency variable (quarterly credit) in the context of the mixed-frequency vector autoregression (MF-VAR) model introduced by Ghysels (2016).7 We illustrate the model below for the simple case where x Q and x M follow an AR(1) process:
1 0 0 0 d 1 0 0 0 d 1 0 0 0 0 1 N x M ( τ , 1 ) x M ( τ , 2 ) x M ( τ , 3 ) x Q ( τ ) = 0 0 d c 1 0 0 0 c 2 0 0 0 c 3 b 1 b 2 b 3 a M x M ( τ 1 , 1 ) x M ( τ 1 , 2 ) x M ( τ 1 , 3 ) x Q ( τ 1 ) + ϵ M ( τ , 1 ) ϵ M ( τ , 2 ) ϵ M ( τ , 3 ) ϵ Q ( τ ) ϵ ( τ )
or
N X ( τ ) = M X ( τ 1 ) + ϵ ( τ ) .
In this MF-VAR specification, the parameters c 1 , c 2 , and c 3 measure the impact of the lagged x Q on x M . Similarly, the parameters b 1 , b 2 and b 3 measure the impact of the lagged x M on x Q . Furthermore, the matrix N is positive definite, and hence it is invertible. Then, it is straightforward to show that the model is of the form:
X ( τ ) = A X ( τ 1 ) + ε ( τ ) ,
where
A = N 1 M = 0 0 d i = 1 1 d 1 i c i 0 0 d 2 i = 1 2 d 2 i c i 0 0 d 3 i = 1 3 d 3 i c i b 1 b 2 b 3 a ,
and ε ( τ ) = N 1 ϵ ( τ ) .8

4.4. Granger Causality Tests

4.4.1. Does Monthly Industrial Production Cause Quarterly Credit?

In the context of the MF-VAR model, we test whether monthly industrial production causes quarterly credit by estimating the following regression with ordinary least squares (OLS):
x Q ( τ ) = α 0 + p = 1 P α p x Q ( τ p ) + r = 1 R β r x M ( τ 1 , m + 1 r ) + ε ( τ ) .
This regression follows Ghysels et al. (2016, 2020). We test whether x M ( τ 1 , r ) causes x Q ( τ ) by testing the null hypothesis that β r = 0 r using a Wald test statistic. Following Ghysels et al. (2016, 2020), the calculation of the Wald test statistic is based on a bootstrap method with a heteroskedasticity-robust covariance matrix.

4.4.2. Does Quarterly Credit Cause Monthly Industrial Production?

We test whether quarterly credit causes monthly industrial production by estimating the following regression with OLS:
x Q ( τ ) = α 0 + p = 1 P α p x Q ( τ p ) + r = 1 R β r x M ( τ 1 , m + 1 r ) + s = 1 S γ s x M ( τ + 1 , m + 1 s ) + ε ( τ ) .
This is a two-sided regression, which incorporates both leads and lags for x M . This type of regression was originally introduced by Sims (1972) and follows Ghysels et al. (2020).
The main difference between regression models (11) and (12) is the lead variable x M ( τ + 1 , s ) . The coefficient of the lead variable γ s is the focus of the quarterly-to-monthly causality test. From the point of view of τ + 1 , the coefficient γ s represents the predictive relation between the lagged x Q ( τ ) variable and the x M ( τ + 1 , s ) variable. Hence, γ s determines the quarterly-to-monthly causality. We assess whether x Q ( τ ) causes x M ( τ + 1 , s ) by testing the null hypothesis that γ s = 0 s using a Wald test statistic. Again, the Wald test statistic is based on a bootstrap method with a heteroskedasticity-robust covariance matrix.

4.4.3. Lag Selection

For both directions of causality, we follow Ghysels et al. (2016) in using 4 quarterly lags ( P = 4 ) and 12 monthly lags ( R = S = 12 ). This implies that for each causality test, we test 12 zero restrictions. This lag selection exhibits good performance with respect to Ljung-Box Q-tests for the serial correlation of residuals. The Ljung-Box Q-tests are based on the double blocks-of-blocks bootstrap method of Ghysels et al. (2020) with 10,000 replications.
In general, there is a tradeoff between adding more lag terms and the performance of Ljung-Box Q-tests. Adding more lags reduces the serial correlation of the residuals but augments the effect of parameter proliferation, which may cause a size distortion to the asymptotic properties of the Wald test. Our lag selection is designed to balance this tradeoff and is also effective in dealing with intra-year seasonalities since the lags use a full year of information.9

4.5. Testing for the US as a Global Leader

The empirical framework we described so far is designed to test whether the industrial production of a country causes the credit of the same country or vice versa. We refer to this approach as the domestic cycle approach because it considers each country in isolation. We now turn to testing for the role of the US as a global leader in causing the business or financial cycle of another country.
Specifically, we test whether US industrial production (or credit) causes the industrial production (or credit) of another country. In order to do this, we estimate a variation of the original MF-VAR specification with two countries: the US and the domestic country denoted by D. This MF-VAR model is specified as follows:
x ˜ M U S ( τ ) x ˜ M D ( τ ) x Q U S ( τ ) x Q D ( τ ) = p = 1 P A p x ˜ M U S ( τ p ) x ˜ M D ( τ p ) x Q U S ( τ p ) x Q D ( τ p ) + ε ˜ M U S ( τ ) ε ˜ M D ( τ ) ε Q U S ( τ ) ε Q D ( τ ) ,
where x ˜ M U S ( τ ) = [ x M U S ( τ , 1 ) , x M U S ( τ , 2 ) , x M U S ( τ , 3 ) ] and x ˜ M D ( τ ) = [ x M D ( τ , 1 ) , x M D ( τ , 2 ) , x M D ( τ , 3 ) ] are the monthly US and domestic variables, respectively; x Q U S ( τ ) and x Q D ( τ ) are the quarterly US and domestic variables, respectively; ε ˜ M U S ( τ ) = [ ε M U S ( τ , 1 ) , ε M U S ( τ , 2 ) , ε M U S ( τ , 3 ) ] and ε ˜ M D ( τ ) = [ ε M D ( τ , 1 ) , ε M D ( τ , 2 ) , ε M D ( τ , 3 ) ] are the monthly error terms; and ε Q U S ( τ ) and ε Q D ( τ ) are the quarterly error terms.
The causality tests for the US as a global leader are set up in a similar way to the tests for individual countries. The main difference here is that because the introduction of the US in the MF-VAR model substantially increases the dimension of the parameters to be estimated, the number of lags must be lower to make estimation feasible. We set P = 2 quarterly lags and R = 6 monthly lags, which is the highest number of lags that avoids estimation problems due to parameter proliferation. In other words, we test for 12 zero restrictions, which is the same number of restrictions estimated for the individual country results: here, we have half the number of lags but double the number of countries, hence the same number of zero restrictions. Again, the Wald test follows Ghysels et al. (2016) and is based on a bootstrap method with a heteroskedasticity-robust covariance matrix.

4.6. Testing for Causality at the Quarterly Frequency

The mixed-frequency causality tests are assessed against the benchmark of quarterly frequency causality tests. The two sets of tests (mixed vs. quarterly) are designed to have the same structure so that they are directly comparable. Specifically, we estimate the same regressions as in Equations (11) and (12), with the only difference being that monthly industrial production is replaced by quarterly GDP. For consistency, all lags are set at four quarters. Our approach is also similar in testing for the role of the US as a global leader: the VAR structure remains the same, but now all variables are quarterly.

5. Results

5.1. Domestic Business and Financial Cycles

We begin by assessing the direction of Granger causality between the business and the financial cycles of each individual country. We refer to the individual country cases as the domestic business and financial cycles. Table 3 reports the p-values of the Wald test over the full sample for two cases: the causal relation of IPI with credit for mixed frequency and the causal relation of GDP with credit for quarterly frequency. As previously shown in Table 1, the full sample period is slightly different across countries with the longest sample period ranging from January 1963 to March 2019.10
The empirical evidence reported in Table 3 indicates that there is strong causality between the business and financial cycles and that it often goes in both directions. This finding holds for both quarterly and mixed frequency. Our discussion focuses on the mixed-frequency results due to the inherent benefits of using higher frequency data (i.e., more data), the novelty of this approach and because the results tend to be stronger. Specifically, we find that IPI causes credit for 4 out of 7 countries, whereas credit also causes IPI for 4 out of 7 countries. For the US and Canada, there is strong bidirectional causality. For France and Italy, it is IP that significantly causes credit. For the UK and Japan, it is credit that significantly causes IPI. Finally, for Germany causality is not significant in either direction, but, as we discuss below, this result is reversed for the post-1990 German reunification period.
The quarterly-frequency results are similar to the mixed-frequency results but overall are a bit weaker. Specifically, the quarterly-frequency p-values are significant for the same cases as the mixed-frequency p-values, with two notable exceptions. First, for the US and Canada quarterly p-values fail to capture the fact that financial cycles cause business cycles; they only show that business cycles cause financial cycles. Second, for Italy the results are actually reversed: for mixed frequency it is the business cycle that causes the financial cycle but for quarterly frequency it is the financial cycle that causes the business cycle. All of the other results for individual countries are the same.
The full sample results in Table 3 are complemented by Figure 1 and Figure 2, which display the p-values period-by-period using a rolling window of 20 years so that the first p-value is available for January 1983. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. Given that the full sample results, with few exceptions, are similar for mixed and quarterly frequency, the figures report results for the mixed-frequency case since this case is more general. The contribution of the figures is that they indicate which time periods are associated with significant causality and which are not. According to the figures, the strongest results (in the sense that causality is significant for long periods of time) relate to IPI-causing credit in the US and France. In addition, in many cases, bidirectional causality is significant around the 2007-2008 global financial crisis. Germany is also an interesting case since we can see that causality of IPI to credit becomes predominantly significant in the post-1990 German reunification period.
In summary, these findings are interesting since for the North American countries (USA and Canada) the business and financial cycles strongly cause one another. For the continental European countries (Germany post-1990, France and Italy), it is the business cycle that causes the financial cycle. Finally, for countries with strong financial centers (UK and Japan), it is the financial cycle that causes the business cycle.

5.2. The US as a Global Leader

Next, we turn to the role of the US as a global leader, where we examine the following four cross-country causal relations: (1) US IPI causing the IPI of another country, (2) US IPI causing the credit of another country, (3) US credit causing the IPI of another country, and (4) US credit causing the credit of another country. The results are reported in Table 4 and Figure 3 and Figure 4.
Our main finding here is that, for mixed frequency, the US IPI strongly causes the IPI of other countries: the p-value is significant for 5 out of 6 countries (the exception being Japan). The result for quarterly frequency is slightly weaker: the US GDP significantly causes the GDP of 4 out of 6 other countries. Therefore, there is strong evidence that the US business cycle strongly causes the business cycle of other countries.
In terms of the US business cycle causing other countries’ financial cycle, the evidence is strong only for mixed-frequency data (4 out of 6 countries) but is weak for quarterly data (no significance for any country). This is the one case where the mixed-frequency results deviate substantially from the quarterly-frequency results. Given the more general nature of mixed-frequency tests, we take these results as evidence that the US business cycle is transmitted to the financial cycle of other countries.
In terms of the US financial cycle causing other countries’ business or financial cycles, the evidence is generally weak, regardless of data frequency and real activity measure. These results are confirmed by Figure 3 and Figure 4, which plot the period-by-period p-value of the causality tests.
We conclude that the US business cycle strongly causes the business cycle of most other countries. This is an interesting result as it indicates that only the business cycle of the US, and not its financial cycle, has an effect on other countries’ real economic activity. In short, we find strong evidence that real economic activity in the US is transmitted to other countries’ real economic activity, thus supporting the view that the US is a global leader.

5.3. Is Causality Cyclical?

Having established the bidirectional causality of domestic business and financial cycles as well as the leading effect of US business cycles on other countries’ business cycles, we now turn to relating causality to the phase of the cycles. In other words, we ask the following question: when is causality the strongest? Is it during severe recessions, during recessions or during expansions? To answer this question, we compute how often (as a percentage of all time periods) the p-value is less than or equal to 0.1 during a particular phase. In other words, we assess how often causality is significant during one of the phases. Table 5 has the results for individual countries, whereas Table 6 has the results for the US as a global leader.
First, we assess the extent to which causality is cyclical for the domestic cycles. Our discussion again focuses on the mixed-frequency results that seem to be the strongest. We find that for the majority of countries, business cycles cause financial cycles more often in severe recessions and less often in expansions. In simple words, the worse the economic conditions the more likely that IPI causes credit. For the US, for example, in severe recessions the causal relation of IPI to credit is always significant (i.e., 100% of the time). This confirms our main result that the business cycle tends to cause the financial cycle in most countries but also adds to this finding that causality is more likely in severe recessions, where these are defined as business cycle recessions occurring at a time of a financial cycle downturn.
Next, we assess the role of the US as a global leader by computing the proportion of times that causality is significant in terms of the US business/financial cycle’s effect on another country’s business/financial cycle. In this case, we define the three phases (severe recession, recession and expansion) using as references both the US cycle and the domestic cycle. In other words, each phase is shown both from the point of view of the US and that of the other country. Given our previous evidence that the US credit has little or no effect on the domestic cycles, Table 6 displays the results only for the US business cycle causing the domestic business cycles with both mixed and quarterly frequency data.
Our main result again involves the mixed-frequency data: for most countries, we find that the US IPI causes the domestic IPI more often during expansions. In other words, the transmission of the US business cycle to other countries’ business cycles is more likely when the economy is at its best. This is primarily true when we look at cycle phases from the point of view of the US. Overall, this is an important finding because it indicates that the US is a global leader in exporting its expansions to other countries—more so than its (severe) recessions. To be precise, the US also exports its (severe) recessions to other countries, but the transmission effect is stronger in expansions than in recessions.
In conclusion, the domestic business cycle is more likely to cause the domestic financial cycle when the economic conditions are bad. In contrast, the US business cycle is more likely to cause the domestic business cycles when the economic conditions are good. In short, the domestic business cycle transmission is more likely in recessions, but the US business cycle transmission is more likely in expansions.

5.4. Causality and the Interest Rate

The interest rate is perhaps the most relevant economic variable in terms of affecting both the business and the financial cycle. We relate causality to the interest rate by forming a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the p-value for causality at a given time period is less than 0.1, and 0 otherwise. Hence, the dummy variable indicates when causality is significant. The p-value is taken from the rolling-window regressions. Then, for individual country analysis, we estimate a probit regression of the dummy variable on the domestic nominal interest rate. In other words, we assess whether interest rates are related to significant p-values for causality. In this analysis, a positive coefficient on the interest rate implies that a higher interest rate makes causality more likely and vice versa.
For the cross-country analysis (i.e., assessing the leading role of the US), we estimate a probit regression of the dummy variable on the difference between the domestic and the US nominal interest rate. Using the difference in interest rates is standard practice in international finance when two countries are involved, for example, in interest parity conditions (e.g., Della Corte et al. 2009; Li et al. 2015). Note that interest rates are the 3-month Treasury Bill rates obtained from the FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The results are reported in Table 7.
We find that for individual countries, causality consistently displays a significant relation to the nominal interest rate, but the sign of the relation differs across countries. In most cases, the sign tends to be positive. For example, when focusing on the mixed-frequency results, the sign of the probit regression coefficient on interest rates is positive for six cases and negative for two. This finding indicates that the interest rate is significantly related to causality in most cases and, when it is, the relation tends to be positive. In short, the higher the interest rate the more likely for one domestic cycle to be causing another domestic cycle.
For the US leadership analysis, causality is also significantly related to the interest rate differential for the majority of cases. When it is, however, the relation tends to be negative. For example, when focusing on the mixed-frequency results, the sign of the probit regression coefficient on the interest rate differential is positive for 5 cases and negative for 12. A negative sign implies that causality is high when the interest rate differential is low, i.e., when either the domestic interest rate is low or the US interest rate is high, or both. In other words, the US tends to export its cycles to other countries when the US interest rate is higher than the domestic interest rate.

6. Equity Prices, Housing Prices and Credit

In this section, we add two further variables to our analysis of the financial cycle: equity prices and housing prices. Aggregate credit is typically the primary variable used in the literature for the study of financial cycles. However, equity and housing prices have also been used, in addition to credit, to provide a comprehensive view of financial cycles (see, e.g., Claessens et al. 2012).

6.1. Equity and Housing Price Data

The financial cycle data on equity prices are available both at the monthly and the quarterly frequency. We use the MSCI stock price index to represent the equity price index (EPI) of each country, which is obtained from the Refinitiv Eikon database. The monthly and quarterly EPI data are converted to real terms by dividing by the CPI of each country. The EPI sample period for all seven countries ranges from January (Q1) 1971 to March (Q1) 2019.
The financial cycle data on housing prices are available only at the quarterly frequency. The quarterly housing price index (HPI) is obtained from the OECD Main Economic Indicators for all countries except for the UK. For the UK, we use the Halifax Housing Price Index obtained from the Refinitiv Eikon database because it is not available from the OECD. The HPI data are converted to real terms in the same way as the EPI data above. The sample period for HPI begins on Q1 of 1971 for all countries except for Q1 of 1969 for the UK and Q1 of 1962 for Japan. The sample period ends in Q1 of 2019 for all countries.
Similar to our main analysis, the analysis of HPI and EPI is based on annual growth rates. Table 8 reports summary statistics for the real annual growth rates of the monthly and quarterly equity price indexes as well as the quarterly housing price indexes.

6.2. Causality Tests Using Housing and Equity Prices

We take a deeper look into the workings of the financial cycle by providing a comprehensive assessment of the following causal relations between a business cycle variable and a new financial cycle variable: (1) monthly IPI causing monthly EPI or vice versa; (2) quarterly GDP causing monthly EPI or vice versa; (3) quarterly GDP causing quarterly EPI or vice versa; (4) monthly IPI causing quarterly HPI or vice versa; and (5) quarterly GDP causing quarterly HPI or vice versa. Some of these relations are same frequency (monthly or quarterly) and some are mixed frequency. The full sample results are reported in Table 9. Note that the sample periods reflect the sample periods reported in Table 8.
The results confirm our main finding that there is bidirectional causality between the business and financial cycles: business cycles cause financial cycles and vice versa. For example, monthly IPI significantly causes monthly EPI for four out of the seven countries, whereas monthly EPI significantly causes monthly IPI for six countries. Hence, the causal relation between IPI and EPI is strong and bidirectional.
More importantly, we find that monthly and mixed frequency results are much stronger than quarterly results. For example, monthly IPI significantly causes monthly EPI for four countries, but quarterly GDP causes quarterly EPI for only one country. Similarly, monthly EPI significantly causes monthly IPI for six countries, but quarterly EPI causes quarterly GDP for four countries. In addition, monthly IPI significantly causes quarterly HPI for four countries, but quarterly GDP significantly causes quarterly HPI for only two countries.
In summary, there is a clear pattern in the results: the monthly and mixed frequency results are similar, but the quarterly results are weaker. This indicates the importance of using monthly data over quarterly data where possible. It also justifies the use a mixed-frequency approach when monthly data are not available for both variables. To conclude, using EPI and HPI as additional variables to describe financial cycles confirms our main finding of bidirectional causality between the two cycles and provides strong evidence that a mixed frequency approach performs better than just using quarterly data.

7. Robustness: Using Monthly European Credit Data

Our main analysis is based on quarterly credit data because monthly credit data are not available for the G7 countries. However, the European Central Bank makes monthly credit data available for the subset of the four European G7 countries (UK, Germany, France and Italy) over a short sample period. For robustness, this section uses the European monthly credit data in assessing the causality between the business and financial cycles. Specifically, the monthly credit data are obtained from the Statistical Data Warehouse of the European Central Bank.11
Table 10 reports summary statistics on the European data. The sample period begins in September 1998 for three countries (Germany, France and Italy) and in January 2000 for the UK. For all four countries, the sample period ends in March 2019, which is the end date for all data used in our analysis. As previously, we use annual growth rates expressed in real terms.
The availability of monthly data allows us to implement monthly same-frequency causality tests rather than having to rely on mixed frequency tests. We assess Granger causality between the monthly IPI and monthly credit, and we report the results in Table 11. Our main finding is that there is significant bidirectional causality for two of the four countries: the UK and France. For the other two countries, Germany and Italy, causality is not significant. Of the eight cases considered in Table 11, five of them match the result of the main analysis: significant causality of IPI to credit for France, lack of significant causality of IPI to credit for Germany, significant causality of credit to IPI for the UK, and lack of significant causality of credit to IPI for Germany and Italy. For the remaining three cases, there is no match with the results of the main analysis.
Overall, these monthly results appear to be a bit weaker than the main analysis based on mixed frequency results. We conjecture that the weaker results are due to the much shorter sample period: whereas in the main analysis the sample period begins in the early 1960s, in this section it begins in the late 1990s, a difference of over 35 years of data. In other words, our main analysis is based on a sample period that is almost three times longer than the European data. We conclude, therefore, that for the four European countries the results are stronger when we use mixed-frequency analysis for a longer sample period than monthly same-frequency analysis for a much shorter sample period.

8. Discussion and Policy Implications

Understanding the nature of aggregate credit risk (as exemplified by the financial cycle) has important implications for macroeconomic and financial stability. For example, Schularick and Taylor (2012) argue that, in the postwar era, credit aggregates are crucial for understanding macroeconomic fluctuations. This is known as the “credit view”. In contrast, Baker et al. (2018) provide new evidence in favour of the “money view” of Friedman and Schwartz (1963), where broad money aggregates outperform credit aggregates in predicting economic downturns. In either case, credit is essential for determining the financial cycle, and this in turn has important implications for real economic activity. Therefore, it is a priority for central banks to pay attention to the systemic implications of credit aggregates in addition to following inflation targeting rules.
Previous research has identified two important features of the financial cycle (see, e.g., Borio et al. 2018). First, financial cycle peaks tend to coincide with banking crises. During expansions, rapid increases in credit drive up property and asset prices, which in turn increase collateral values and thus the amount of credit the private sector can obtain. In recessions, this process is reversed and can lead to a “balance sheet recession” (termed by Koo 2003) based on the mutually reinforcing interaction between financing constraints and perceptions of value and risk. Balance sheet recessions tend to be deeper, followed by a weaker recovery and can result in permanent output loss.
Second, the financial cycle can be much longer than the business cycle. While the business cycle typically lasts up to eight years, the average length of the financial cycle is about 16 years (see, e.g., Borio 2014). The difference in length means that a financial cycle can span more than a business cycle. As a result, while the financial cycle peaks tend to usher in recessions, not all recessions will be preceded by financial cycle peaks.12
Borio (2014) provides a thorough discussion of the policy implications of dealing with severe recessions due to the interaction of business and financial cycles. This discussion is also relevant in our context. Our main contribution is to determine the direction and timing of causality between the business and financial cycles. Therefore, our analysis allows us to pinpoint when a country’s cycle causes the same country’s other cycle. We also establish the role of the US as global leader in affecting the business and financial cycle of other countries. By design, our analysis identifies causality but does not provide a prescription of appropriate policy responses for alleviating the effects of cycles. For this reason, the discussion in this section is based on Borio (2014), who provides detailed information on appropriate policy responses that would be relevant given our findings.
We first focus on dealing with the boom. In the case of prudential policy, Borio (2014) proposes the strengthening of the macroprudential/systemic arrangements in place. This implies building buffers in good times, as financial vulnerabilities grow, in order to draw them down in bad times as financial stress materializes. In the case of monetary policy, central banks must adopt a strategy against the build up of financial imbalances even if near-term inflation remains low. One way to achieve this is to extend the policy horizon beyond the standard of two years, which is typical of inflation targeting regimes.
In dealing with the bust, Borio (2014) argues that it is critical to distinguish between two different phases: crisis management and crisis resolution. Crisis management is about preventing the implosion of the financial system and reducing the threat of a self-reinforcing downward spiral for economic activity. Crisis resolution focuses on balance sheet repair in an effort to lay the foundations of economic recovery. In summary, these are the main policy responses advocated by Borio (2014) that are relevant in an economy where business and financial cycles cause each other.

9. Conclusions

An emerging literature in financial economics has established the presence of financial cycles, which are primarily based on the cyclical behaviour of aggregate real credit issued by banks. Financial cycles are distinct from but correlated with business cycles. When both cycles are approaching their peak, the economic and financial conditions are extraordinarily good. Similarly, when both cycles are approaching their trough, the economic and financial conditions are extraordinarily bad. An open question in this literature that remains is whether business cycles cause financial cycles or vice versa. This is a question with fundamental implications for research, policy and financial practice.
Our paper bridges this gap in the literature by investigating the direction and timing of Granger causality between the two cycles. Our methodology is primarily based on a mixed-frequency vector autoregression that exploits the fact that real economic activity measured by industrial production is observed at a higher frequency than aggregate credit. We complement the mixed-frequency approach with a standard same-frequency approach based on quarterly GDP and quarterly aggregate credit. In short, implementing both approaches provides a comprehensive view of the causality between the real and financial sectors.
The empirical evidence establishes four main findings for the G7 countries: (1) there is a statistically significant causal relation between the business and financial cycles for the G7 countries; (2) the causal relation is often bidirectional: business cycles cause financial cycles and vice versa; (3) the direction of causality depends on the country: it is bidirectional for the US and Canada; the business cycle causes the financial cycle for Germany, France and Italy; and the financial cycle causes the business cycle for the UK and Japan; and finally (4) the US is a global leader in that the US business cycle causes the business cycles of other countries. Overall, these findings indicate that Main Street and Wall Street are not only correlated but actually affect each other, with the US Main Street playing a leading role among the G7 countries.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, I.T. and H.Z.; methodology, I.T. and H.Z.; formal analysis, I.T. and H.Z.; software, H.Z.; validation, H.Z.; writing—original draft, I.T.; writing—review and editing, I.T.; project administration, I.T.; and funding acquisition, I.T. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada grant number 430418.

Data Availability Statement

Data are obtained from the FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the National Bureau of Economic Research, the Bank for International Settlements, the Refinitiv Eikon database and the OECD Main Economic Indicators.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful for useful comments to Nikola Gradojevic; Delong Li; Alex Maynard; Ivan Medovikov; and seminar participants at the University of Guelph, the 2018 Midwest Econometrics Group Conference, the 2018 Doctoral Workshop in Applied Econometrics at Ryerson University, and the 2019 Canadian Economics Association Conference.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Notes

1
For example, Claessens et al. (2012) find that recessions accompanied by financial disruption, such as house and equity price busts, tend to be longer and deeper. On the other hand, recoveries combined with rapid growth in credit and house prices tend to be stronger. Similarly, Borio (2014) finds that recessions that coincide with the contraction phase of a financial cycle are especially severe. These findings are consistent with Romer and Romer (2017), who find that in the aftermath of financial crises, real output falls significantly and persistently.
2
See Breitung and Swanson (2002) for a detailed discussion of these issues.
3
For example, Rapach et al. (2013) perform a similar analysis for equity markets and find that the US is a global leader in causing the movements of remaining international equity markets.
4
Note that the financial accelerator approach of Bernanke and Gertler (1989) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) provides a theory of loans to corporations (including frictions). Our analysis uses aggregate credit data that includes loans to households. Hence, our empirical approach is more general than the theoretical implications of credit constraints on corporate credit.
5
As discussed below, our analysis is based on annual growth rates. The correlation between the quarter-by-quarter annual growth rates of real industrial production and real GDP for the US during our sample period is equal to 0.80 .
6
The addition of severe recessions to the standard business cycle recessions is meant to emphasize the role of financial cycle downturns in making recessions worse. In contrast, we do not consider a separate phase for business cycle expansions that coincide with financial cycle upturns because the empirical evidence indicates that upturns have little effect on expansions.
7
The mixed-frequency VAR provides an alternative to commonly used state-space models applied on mixed-frequency data. State-space models involve latent processes and, therefore, rely on filtering to extract hidden states that are used to predict future outcomes. Consequently, state-space models are parameter-driven models. In contrast, the mixed-frequency VAR models are observation-driven models as they are formulated exclusively in terms of observable data. For more details, see Ghysels (2016).
8
For notational simplicity, in this specification we ignore the vector of constants, but we add it later to the notation used for the causality tests. Also for notational simplicity, the specification presented in Equations (7)– (10) assume an AR(1) process for the vector X ( τ ) . As we will see later, the models we estimate in our empirical analysis actually use 4 quarterly and 12 monthly lags.
9
The Ljung-Box Q-tests on the OLS residuals of Equations (11) and (12) are used extensively by Ghysels et al. (2020). These tests are appropriate in this context because they assess whether the full set of all VAR autocorrelations is significantly different from zero instead of individually testing each lag. Unreported results on Ljung-Box Q-tests are available upon request. Overall, the Q-tests show that the residuals are not serially correlated for Q = 4 , R = S = 12 with 95 % confidence for all countries.
10
The first data point is for January 1962, but since we are computing the annual growth rate, the analysis effectively begins on January 1963.
11
The data are for loans vis-a-vis domestic non-monetary and financial institutions (non-MFI) reported by MFI excluding ESCB in the UK, Germany, France and Italy.
12
Using spectral analysis, Schuler et al. (2020) find that, although financial cycle durations vary greatly across countries, the average duration of financial cycles is also about 16 years.

References

  1. Baker, Sarah S., David Lopez-Salido, and Edward Nelson. 2018. The money view versus the credit view. In Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2018–042; Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Bernanke, Ben, and Mark Gertler. 1989. Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations. American Economic Review 79: 14–31. [Google Scholar]
  3. Bond, Philip, Alex Edmans, and Itay Goldstein. 2012. The real effects of financial markets. Annual Review of Financial Economics 4: 339–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Bordalo, Pedro, Nicola Gennaioli, and Andrei Shleifer. 2018. Diagnostic expectations and credit cycles. Journal of Finance 73: 199–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Borio, Claudio. 2014. The financial cycle and macroeconomics: What have we learnt? Journal of Banking and Finance 45: 182–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Borio, Claudio, Mathias Drehmann, and Dora Xia. 2018. The financial cycle and recession risk. BIS Quarterly Review 12: 59–71. [Google Scholar]
  7. Breitung, Jorg, and Norman R. Swanson. 2002. Temporal aggregation and spurious instantaneous causality in multiple time series models. Journal of Time Series Analysis 23: 651–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Claessens, Stijn, M. Ayhan Kose, and Marco E. Terrones. 2012. How do business and financial cycles interact? Journal of International Economics 87: 178–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Danielsson, Jon, Marcela Valenzuela, and Ilknur Zer. 2018. Learning from history: Volatility and financial crises. Review of Financial Studies 31: 2774–805. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Della Corte, Pasquale, Lucio Sarno, and Ilias Tsiakas. 2009. An economic evaluation of empirical exchange rate models. Review of Financial Studies 22: 3491–530. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. European Central Bank. 2018. Real and Financial Cycles in EU Countries: Stylized Facts and Modelling Implications. ECB Occasional Paper Series No. 205. Available online: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpops/ecb.op205.en.pdf (accessed on 19 September 2023).
  12. Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–960. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
  13. Galati, Gabriele, Irma Hindrayanto, Siem J. Koopman, and Marente Vlekke. 2016. Measuring financial cycles in a model-based analysis: Empirical evidence for the United States and the Euro area. Economics Letters 145: 83–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Ghysels, Eric. 2016. Macroeconomics and the reality of mixed frequency data. Journal of Econometrics 193: 294–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Ghysels, Eric, Jonathan B. Hill, and Kaiji Motegi. 2016. Testing for Granger causality with mixed frequency data. Journal of Econometrics 192: 207–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Ghysels, Eric, Jonathan B. Hill, and Kaiji Motegi. 2020. Testing a large set of zero restrictions in regression models with an application to mixed frequency Granger causality. Journal of Econometrics 218: 633–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Granger, Clive W. J. 1969. Investigating causal relations by econometric models and cross-spectral methods. Econometrica 37: 424–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Harding, Don, and Adrian Pagan. 2002. Dissecting the cycle: A methodological investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 49: 365–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Harvey, Andrew C., and Siem J. Koopman. 1997. Multivariate structural time series models. In System Dynamics in Economic and Financial Models. Edited by Christiaan Heij, Hans Schumacher, Bernard Hanzon and Kees Praagman. New York: Wiley. [Google Scholar]
  20. Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and John Moore. 1997. Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy 105: 211–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Koo, Richard. 2003. Balance Sheet Recession. Singapore: Wiley. [Google Scholar]
  22. Li, Jiahan, Ilias Tsiakas, and Wei Wang. 2015. Predicting exchange rates out of sample: Can economic fundamentals beat the random walk? Journal of Financial Econometrics 13: 293–341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Lopez-Salido, David, Jeremy C. Stein, and Egon Zakrajsek. 2017. Credit-market sentiment and the business cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics 132: 1373–421. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Minsky, Hyman. 1977. The financial instability hypothesis: An interpretation of Keynes and an alternative to “standard” theory. Nebraska Journal of Economics and Business 16: 5–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Prabheesh, K. P., Reza Anglingkusumo, and Solikin M. Juhro. 2021. The dynamics of global financial cycle and domestic economic cycles: Evidence from India and Indonesia. Economic Modelling 94: 831–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Rapach, David E., Jack K. Strauss, and Guofu Zhou. 2013. International stock return predictability: What is the role of the United States? Journal of Finance 68: 1633–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer. 2017. New evidence on the aftermath of financial crises in advanced countries. American Economic Review 107: 3072–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Runstler, Gerhard, and Marente Vlekke. 2018. Business, housing and credit cycles. Journal of Applied Econometrics 33: 212–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Sarno, Lucio, Ilias Tsiakas, and Barbara Ulloa. 2016. What drives international portfolio flows? Journal of International Money and Finance 60: 53–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Schularick, Moritz, and Alan M. Taylor. 2012. Credit booms gone bust: Monetary policy, leverage cycles, and financial crises, 1870–2008. American Economic Review 102: 1029–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Schuler, Yves S., Paul P. Hiebert, and Tuomas A. Peltonen. 2020. Financial cycles: Characterization and real-time measurement. Journal of International Money and Finance 100: 102082. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Sims, Christopher A. 1972. Money, income, and causality. American Economic Review 62: 540–52. [Google Scholar]
  33. Stockhammer, Engelbert, Robert C. Jump, Karsten Kohler, and Julian Cavallero. 2019. Short and medium term financial-real cycles: An empirical assessment. Journal of International Money and Finance 94: 81–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Strohsal, Till, Christian Proano, and Juergen Wolters. 2019. Characterizing the financial cycle: Evidence from a frequency domain analysis. Journal of Banking and Finance 106: 568–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Yan, Chuanpeng, and Kevin X. D. Huang. 2020. Financial cycle and business cycle: An empirical analysis based on the data from the U.S. Economic Modelling 93: 693–701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Industrial production causing credit—mixed frequency p-values. The p-value is estimated using a 20-year rolling window. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. The red horizontal line indicates the 0.10 value.
Figure 1. Industrial production causing credit—mixed frequency p-values. The p-value is estimated using a 20-year rolling window. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. The red horizontal line indicates the 0.10 value.
Jrfm 16 00430 g001
Figure 2. Credit causing industrial production—mixed frequency p-values. The p-value is estimated using a 20-year rolling window. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. The red horizontal line indicates the 0.10 value.
Figure 2. Credit causing industrial production—mixed frequency p-values. The p-value is estimated using a 20-year rolling window. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. The red horizontal line indicates the 0.10 value.
Jrfm 16 00430 g002
Figure 3. The US business cycle as a global leader—mixed frequency p-values. The p-value is estimated using a 20-year rolling window. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. The red horizontal line indicates the 0.10 value.
Figure 3. The US business cycle as a global leader—mixed frequency p-values. The p-value is estimated using a 20-year rolling window. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. The red horizontal line indicates the 0.10 value.
Jrfm 16 00430 g003
Figure 4. The US financial cycle as a global leader—mixed frequency p-values. The p-value is estimated using a 20-year rolling window. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. The red horizontal line indicates the 0.10 value.
Figure 4. The US financial cycle as a global leader—mixed frequency p-values. The p-value is estimated using a 20-year rolling window. The grey areas indicate recessions and severe recessions. The red horizontal line indicates the 0.10 value.
Jrfm 16 00430 g004
Table 1. Summary statistics.
Table 1. Summary statistics.
Sample Period
BeginEndMeanSt DevSkewKurtMinMaxAR(1)
Panel A: USA
IPI1962M12019M32.644.62−1.155.47−16.6512.560.98
GDP1962Q12019Q13.012.19−0.443.74−4.008.230.96
Credit1962Q12019Q13.114.77−0.542.90−10.5612.640.97
Panel B: Canada
IPI1962M12019M32.745.15−0.523.55−16.0115.810.96
GDP1962Q12019Q13.072.31−0.553.96−4.168.880.96
Credit1962Q12019Q16.675.770.143.20−9.6221.850.95
Panel C: UK
IPI1962M12019M31.023.86−0.575.62−12.7220.400.88
GDP1962Q12019Q12.342.24−0.875.41−6.289.300.92
Credit1964Q12019Q14.935.520.032.64−8.6017.650.96
Panel D: Germany
IPI1962M12019M32.175.48−1.267.71−27.4815.960.91
GDP1962Q12019Q12.332.36−0.484.89−7.299.650.91
Credit1962Q12019Q13.473.660.122.20−3.2812.390.98
Panel E: France
IPI1962M12019M31.735.050.2719.24−30.8249.300.79
GDP1962Q12019Q12.622.140.706.94−3.8714.400.89
Credit1970Q12019Q13.213.460.292.72−4.5711.940.97
Panel F: Italy
IPI1962M12019M31.776.18−0.876.57−29.8620.000.89
GDP1962Q12019Q12.242.79−0.053.65−7.449.400.93
Credit1975Q12019Q12.454.650.071.93−6.2212.230.95
Panel G: Japan
IPI1962M12019M33.277.96−0.997.14−40.5524.150.96
GDP1962Q12019Q13.543.700.403.39−9.0813.490.96
Credit1965Q12019Q13.294.990.502.83−9.3518.120.97
Notes: The table reports summary statistics for 100× annual log-difference of the monthly industrial production index (IPI), quarterly GDP and quarterly aggregate credit for the G7 countries. AR(1) is the serial correlation at one lag. All data are in real terms.
Table 2. Business and financial cycles.
Table 2. Business and financial cycles.
USACanadaUKGermanyFranceItalyJapan
Panel A: IPI (monthly)
Severe Recession−4.47−2.11−2.18−0.79−3.65−0.861.59
Recession−3.210.870.11−0.060.140.000.87
Expansion3.534.171.634.003.023.295.28
Panel B: GDP (quarterly)
Severe Recession−0.790.62−0.880.760.751.341.45
Recession−0.172.211.321.312.021.542.40
Expansion3.493.723.023.163.102.834.49
Panel C: Credit (quarterly)
Severe Recession−0.15−0.97−0.730.310.30−1.460.55
Recession−0.555.464.632.672.201.541.90
Expansion3.666.835.124.123.973.204.38
Notes: The table reports the mean of 100 × log-difference of the monthly industrial production index (IPI), quarterly GDP and quarterly aggregate credit during different phases of business and financial cycles. For the US, recessions and expansions exist according to the NBER. For the other G7 countries, recessions and expansions exist according to the OECD-based recession indicators. A severe recession is a business cycle recession that coincides with a financial cycle downturn. We report results for recessions exclusive of severe recessions. Financial cycle upturns and downturns are defined as in Claessens et al. (2012).
Table 3. Granger causality tests.
Table 3. Granger causality tests.
USACanadaUKGermanyFranceItalyJapan
Panel A: IPI and Credit—Mixed Frequency
IPI ↛ Credit0.003 **0.001 *** 0.328 0.244 0.002 ***0.002 *** 0.326
Credit ↛ IPI0.100 * 0.070 *0.046 ** 0.340 0.493 0.616 0.006 ***
Panel B: GDP and Credit—Quarterly Frequency
GDP ↛ Credit0.001 ***0.057 ** 0.771 0.521 0.094 ** 0.243 0.225
Credit ↛ GDP 0.127 0.472 0.064 **0.004 *** 0.540 0.074 *0.032 **
Notes: The table displays the p-value for the Wald test used to assess the Granger causality between (a) the industrial production index (IPI) and aggregate credit, and (b) GDP and credit. Panel A is for mixed frequency based on monthly IPI and quarterly credit, whereas Panel B is for quarterly GDP and quarterly credit. The notation, for example, “IPI ↛ Credit” denotes the null hypothesis of no causality from IPI to credit. The Wald test uses 12 monthly or 4 quarterly lags and is based on a heteroskedasticity-robust covariance matrix with 10,000 bootstrap replications. The full sample covers the sample periods reported in Table 1. *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.
Table 4. Granger causality tests: the US as a global leader.
Table 4. Granger causality tests: the US as a global leader.
CanadaUKGermanyFranceItalyJapan
Panel A: IPI and Credit—Mixed Frequency
IPI U S ↛ IPI o t h e r 0.001 ***0.100 *0.008 ***0.008 ***0.011 ** 0.480
IPI U S ↛ Credit o t h e r 0.135 0.644 0.098 *0.023 **0.025 **0.100 *
Credit U S ↛ IPI o t h e r 0.644 0.901 0.246 0.679 0.798 0.746
Credit U S ↛ Credit o t h e r 0.509 0.177 0.995 0.046 ** 0.143 0.025 **
Panel B: GDP and Credit—Quarterly Frequency
GDP U S ↛ GDP o t h e r 0.001 ***0.083 *0.004 *** 0.196 0.058 * 0.113
GDP U S ↛ Credit o t h e r 0.776 0.536 0.463 0.345 0.142 0.932
Credit U S ↛ GDP o t h e r 0.667 0.307 0.620 0.741 0.045 ** 0.359
Credit U S ↛ Credit o t h e r 0.284 0.524 0.558 0.235 0.083 * 0.519
Notes: The table displays the p-value for the Wald test used to assess the Granger causality between the US and another G7 country. Panel A is for mixed frequency based on monthly IPI and quarterly credit, whereas Panel B is for quarterly GDP and quarterly credit. The notation, for example “IPI U S ↛ Credit o t h e r ”, denotes the null hypothesis of no causality from the US IPI to another country’s credit. The Wald test uses 6 monthly lags or 2 quarterly lags and is based on a heteroskedasticity-robust covariance matrix with 1999 bootstrap replications. The full sample covers the sample periods reported in Table 1. *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.
Table 5. Granger causality across cycle phases.
Table 5. Granger causality across cycle phases.
USCanadaUKGermanyFranceItalyJapan
Panel A: IPI ↛ Credit—Mixed Frequency
Severe Recession1.000.660.330.691.000.680.67
Recession1.000.600.800.861.000.330.73
Expansion0.970.670.260.560.850.480.67
Panel B: Credit ↛ IPI—Mixed Frequency
Severe Recession0.540.210.100.070.040.080.39
Recession0.670.200.200.000.200.000.27
Expansion0.250.230.120.060.000.040.30
Panel C: GDP ↛ Credit—Quarterly Frequency
Severe Recession0.460.560.350.000.710.180.00
Recession0.330.600.400.000.600.000.00
Expansion0.710.630.360.000.880.040.00
Panel D: Credit ↛ GDP—Quarterly Frequency
Severe Recession0.230.380.270.170.220.210.07
Recession0.000.000.400.140.400.330.09
Expansion0.240.330.230.310.030.330.17
Notes: The table reports how often we observe statistically significant Granger causality (i.e., Wald p-value ≤ 0.1) for different phases of the business and financial cycles. Each entry is the frequency of statistically significant causality using a 20-year-rolling window. For example, a value of 1.00 in the upper left corner implies that IPI has significantly caused credit in the US 100% of the time during severe recessions.
Table 6. Granger causality across cycle phases: the US as a global leader.
Table 6. Granger causality across cycle phases: the US as a global leader.
Panel A: US causing Canada
IPI U S ↛ IPI C a n a d a GDP U S ↛ GDP C a n a d a
US CycleCanada CycleUS CycleCanada Cycle
Severe Recession0.540.610.770.82
Recession0.600.650.800.85
Expansion0.690.720.810.76
Panel B: US causing UK
IPI U S ↛ IPI U K GDP U S ↛ GDP U K
US CycleUK CycleUS CycleUK Cycle
Severe Recession0.310.310.000.14
Recession0.670.670.330.33
Expansion0.430.480.250.29
Panel C: US causing Germany
IPI U S ↛ IPI G e r m a n y GDP U S ↛ GDP G e r m a n y
US CycleGermany CycleUS CycleGermany Cycle
Severe Recession0.620.800.380.42
Recession0.800.850.600.63
Expansion0.760.700.360.31
Panel D: US causing France
IPI U S ↛ IPI F r a n c e GDP U S ↛ GDP F r a n c e
US CycleFrance CycleUS CycleFrance Cycle
Severe Recession0.770.840.230.41
Recession0.820.850.450.51
Expansion0.780.740.430.31
Panel E: US causing Italy
IPI U S ↛ IPI I t a l y GDP U S ↛ GDP I t a l y
US CycleItaly CycleUS CycleItaly Cycle
Severe Recession0.850.970.460.71
Recession1.000.980.570.71
Expansion0.960.940.750.76
Panel F: US causing Japan
IPI U S ↛ IPI J a p a n GDP U S ↛ GDP J a p a n
US CycleJapan CycleUS CycleJapan Cycle
Severe Recession0.460.540.230.42
Recession0.430.500.290.48
Expansion0.560.600.370.31
Notes: The table reports how often we observe statistically significant Granger causality (i.e., Wald p-value ≤ 0.1) for different phases of the business and financial cycles. Each entry is the frequency of statistically significant causality using a 20-year-rolling window. For example, a value of 0.54 in the upper left corner implies that IPI US has significantly caused IPI Canada 54% of the time during severe recessions according to the US cycle.
Table 7. Granger causality tests: the role of interest rates.
Table 7. Granger causality tests: the role of interest rates.
USCanadaUKGermanyFranceItalyJapan
Panel A: Individual Countries—Mixed Frequency
IPI ↛ Credit0.07 ***0.11 ***−0.04−0.09 ***0.010.12 ***−0.08 ***
Credit ↛ IPI0.02 *−0.01−0.01−0.030.11 ***−0.520.13 ***
Panel B: Individual Countries—Quarterly Frequency
GDP ↛ Credit0.04 ***−0.01−0.06−0.01−0.19 ***0.10 ***0.01
Credit ↛ GDP−0.07 ***0.06 ***0.10 ***0.09 ***0.20 ***−0.53 ***−0.26
Panel C: The US as a Global Leader—Mixed Frequency
IPI U S A ↛ IPI o t h e r -8.22 ***0.07 ***0.03−0.04 **−0.010.04 *
IPI U S A ↛ Credit o t h e r −0.18 ***−0.11 ***−0.05 *−0.11 ***0.03 **0.02
Credit U S A ↛ IPI o t h e r −0.04−0.15 ***0.05−0.07 *0.02 **−0.03
Credit U S A ↛ Credit o t h e r −0.09 *0.15 ***0.01−0.08 ***−0.10 ***−0.09 ***
Panel D: The US as a Global Leader—Quarterly Frequency
GDP U S A ↛ GDP o t h e r 0.11 **0.12 ***0.05 **−0.12 ***−0.18 ***0.12 ***
GDP U S A ↛ Credit o t h e r 0.030.23 ***0.01−0.010.04 ***0.01
Credit U S A ↛ GDP o t h e r −0.11 **−0.03 *0.05−0.01−0.04 *−0.07 *
Credit U S A ↛ Credit o t h e r −0.130.19 ***0.010.020.04 **−0.01
Notes: The table reports the relation between Granger causality and the nominal interest rate. Panels A and B display the β i estimates from the probit model: P i , t = α i + β i r i , t + ε i , t , for country i at time t, where P i , t is a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if causality for country i at time t is significant at the 10% level, and 0 otherwise, and r i , t is the nominal interest rate of country i at time t. Panel B shows the β i estimates from the probit model: P U S A , i , t = α i + β i ( r i , t r U S A , t ) + ε U S A , i , t , where i refers to a country other than the USA, and P U S A , i , t is a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if causality from the USA to another country i is significant at 10%, and 0 otherwise. *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.
Table 8. Summary statistics for housing and equity prices.
Table 8. Summary statistics for housing and equity prices.
Sample Period
FreqBeginEndMeanSt DevSkewKurtMinMaxAR(1)
Panel A: USA
EPIM1971012019M33.0716.81−0.934.20−66.2939.090.94
EPIQ1971Q12019Q13.3918.330.120.74−42.3468.710.85
HPIQ1971Q12019Q11.544.03−1.054.10−13.387.830.96
Panel B: Canada
EPIM1971012019M32.4918.28−0.583.99−66.5354.520.93
EPIQ1971Q12019Q13.3413.39−0.570.49−40.5737.040.86
HPIQ1971Q12019Q12.856.08−0.114.57−18.7722.400.89
Panel C: UK
EPIM1971012019M31.2619.15−1.538.52−101.6963.700.92
EPIQ1971Q12019Q11.8225.091.363.41−47.86106.150.88
HPIQ1969Q12019Q13.169.230.213.44−19.3932.740.95
Panel D: Germany
EPIM1971012019M32.3921.76−0.493.58−80.4859.750.94
EPIQ1971Q12019Q14.1515.440.223.83−50.9280.740.81
HPIQ1971Q12019Q10.312.770.242.41−5.507.110.89
Panel E: France
EPIM1971012019M32.1622.87−0.533.24−76.6561.400.94
EPIQ1971Q12019Q12.7914.81−0.160.85−39.2947.610.82
HPIQ1971Q12019Q11.904.890.042.37−8.0613.080.97
Panel F: Italy
EPIM1971012019M30.8028.100.303.50−76.7095.200.90
EPIQ1971Q12019Q10.7917.740.09−0.15−45.5951.930.85
HPIQ1971Q12019Q10.939.301.597.30−19.4543.930.87
Panel G: Japan
EPIM1971012019M32.5122.69−0.183.33−66.3769.510.95
EPIQ1971Q12019Q13.5218.800.460.56−43.0759.530.85
HPIQ1962Q12019Q11.776.300.163.74−18.2720.840.96
Notes: The table reports summary statistics for 100 × annual log-difference of the monthly equity price index (EPI), the quarterly EPI, and the quarterly housing price index (HPI). AR(1) is the serial correlation at one lag. All data are in real terms.
Table 9. Granger causality tests for housing and equity prices.
Table 9. Granger causality tests for housing and equity prices.
USACanadaUKGermanyFranceItalyJapan
Panel A: IPI (M) and EPI (M)—Monthly Frequency
IPI ↛ EPI0.3520.017 **0.012 **0.4320.096 *0.031 **0.270
EPI ↛ IPI0.001 ***0.001 ***0.076 *0.015 **0.003 ***0.013 **0.226
Panel B: GDP (Q) and EPI (M)—Mixed Frequency
GDP ↛ EPI0.1450.083 *0.5100.6060.063 *0.1860.100 *
EPI ↛ GDP0.003 ***0.002 ***0.084 *0.001 ***0.011 **0.003 ***0.001 ***
Panel C: GDP (Q) and EPI (Q)—Quarterly Frequency
GDP ↛ EPI0.7820.028 **0.2670.7410.4200.1150.703
EPI ↛ GDP0.031 **0.001 ***0.1110.001 ***0.0930.2100.020 **
Panel D: IPI (M) and HPI (Q)—Mixed Frequency
IPI ↛ HPI0.1980.004 ***0.001 ***0.4830.1110.002 ***0.080 *
HPI ↛ IPI0.026 **0.1150.1430.6490.010 ***0.022 **0.072 *
Panel E: GDP (Q) and HPI (Q)—Quarterly Frequency
GDP ↛ HPI0.8450.2050.092 *0.1770.3900.077 *0.295
HPI ↛ GDP0.1340.010 **0.026 **0.3290.7290.6120.019 **
Notes: The table displays the p-value for the Wald test used to assess the Granger causality between pairs of IPI (industrial production index), GDP, the equity price index (EPI) and the housing price index (HPI). The results are for monthly, mixed and quarterly frequency depending on the frequency of available data. M stands monthly and Q for quarterly. The notation, for example, “IPI ↛ EPI” denotes the null hypothesis of no causality from IPI to EPI. The Wald test uses 12 monthly or 4 quarterly lags and is based on a heteroskedasticity-robust covariance matrix with 10,000 bootstrap replications. The full sample covers the sample periods reported in Table 8. *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.
Table 10. Summary statistics—monthly European data.
Table 10. Summary statistics—monthly European data.
Sample Period
BeginEndMeanSt DevSkewKurtMinMaxAR(1)
Panel A: UK
IPI2000M12019M31.004.57−1.004.88−16.0110.600.95
Credit2000M12019M31.898.08−0.182.49−17.7420.860.92
Panel B: Germany
IPI1998M92019M31.134.24−2.228.71−16.658.120.98
Credit1998M92019M3−1.082.27−0.142.16−6.323.720.95
Panel C: France
IPI1998M92019M3−0.292.94−1.787.59−12.205.300.89
Credit1998M92019M32.823.120.522.66−3.4910.350.98
Panel D: Italy
IPI1998M92019M31.686.33−1.879.15−27.4814.500.94
Credit1998M92019M33.195.170.292.66−6.4517.420.98
Notes: The table reports summary statistics for 100× annual log-difference of the monthly industrial production index (IPI) and the monthly aggregate credit for four European countries for which monthly credit data are available. AR(1) is the serial correlation at one lag. All data are in real terms.
Table 11. Granger causality tests—monthly European data.
Table 11. Granger causality tests—monthly European data.
IPI and Credit—Monthly Frequency
UKGermanyFranceItaly
IPI ↛ Credit0.097 * 0.224 0.001 *** 0.138
Credit ↛ IPI0.057 * 0.422 0.066 * 0.614
Notes: The table displays the p-value for the Wald test used to assess the Granger causality between the monthly industrial production index (IPI) and monthly aggregate credit for the four European countries for which monthly credit data are available. The notation, for example, “IPI ↛ Credit”, denotes the null hypothesis of no causality from IPI to credit. The Wald test uses 12 monthly or 4 quarterly lags and is based on a heteroskedasticity-robust covariance matrix with 10,000 bootstrap replications. The full sample covers the sample periods reported in Table 10. *, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Tsiakas, I.; Zhang, H. On the Direction of Causality between Business and Financial Cycles. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2023, 16, 430. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16100430

AMA Style

Tsiakas I, Zhang H. On the Direction of Causality between Business and Financial Cycles. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2023; 16(10):430. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16100430

Chicago/Turabian Style

Tsiakas, Ilias, and Haibin Zhang. 2023. "On the Direction of Causality between Business and Financial Cycles" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 16, no. 10: 430. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16100430

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop