Next Article in Journal
Crisis and the Role of Money in the Real and Financial Economies—An Innovative Approach to Monetary Stimulus
Next Article in Special Issue
Recent Patterns of Economic Alignment in the European (Monetary) Union
Previous Article in Journal
Financial Crises, Macroeconomic Variables, and Long-Run Risk: An Econometric Analysis of Stock Returns Correlations (2000 to 2019)
Previous Article in Special Issue
Divergence Tendencies in the European Integration Process: A Danger for the Sustainability of the E(M)U?
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Estimating the Growth Effects of 2004 Eastern Enlargement of the European Union

by
Andrzej Cieślik
1,* and
Mehmet Burak Turgut
2
1
Department of Macroeconomics and International Trade Theory, Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw, 00-241 Warsaw, Poland
2
CASE—Center for Social and Economic Research, 01-031 Warsaw, Poland
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14(3), 128; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14030128
Submission received: 25 February 2021 / Revised: 10 March 2021 / Accepted: 16 March 2021 / Published: 20 March 2021
(This article belongs to the Special Issue European Market Integration and the Economic Development)

Abstract

:
In this paper, we study the growth effects of the 2004 Eastern enlargement of the European Union (EU) using the synthetic control method. We estimate that this EU enlargement had an immediate but modest positive impact on the economic growth of the EU-8 countries in the first few years following their EU accession. The positive impact of the EU enlargement became more apparent from 2007 when the new EU member states were admitted into the Schengen zone. As a result, the gross domestic product (GDP) per capita difference between the actual and synthetic EU-8 continued to grow towards the end of the sample period. We found that over the entire 2004–2012 period, GDP per capita of the EU-8 was increased by about 2313 USD per year on average relative to the synthetic EU-8. The growth rate of the GDP per capita in the actual EU-8 for the same period was 2.7% larger than the synthetic EU-8.

1. Introduction

The process of economic integration has experienced unprecedented progress since the beginning of the second half of the 20th century. The European Union (EU) is a prominent example of this progress and is considered as the economic integration case in the most integrated form around the world today. The foundations of the European Union go back to 1952 when the six nations decided to form the European Coal and Steel Community. The Treaty of Rome signed in 1957 followed this movement and created the European Economic Community. The European Union was formally established in 1993 with 12 members when the Maastricht treaty came into force in 1993 and reached 15 member states in 1995.
The largest enlargement of the European Union took place in 2004 and incorporated 10 new economies, mainly the Central and Eastern European (CEE) countries. This was the biggest single enlargement in terms of the number of people, and the number of countries, but not in terms of GDP as these countries were much poorer compared to the old members of the EU. The less developed nature of these countries was of concern to some of the older member states due to the increased pressure on the EU budget. The eight CEE countries included: the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia, and Slovenia, plus two small Mediterranean island countries: Malta and Cyprus that were able to join on 1 May 2004. As the CEE countries are similar in many aspects, this provides interesting background for research. A substantial part of these countries belonged to the former Soviet Union (USSR; Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania) or were controlled by it through the Warsaw Pact and the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON). Since the break-up of the USSR, their development patterns and gross domestic product (GDP) levels have been comparable. Therefore, in this paper we focus on the EU accession-induced growth effects for the eight CEE countries only.
The process of European economic integration poses some questions of great importance both from an academic point of view and from an economic policy and public perspective: is economic integration beneficial to the CEE economies and does it proceed in the right direction? Should the CEE countries tighten co-operation and enhance further unification with the EU? It is also possible to generalize results from testing the growth effects of accession to the EU to assess whether integration is generally beneficial for relatively new participating economies and economies that are about to join it. For example, if the CEE economies increase their growth rates and indeed catch up towards the EU-15, the results may be also true for Serbia and Montenegro, which are currently negotiating EU accession. To conclude, the main objective of this study is to assess whether there are positive growth effects of accession to the EU on the CEE economies.
The ideal environment to accomplish our objective would be to observe the counterfactual, economic growth of the CEE countries in a hypothetical world where the CEE countries had not gained accession to the EU, and compare the actual growth with the counterfactual ones. However, we only observe the growth rates of the CEE countries after their accession to the EU. Hence, the difficulty arises due to the inability to observe the counterfactual data. We tackle this difficulty using the synthetic control method. The applicability of the synthetic control method requires the availability of countries that share similar characteristics with the CEE countries before their accession to the EU. The countries that gained independence from the former USSR and Yugoslavia but did not gain accession to the EU help us to fulfil this requirement. These countries and the CEE countries were both ruled under communist regimes until the late 1980s and early 1990s. Their economies functioned under a centrally planned economy and converted to market economies only after the communist regimes ended. Hence, they share similar economic and institutional characteristics which will help us to implement the synthetic control method.
The novelty of this study that distinguishes it from previous ones is the innovative framework to estimate the growth effect of 2004 EU enlargement on new members. We design an environment to mimic an experimental research design using observational data by studying the effect of a treatment, EU accession in 2004, on a treatment group, the CEE countries that became EU members in 2004, versus a control group, the countries that did not gain accession to the EU, in a natural experiment. The synthetic control method provides attractive features relative to traditional regression methods such as measuring dynamic effects, dealing with time-varying omitted variables, transparency, and safeguard against extrapolation. The standard panel or difference-in-differences approaches can measure the average effect of the EU accession whereas the synthetic control permits us to estimate dynamic effects of EU accession. The year-by-year match during the pre-intervention period between the treated group and its synthetic control allows us to control for the time-varying confounding factors whereas methods such as panel fixed-effects or difference-in-differences can only account for time-invariant or common trend confounders. The synthetic control method is a weighted average of the control units (e.g., countries) and transparency can be observed through the explicit contribution of each control unit to the counterfactual and the similarities between the treatment group and the synthetic control group. Because the weights for the synthetic control can be restricted to be positive and sum to one, the method provides a safeguard against extrapolation where the same is not true for regression since regression weights may be outside the [0,1] interval (see Abadie et al. 2015, for a thorough discussion).
The structure of this paper is as follows. Section 2 presents the review of relevant literature. Section 3 describes the synthetic control method that we use as our main research methodology. Section 4 provides data description. Section 5 reports and interprets our empirical results. Section 6 presents the results of the placebo studies. Final section summarizes and concludes.

2. Literature Review

There are two main strands in the theory of economic growth literature that study the effects of economic integration on growth: neoclassical and endogenous growth theory. The neoclassical growth theory postulates that economic integration increases the growth rate only during the transition period without an impact on steady-state growth since the latter is solely determined by the exogenous rate of technological progress (see Barro and Sala-i-Martin 2004, for a review). Baldwin (1993) shows that this temporary effect can be divided into static and dynamic effects. The sources of static effect are lower trade costs, increased competition and enhanced factor mobility whereas the source of dynamic effects is the increased capital accumulation as a result of higher investment resulting from the higher output and the constant output-investment ratio.
However, the impact of economic integration on growth is mixed according to endogenous growth theories. Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991) extend the horizontally differentiated products frameworks of Grossman and Helpman (1990) and Romer (1990) by incorporating two identical countries and they find scale effect, larger innovation rate as a result of larger public knowledge, and redundancy effect, avoidance of duplicative research and development (R&D) efforts, of R&D sector integration where both effects lead to higher growth rate in the steady-state. The positive growth impact of economic integration through its scale effect can be also found in Razin and Yuen (1996) as a result of labor migration and in Walz (1997a) as a result of foreign direct investment.
The Rivera-Batiz and Xie (1993) find mixed results when the economies are heterogenous in Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991) frameworks. They find a lower innovation rate and growth in the country with a larger skilled labor force whereas the opposite holds for the other country. Walz (1997b) argues that customs union can increase or decrease growth depending on the trade creation and diversion effects.
In more recent papers, Peretto (2003) obtains a higher growth rate when the economies are integrated in a world populated by the global oligopolists due to the larger body of technological spillovers that support faster growth. Brou and Ruta (2011) incorporate an economic market where firms compete for market share and a political market where firms compete for government transfers into the endogenous growth framework. They conclude that economic integration can lead to more innovation and faster growth when it is accompanied by political integration. Otherwise, economic integration can lead to less innovation and slower growth as firms focus more on rent-seeking activity due to increased competition in the economic market.
The results of existing empirical studies concerned with the long-term growth effects of European economic integration are also rather inconclusive. Landau (1995) obtains no effect of European Community (EC) membership on growth in a sample of 17 Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries in the period of 1950–1990. This result is confirmed in the study by Vanhoudt (1999) in which the author finds no growth effects of European integration for the members in comparison to non-member OECD countries. In contrast, Henrekson et al. (1997) provide evidence for permanent growth effects of EC membership using cross-sectional growth regressions for a sample of 115 countries. Torstensson (1999) identifies a positive impact of economic integration on economic growth through investment and knowledge transfers in an analysis of a data panel consisting of 20 OECD countries. Badinger (2005) finds no permanent growth effects of European integration although he finds temporary growth effects and concludes that “GDP per capita of the EU would be approximately one fifth lower today, if no economic integration had taken place since 1950”.
In more recent papers, Cuaresma et al. (2013) find that the EU membership has a significant and positive effect on the economic growth and this effect is more pronounced for poorer countries after using panel-data methods. In the following work, Cuaresma et al. (2016) project slower income convergence across European countries as a result of the current demographic trends. They claim that lowering the educational attainment gap between the member states that joined the EU in 2004 and the rest of the EU along with increasing labor force participation can restore the income convergence into an accelerated path.
The related concept to the growth effects of European integration is the income convergence debate in the context of European integration which received attention following the expansion of the European Union in 2004. The studies by Vojinović and Oplotnik (2008), Vojinović et al. (2009, 2010) and Próchniak and Witkowski (2013) find income convergence among the new EU member states and between the CEE-8 and the EU-15, with slight differences in the estimated speed of convergence. On the other hand, Allington and McCombie (2007) estimate a relatively poor convergence for the members located at the EU periphery both amongst themselves and in clubs with the old EU countries. Cavenaile and Dubois (2011), using a panel approach to the neoclassical convergence equation, find that the new EU member states and the old EU members are in different groups of convergence.
Monfort et al. (2013) use econometric techniques based on factor analysis to study real convergence in GDP per worker in the enlarged EU. Their evidence points to significant productivity divergences across countries. In particular, they identify different income convergence within the EU-14 and the new EU member states. Borsi and Metiu (2015) investigate the evolution of convergence in the enlarged EU between 1970 and 2010 through the application of the Phillips and Sul (2007a, 2007b, 2009) framework which accounts for heterogeneity in technological progress across countries. They do not obtain any evidence that supports real income per capita convergence in the EU. Instead, they identify several groups of countries that converge to their separate steady-states.
Most recently, Cieślik and Wciślik (2020) study the converge within CEE-8 and EU-15 and between those using a time-varying factor model a la Phillips and Sul (2007a, 2007b). They identify convergence within CEE-8 but do not identify convergence between CEE-8 and EU-15. However, their results show convergence of the CEE-8 towards two largest EU countries: Germany and France. Finally, Akhvlediani and Cieślik (2020) estimate growth regressions using the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) estimation method for the period 1950 to 2014 based on panel data to examine the impact of human capital on total factor productivity growth. Their results do not favour the convergence of all countries in the sample to the technological frontier. Moreover, their estimates suggest that the peripheral EU countries show only a weak convergence rate due to insufficient investment in human capital.
In terms of our research methodology our paper belongs to the literature that uses the synthetic control method (SCM) as an alternative approach to the standard panel data econometric methods. The main difficulty in econometric studies based on such methods is the identification of a proper benchmark for comparison which the SCM literature is able to satisfactorily address. The SCM is originally proposed by Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003). The authors study the economic impact of terrorism in the Basque Country by constructing a synthetic Basque country as a combination of two Spanish regions and measuring the economic growth that would have occurred in the Basque Country without terrorism. In the following work, in their study of the effect of a large-scale tobacco-control program legislated in California in 1988, Abadie et al. (2010) use a combination of five US states to approximate the cigarette sales that would have happened in California in the absence of legislation. More recently, Abadie et al. (2015) construct synthetic West Germany using five OECD countries to estimate the effect of the 1990 German unification on West Germany’s economic growth. Their results indicate a negative impact of reunification on real GDP per capita in West Germany between 1992–2003.
The closest to our paper is the recent study by Campos et al. (2019) who employ the SCM to the four EU enlargement periods and estimate the effect of the EU membership on real GDP per capita separately for each country. For the CEE countries, their results generally provide mixed evidence of the growth effects of EU integration when the EU accession date is set to 2004. The authors estimate positive growth effects when the EU accession date is set to 1998. This leaves only 4 years of pre-intervention data to construct synthetic control which may seem relatively short compared to other studies (see Abadie and Gardeazabal 2003; Abadie et al. 2015). However, our estimation indicates positive growth effects of EU integration when the accession date is set to the original date of 2004. The other important differences between their approach and our approach are following. First, our group of potential countries for the control group includes countries that are the part of the former USSR and Yugoslavia whereas their group mostly includes countries from Latin America and Asia and only 3 former communist countries. We believe this is an important issue since the countries in the potential group should share similar characteristics with the CEE countries through history or institutions; otherwise, there is a risk of overfitting. Second, we use a longer time span whereas Campos et al. (2019) end their sample period in 2008. Since the objective of the analysis is to estimate effects of EU membership on the long-run growth and some changes in the economy due to the EU accession may take some time, we believe longer sample period is more suitable for the analysis and likely to bring more reliable results. Third, they conduct analysis separately for each CEE country to address the country heterogeneity whereas we group the CEE countries and treat them as a single unit. We believe country heterogeneity is not a major issue for the CEE countries since they share similar past and characteristics. However, treating the CEE countries as single unit avoids the potential spillover effects. The other potential problem of constructing synthetic control separately for each CEE country from the same group of potential countries could be poor fitting of pre-intervention variables between the CEE countries and the synthetic control. This problem is visible in Figure 3 on page 95 of Campos et al. (2019) for some countries regarding pre-EU accession GDP per capita, and on Table A.2 in their Online Appendix regarding pre-EU accession predictors. Since these countries mostly share borders with each other and have strong economic linkages, a country enjoying positive growth from EU membership can spill over this growth to the EU member neighbouring country through these linkages. Hence, the growth in the neighbouring countries cannot be totally attributed to EU membership. Our approach of grouping the CEE countries addresses this problem. We are aware that spillovers can also occur for the potential control countries. We discuss this issue in detail in the concluding section.

3. The Synthetic Control Method

The SCM is a statistical method used in comparative case studies to evaluate the effect of an treatment or intervention. It involves a treatment group, a unit or units that receive the treatment, and the construction of a control group, a weighted combination of untreated units that best resembles the treatment group before the occurrence of the treatment. The comparison between the treatment and control groups after the treatment is used to estimate the effect of the treatment.
Below we provide only a short overview of the SCM as the details of this methodology can be found in Abadie et al. (2010) and Abadie et al. (2015). Suppose that we observe J + 1 units (e.g., countries) indexed by j , among whom unit j = 1 is the “treated unit”, the unit exposed to the treatment or intervention, and units j = 2 to j = J + 1 compose the “donor pool”, a group of potential control units that are not exposed to the treatment or intervention. In our case, as we will see later, the treated unit will be the population-weighted average of 8 CEE countries (EU-8) and the donor pool will be a group of 8 countries mostly with communist backgrounds that did not become members of the EU during the period of analysis.
We assume that the variables related to the all units of the sample are observed at the time periods from t = 1 to t = T . Furthermore, we assume that the time periods are composed of two parts: pre-intervention periods from t = 1 to t = T 0 in which the intervention has no effect and post-intervention periods from t = T 0 + 1 to t = T in which the “treated unit” is exposed to the intervention (in our case accession to the EU). In this format, the date when the intervention sets out is given by T 0 + 1 . Furthermore, we label the post-intervention period as T 1 = T 0 + 1 , , T .
Finally, assume that X 1 is a ( K × 1 ) vector with the values of the pre-intervention characteristics of the treated unit, and X 0 is a ( K × J ) matrix with the values of the pre-intervention characteristics for the units in the donor pool. There are K number of pre-intervention characteristics and these should include variables that are important predictors of the outcome variable, in our case real GDP per capita, for the post-intervention period.
The synthetic control of the treated unit is defined as a weighted average of the units in the donor pool that best mimics the pre-intervention characteristics of the treated unit. Let W be a ( J × 1 ) vector of weights such that W = ( w 2 , ,   w J + 1 ) , with 0 w J 1 for j = 2 ,     J and w 2 , ,   w J + 1 = 1 . Hence, the value of W defines the synthetic control. The crucial point here is how to choose the value of W . The literature proposes to select the synthetic control, W * , that minimizes the difference between the pre-intervention characteristics of the treated unit and a synthetic control that is given by the vector X 1 X 0 W (see Abadie and Gardeazabal 2003; Abadie et al. 2010; for a thorough discussion). Consider the following problem:
min W W ( X 1 X 0 W ) V ( X 1 X 0 W ) ,
where W = { ( w 2 , ,   w J + 1 )   subject   to   0 w J 1   for   j = 2 , J   and   w 2 , ,   w J + 1 = 1 } and V is a diagonal matrix of which the values of its diagonal elements reflect the relative importance of the pre-intervention characteristics in X 0 and X 1 . The solution to the problem in Equation (1) gives the vector W * that defines the synthetic control, the combination of units from the donor pool which best proxies the actual EU-8 in pre-intervention characteristics. An important point in the above problem is that the solution vector W * depends on the diagonal matrix V . The procedure for selecting the matrix V is following. Let Z 1 be a ( T 0 × 1 ) vector containing the real GDP per capita values of the EU-8 during the pre-EU accession period and Z 0 be a ( T 0 × J ) vector containing the real GDP per capita values of the potential control countries for the same period as well. Consider the following problem:
  min V V ( X 1 X 0 W * ( V ) ) V ( X 1 X 0 W * ( V ) ) ,
where V is the set of all non-negative diagonal ( K × K ) matrices. The solution to the above problem is given by V * and the weights for the synthetic control is given by W * ( V * ) . This procedure selects V such that pre-EU accession GDP per capita for the EU-8 is best reproduced by the synthetic control defined by W * ( V * ) .
The effect of intervention (treatment) estimated by the SCM is given by the difference of the post-intervention outcomes between the treated unit and the synthetic control. Let Y 1 be a ( T 1 × 1 ) vector whose elements are the post-intervention values of the outcome for the treated unit and let Y 0 be a ( T 1 × J ) matrix which contains the values of the outcome variable for the control units. Then, the synthetic control estimator is given by:
Y 1 Y 0 W * = t = T 0 + 1 T ( Y 1 t j = 2 J + 1 w j * Y j t ) ,
where w j * is the weight in vector W * for   j = 2 , J . In Equation (3), Y 0 W * is the outcome variable of the synthetic control, in our case real GDP per capita of synthetic EU-8, whereas Y 1 is the actual outcome variable of the treated unit, in our case real GDP per capita of the EU-8. In short, the SCM estimates the impact of an intervention by comparing the actual outcome and its counterfactual during the post-intervention period.
The inference with SCM is done by falsification exercises, so-called placebo studies. The use of standard (large-sample) inferential techniques in SMC is difficult because of the small-sample nature of the data (see Billmeier and Nannicini 2013). The idea behind the placebo studies is to test whether similar effects of artificial intervention is observed for the untreated units, “in-space placebos”, or for the dates when the intervention did not take place, “in-time placebos”. The confidence on the estimated effects of intervention would be undermined if similar or larger effects are obtained when the intervention is artificially reassigned to units not directly exposed to the intervention or when the SCM is applied to date when the intervention did not occur.
Following Abadie et al. (2015), we use root mean square prediction error (RMSPE) to evaluate the in-space placebos. RMSPE measures the difference between values of the actual outcome variable and its synthetic counterpart for any particular country. The pre-intervention RMSPE for unit i is defined as:
R M S P E i = ( 1 T 0 t = 1 T 0 ( Y i t j = 2 J + 1 w j * Y j t ) 2 ) 1 / 2 ,
where T 0 is the last year of pre-intervention period, Y i t is the GDP per capita of the treatment group, J is the number of countries in the control group (door pool), w j * is the synthetic control weights, and Y j t   is the GDP per capita for the country j in the control group. The similar RMSPE obtained from the actually treated unit and the artificially treated unit would dissipate the validity of the effect estimated by SCM.
As discussed in the Introduction, the SCM has some advantages such as measuring dynamic effects, dealing with time-varying omitted variables, and transparency; however, it comes with some limitations as well. The synthetic control estimator is a suitable application if there is a good fit between Z 0 W * and Z 1 . The SCM is not recommondable if the fit is poor between Z 0 W * and Z 1 (see Abadie et al. 2010). The units in the control and treatment groups should share similar pre-intervention characteristics; otherwise, there are risks of interpolation bias and overfitting.The units in the donor pool should not be affected by the intervention or by events of similar nature. Besides, the untreated units that may have suffered large idiosyncratic shocks to the outcome of interest during the post-intervention period may cause bias in the estimated effect of the intervention. Finally, a sizable number of pre-intervention periods are necessary, especially if the effect of intervention takes place gradually.

4. Data and Synthetic European Union (EU)-8

The synthetic control method requires two types of country or country groups for the analysis; the first group is the treatment group which consists of the countries that gained accession to the EU in 2004 and the second group is the control group which consists of the countries that do not gain access to the EU but their weighted average resembles to the values of treatment group’s pre-accession economic growth predictors. We include 8 countries in the treatment group that became part of the EU in 2004: the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia, and Slovenia. These countries are called the EU-8. The potential countries for the control group, donor pool, are: Albania, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Croatia, Georgia, Israel, Kazakhstan, Montenegro, North Macedonia, Republic of Moldova, Russian Federation, Serbia, Ukraine. These countries share common characteristics with the countries in the treatment group due to the historical links or communist past which motivated us to include them in the donor pool. In addition to not having an accession to the EU, the countries in the donor pool should have characteristics similar to the treated countries to avoid overfitting.
We use annual country-level balanced panel data for the period 1994–2012. The accession of the EU-8 countries to the European Union took place in 2004, giving us 10 years of pre-intervention data. Our sample period begins in 1994 due to data availability since most of the countries in our treatment and control groups either gained independence or switched to market economy in the early 1990s. The sample period ends in 2012 because Croatia, the country in the control group, became a member of the EU on 1 July 2013. Moreover, a decade-long period after the 2004 enlargement gives enough data points for a reliable estimation of the effect of EU accession. Another rationale to end the sample in 2012 is that Ukraine received huge negative idiosyncratic shock in 2014 and following years due to revolutions and civil unrest set out in 2014. We conduct a sensitivity analysis in Section 6.2 where we drop Croatia and Ukraine from the donor pool and extend the sample until 2019 to benefit from the most recent data.
We provide a list of all variables used in the analysis in the data Appendix A, along with data sources. The outcome variable, Y i t , is the real GDP per capita in country i at time t. GDP is expenditure-side real GDP at chained purchasing power parity (PPP) and measured in 2017 U.S. dollars (USD, hereafter). For the pre-EU accession characteristics in X 1 and X 0 , we use a standard set of economic growth predictors: the human capital index, the investment rate, the government consumption rate, total factor productivity, trade openness, and the price level. The total factor productivity variable is only available for the following countries in our donor pool: Armenia, Croatia, Israel, Kazakhstan, Republic of Moldova, Russian Federation, Serbia, Ukraine. Hence, our donor pool shrinks to 8 countries from 14.
To have a suitable control group for the EU-8 and to accurately reproduce the pre-2004 GDP per capita path for the EU-8, we construct the synthetic EU-8 as the convex combination of countries in the donor pool that most closely resembled the EU-8 in terms of pre-EU accession values of GDP per capita predictors. Table 1 shows the weights of each country in the synthetic version of EU-8. The synthetic EU-8 is a weighted average of Croatia, Israel, Armenia, and Ukraine. All other countries in the donor pool obtain zero weights.
Table 2 compares the pre-treatment (pre-EU accession) characteristics of the actual EU-8 with that of the synthetic EU-8, as well as with the population-weighted average of the 8 countries in the donor pool. The results in Table 2 suggest that the synthetic EU-8 provides a better comparison for the EU-8 than the average of our sample of potential control countries. The synthetic EU-8 is very similar to the actual EU-8 in terms of pre-2004 real GDP per capita, investment and government consumption rates, total factor productivity, and trade openness. The average of the potential countries matches closer to the actual EU-8 for human capital index and price level; however, the differences in these predictors between synthetic EU-8 and average of the potential control are minimal.

5. Results

Figure 1 displays the GDP per capita path of EU-8 and its synthetic counterpart for the 1994–2012 period. The synthetic EU-8 almost exactly reproduces the GDP per capita for the actual EU-8 during the entire pre-EU accession period that is 1994–2003. The close fit we obtain for the pre-EU accession GDP per capita in Figure 1 and the GDP predictors in Table 2 indicate that a combination of countries from our donor pool reproduces the economic characteristics of EU-8 countries before they became members of the European Union. This implies that the synthetic control method is an appropriate tool for our analysis and to estimate the impact of EU accession on economic growth.
Figure 2 displays our estimate of the effect of the EU 2004 enlargement on GDP per capita in EU-8 countries that is the difference between the actual EU-8 and its synthetic version. We estimate that EU enlargement has an immediate but modest positive impact on the economic growth of the EU-8 countries in the first few years following their EU accession. The positive impact of the EU enlargement becomes more apparent starting with 2007 when the new EU member states were admitted into the Schengen zone and could fully benefit from the Single Market. As a result, the GDP per capita difference between the actual and synthetic EU-8 continues to grow towards the end of the sample period. Thus, our results suggest a pronounced positive effect of EU enlargement on the economic growth of the EU-8 countries. We find that over the entire 2004–2012 period, GDP per capita of the EU-8 was increased by about 2313 USD per year on average relative to the synthetic EU-8. The growth rate of the GDP per capita in the actual EU-8 for the same period was 2.7% larger than the synthetic EU-8. In 2012, per capita GDP in the actual EU-8 is estimated to be about 19% higher than in the synthetic EU-8.

6. Placebo Studies and Sensitivity Analysis

6.1. Placebo Studies

We conduct placebo studies following Bertrand et al. (2004) and Abadie et al. (2015) to assess the credibility of our results. We run two placebo studies; first is “in-time placebo” where the treatment is reassigned in the data to a year other than 2004 and second is “in-space placebo” where the treatment is reassigned to countries different than EU-8. For the “in-time placebo” study, we rerun the model after reassigning the EU enlargement date to the year 2000, 4 years earlier than the actual EU enlargement, and compare the EU enlargement effect estimated above for EU-8 to the effect obtained when the enlargement date is assigned to the year 2000. We chose this data because many CEE countries that submitted their applications for full membership in the mid-1990s and were hoping to become members in 2000. This date would also help to assess whether there were any anticipation effects and the impact of EU membership started before the official accession date. If the comparison manifests similar effects, then our interpretation is that our analysis does not provide significant evidence of a positive effect of EU enlargement on economic growth.
Figure 3 displays the results of this “in-time placebo” study. The synthetic EU-8 almost exactly reproduces the GDP per capita trajectory in the actual EU-8 for the 1994–1999 period. More importantly, the evolution of the GDP per capita for the EU-8 and its synthetic counterpart do not diverge during the 2000–2004 period. That is, in contrast to the actual 2004 EU enlargement, our 2000 placebo enlargement has no perceivable effect on the economic growth of the EU-8. This suggests that the positive gap estimated in Figure 1 and Figure 2 reflects the growth enhancing impact of the EU enlargement that took place in 2004 and was not driven by chance.
For the “in-space placebo” study, we rerun our model each time by reassigning the accession to the integration to one of the 8 control countries and shifting EU-8 to the donor pool. In other words, we create 8 scenarios, and in each scenario, we allow one of the countries in the donor pool to gain accession to the economic integration in 2004, instead of EU-8 countries. In this way, we obtain synthetic control estimates for countries that did not experience the economic integration, accession to the EU. We then compute the estimated effect associated with each placebo study. This procedure allows us to compare the estimated effect of the 2004 EU enlargement on the EU-8 to the placebo effects obtained for other countries. We interpret the effect of the EU enlargement on EU-8 significant if the estimated effect for the EU-8 is considerably large relative to the placebo effects.
To study the effects of “in-space placebo”, we use the RMSPE given in Equation (4). Figure 4 reports the ratios between the post-2004 RMSPE and the pre-2004 RMSPE for EU-8 and for all the countries in the donor pool. RMSPE measures the magnitude of the gap in the GDP per capita between each country and its synthetic counterpart. A large post-intervention RMSPE is not indicative of a large effect of the intervention if the pre-intervention RMSPE is also large. Therefore, for each country, we divide the post-intervention RMSPE by its pre-intervention RMSPE. In Figure 4, the highest RMSPE ratio is obtained by EU-8. For EU-8, the post-EU accession gap is about 257 times larger than the pre-EU accession gap. This ratio is approximately 5 times larger than the second and third highest RMSPE ratios obtained by Ukraine and Kazakhstan.

6.2. Sensitivity Analysis

In the baseline analysis, we end our sample in 2012 since two countries in our donor pool, Croatia and Ukraine, became subject to intervention or idiosyncratic shocks in 2013 and 2014. Croatia became an EU member in 2013. Hence, it cannot be treated as a control country anymore since it was affected by the intervention. Ukraine received huge negative idiosyncratic shocks in 2014 due to the 2014 revolution, civil unrest, and the Russian intervention. This means that Ukraine is not an appropriate control country for the analysis starting in 2014, since it was exposed to large idiosyncratic shocks in GDP per capita, our outcome of interest.
We conduct sensitivity analysis by dropping Croatia and Ukraine from the donor pool and extend the sample until 2019. This means we are left with 6 countries in our donor pool: Armenia, Israel, Kazakhstan, Republic of Moldova, Russian Federation, and Serbia. We also tried an alternative sensitivity analysis using 12 countries in the donor pool by excluding Croatia and Ukraine after dropping total factor productivity variable from the set of predictors. We obtained very similar results which are available upon request. This sensitivity check by using data until 2019 would help us to obtain 15 years of post-intervention data and to observe whether GDP differences between actual and synthetic control are long-lasting or not. Table 3 shows the weights of the each of the country in the synthetic control after Croatia and Ukraine are dropped from the donor pool. We see that, relative to baseline weights from Table 1, now Kazakhstan and Serbia have obtained positive weights.
Figure 5 displays the GDP per capita path of EU-8 and its synthetic counterpart for the 1994–2019 period using the weights given in Table 3. We observe that the difference in GDP per capita between actual and synthetic EU-8 continues until 2019. In fact, the difference gradually increases after the EU membership. This suggest that positive growth effects of the EU accession are long-lasting and beneficial to the new members in the long-run. However, the results from Figure 5 should be treated with caution because the fit of GDP per capita between actual and synthetic EU-8 during the pre-EU accession period is slightly poor. As Abadie et al. (2015) indicate, synthetic control loses credibility when it does not track the treated unit’s pre-intervention outcomes. As we already saw in Figure 1, our baseline synthetic control provides good fit that supports our choice of ending the sample period in 2012.

7. Conclusions

In this paper we studied the growth effects of 2004 enlargement of the European Union to the East using the synthetic control method. We estimated that EU enlargement had an immediate but modest positive impact on the economic growth of the EU-8 countries in the first few years following their EU accession. The positive impact of the EU enlargement becomes even more apparent starting with 2007 when the new EU member states were admitted into the Schengen zone. As a result, the GDP per capita difference between the actual and synthetic EU-8 continues to grow towards the end of the sample period. Thus, our results suggest a pronounced positive effect of the EU enlargement on the economic growth of the EU-8 countries. We find that over the entire 2004–2012 period, GDP per capita of the EU-8 was increased by about 2313 USD per year on average relative to the synthetic EU-8. The growth rate of GDP per capita in the actual EU-8 for the same period was 2.7% higher than the synthetic EU-8. In 2012, per capita GDP in the actual EU-8 is estimated to be about 19% higher than in the synthetic EU-8.
We applied the synthetic control method in our analysis since it is a powerful tool in assessing the impact of treatment or intervention because it allows the researcher to construct counterfactual analysis, an essential element in comparative case studies. However, there are some potential threats to our methodology. The one of the assumptions of the synthetic control that we maintained in our study is that the countries in our donor pool should not be affected by the 2004 EU enlargement. Since most of the control countries have some degree of trade or financial links with the CEE countries, these links can create spillover effects. This can cause bias in our estimates; however, it is difficult to assess the direction of this bias since spillover effects can be positive for some of the control countries, while negative for others. Assuming positive spillover effects outweighs the negative ones, our estimates can be seen as a lower bound for the growth effects of 2004 EU enlargement on the CEE countries. Another potential threat is the complexity of the membership process which cannot be captured by a single date. For example, even though the CEE countries joined the EU in 2004, they were admitted to the Schengen Area only in 2007. Therefore, our estimates may not only reflect the impact of economic integration but also geographic integration on growth. As a result, our estimates would be smaller without geographic integration. We actually acquired some evidence in this direction, since the effect of EU accession becomes more visible starting with 2007.
Related to the last point, extending our analysis to account for the multiple treatment effects, e.g., accession to the EU and accession to the Schengen Area, can be an interesting avenue for future research. Such a study would be helpful to isolate the impact of economic integration and geographic integration. Another extension for future research would be to identify the growth mechanisms and channels of EU membership. In this study, we only provide a positive effect of EU membership on economic growth. However, documenting the growth channels which may include but are not limited to trade openness, financial integration, or institutional quality can be useful in policy planning. Finally, studying the effects of other waves of Eastern enlargement of the European Union would help to assess whether every member benefits from EU integration and that positive growth effects of EU membership are not limited only to a certain group of countries.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, A.C. and M.B.T.; methodology, A.C. and M.B.T.; software, M.B.T.; validation, and M.B.T.; formal analysis, A.C. and M.B.T.; investigation, A.C. and M.B.T.; resources, A.C. and M.B.T.; data curation, M.B.T.; writing—original draft preparation, A.C. and M.B.T.; writing—review and editing, A.C.; visualization, M.B.T.; supervision, A.C.; project administration, A.C. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

PWT 10.0|Penn World Table|Groningen Growth and Development Centre|University of Groningen (rug.nl).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Data Definitions and Sources

  • Real GDP per Capita: Expenditure-side real GDP at chained PPPs (in mil. 2017US$). Source: Penn World Table, version 10.0.
  • Human Capital Index: Human capital index, based on years of schooling and returns to education. Source: Penn World Table, version 10.0.
  • Total Factor Productivity: TFP level at current PPPs (USA = 1). Source: Penn World Table, version 10.0.
  • Investment rate: Share of gross capital formation (private plus public) in GDP at current PPPs. Source: Penn World Table, version 10.0.
  • Government consumption rate: Share of government consumption in GDP at current PPPs. Source: Penn World Table, version 10.0.
  • Trade Openness: Share of merchandise exports plus share of merchandise imports consumption in GDP at current PPPs. Source: Penn World Table, version 10.0.
  • Price Level: Price level of output-side GDP. Source: Penn World Table, version 10.0.

References

  1. Abadie, Alberto, and Javier Gardeazabal. 2003. The economic costs of conflict: A case study of the Basque Country. American Economic Review 93: 113–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Abadie, Alberto, Alexis Diamond, and Jens Hainmueller. 2010. Synthetic control methods for comparative case studies: Estimating the effect of California’s tobacco control program. Journal of the American statistical Association 105: 493–505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Abadie, Alberto, Alexis Diamond, and Jens Hainmueller. 2015. Comparative politics and the synthetic control method. American Journal of Political Science 59: 495–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Akhvlediani, Tinatin, and Andrzej Cieślik. 2020. Human capital, technological progress and technology diffusion across Europe: Education matters. Empirica 47: 475–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Allington, Nigel F., and John S. McCombie. 2007. Economic growth and beta-convergence in the East European Transition Economies. In Economic Growth: New Directions in Theory and Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. [Google Scholar]
  6. Badinger, Harald. 2005. Growth effects of economic integration: Evidence from the EU member states. Review of World Economics 141: 50–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Baldwin, Richard E. 1993. On the Measurement of Dynamic Effects of Integration. Empirica 20: 129–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Barro, Robert Joseph, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 2004. Economic Growth, 2nd ed. Cambridge: The MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
  9. Bertrand, Marianne, Esther Duflo, and Sendhil Mullainathan. 2004. How much should we trust differences-in-differences estimates? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 119: 249–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Billmeier, Andreas, and Tommaso Nannicini. 2013. Assessing economic liberalization episodes: A synthetic control approach. Review of Economics and Statistics 95: 983–1001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Borsi, Mihály Tamás, and Norbert Metiu. 2015. The evolution of economic convergence in the European Union. Empirical Economics 48: 657–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Brou, Daniel, and Michele Ruta. 2011. Economic integration, political integration or both? Journal of the European Economic Association 9: 1143–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Campos, Nauro F., Fabrizio Coricelli, and Luigi Moretti. 2019. Institutional integration and economic growth in Europe. Journal of Monetary Economics 103: 88–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Cavenaile, Laurent, and David Dubois. 2011. An empirical analysis of income convergence in the European Union. Applied Economics Letters 18: 1705–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Cieślik, Andrzej, and Dominika Róża Wciślik. 2020. Convergence among the CEE-8 economies and their catch-up towards the EU-15. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 55: 39–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Cuaresma, Jesús Crespo, Miroslava Havettová, and Martin Lábaj. 2013. Income convergence prospects in Europe: Assessing the role of human capital dynamics. Economic Systems 37: 493–507. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Cuaresma, Jesús Crespo, Elke Loichinger, and Gallina A. Vincelette. 2016. Aging and income convergence in Europe: A survey of the literature and insights from a demographic projection exercise. Economic Systems 40: 4–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman. 1990. Comparative Advantage and Long-Run Growth. American Economic Review 80: 796–815. [Google Scholar]
  19. Henrekson, Magnus, Johan Torstensson, and Rasha Torstensson. 1997. Growth effects of European integration. European Economic Review 41: 1537–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Landau, Daniel. 1995. The contribution of the European common market to the growth of its member countries: An empirical test. Review of World Economics 131: 774. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Monfort, Mercedes, Juan Carlos Cuestas, and Javier Ordonez. 2013. Real convergence in Europe: A cluster analysis. Economic Modelling 33: 689–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Peretto, Pietro F. 2003. Endogenous market structure and the growth and welfare effects of economic integration. Journal of International Economics 60: 177–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Phillips, Peter C., and Donggyu Sul. 2007a. Transition modeling and econometric convergence tests. Econometrica 75: 1771–855. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Phillips, Peter C., and Donggyu Sul. 2007b. Some empirics on economic growth under heterogeneous technology. Journal of Macroeconomics 29: 455–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Phillips, Peter C., and Donggyu Sul. 2009. Economic transition and growth. Journal of Applied Econometrics 24: 1153–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Próchniak, Mariusz, and Bartosz Witkowski. 2013. Time stability of the beta convergence among EU countries: Bayesian model averaging perspective. Economic Modelling 30: 322–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Razin, Assaf, and Chi-Wa Yuen. 1996. Labor mobility and fiscal coordination (No. w5433). National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Rivera-Batiz, Luis A., and Paul M. Romer. 1991. Economic integration and endogenous growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 531–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Rivera-Batiz, Luis A., and Danyang Xie. 1993. Integration among unequals. Regional Science and Urban Economics 23: 337–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Romer, Paul M. 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98: S71–S102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Torstensson, Rasha M. 1999. Growth, knowledge transfer and European integration. Applied Economics 31: 97–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Vanhoudt, Patrick. 1999. Did the European unification induce economic growth? In search of scale effects and persistent changes. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 135: 193–220. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Vojinović, Borut, and Žan Jan Oplotnik. 2008. Real convergence in the new EU Member States. Prague Economic Papers 2008: 23–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Vojinović, Borut, Sanjaya Acharya, and Mariusz Próchniak. 2009. Convergence analysis among the ten European transition economies. Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics 50: 123–41. [Google Scholar]
  35. Vojinović, Borut, Žan J. Oplotnik, and Mariusz Próchniak. 2010. EU enlargement and real economic convergence. Post-Communist Economies 22: 303–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Walz, Uwe. 1997a. Innovation, foreign direct investment and growth. Economica 64: 63–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Walz, Uwe. 1997b. Growth and Deeper Regional Integration in a Three-Country Model. Review of International Economics 5: 492–507. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Trends in GDP per capita: EU-8 versus synthetic EU-8.
Figure 1. Trends in GDP per capita: EU-8 versus synthetic EU-8.
Jrfm 14 00128 g001
Figure 2. GDP per capita difference between EU-8 and synthetic EU-8.
Figure 2. GDP per capita difference between EU-8 and synthetic EU-8.
Jrfm 14 00128 g002
Figure 3. In-time placebo: GDP per capita difference between EU-8 and synthetic EU-8.
Figure 3. In-time placebo: GDP per capita difference between EU-8 and synthetic EU-8.
Jrfm 14 00128 g003
Figure 4. Ratio of post-EU accession root mean square prediction error (RMSPE) to pre-EU accession RMSPE: EU-8 and control countries.
Figure 4. Ratio of post-EU accession root mean square prediction error (RMSPE) to pre-EU accession RMSPE: EU-8 and control countries.
Jrfm 14 00128 g004
Figure 5. Sensitivity analysis: EU-8 versus synthetic EU-8.
Figure 5. Sensitivity analysis: EU-8 versus synthetic EU-8.
Jrfm 14 00128 g005
Table 1. Synthetic weights for the European Union (EU)-8.
Table 1. Synthetic weights for the European Union (EU)-8.
CountrySynthetic Control WeightCountrySynthetic Control Weight
Armenia0.1381Moldova0
Croatia0.5070Russia0
Israel0.2362Serbia0
Kazakhstan0Ukraine0.1187
Table 2. Pre-EU accession characteristics.
Table 2. Pre-EU accession characteristics.
EU-8Synthetic EU-8Potential Control
Real GDP per capita15,251.815,248.19356.4
Predictors
Human capital3.063.023.03
Investment rate0.190.200.16
Government consumption rate0.270.270.31
Total factor productivity0.650.570.32
Trade openness−0.05−0.120.05
Price Level0.330.430.25
Notes: The real gross domestic product (GDP) per capita and the GDP predictors for EU-8 and potential control are population-weighted averaged for the period 1994–2003 whereas the same variables for the synthetic EU-8 are constructed using the synthetic control weights.
Table 3. Synthetic weights for the EU-8—sensitivity analysis 1.
Table 3. Synthetic weights for the EU-8—sensitivity analysis 1.
CountrySynthetic Control WeightCountrySynthetic Control Weight
Armenia0.0789Moldova0
Israel0.3301Russia0
Kazakhstan0.1663Serbia0.4248
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Cieślik, A.; Turgut, M.B. Estimating the Growth Effects of 2004 Eastern Enlargement of the European Union. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14, 128. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14030128

AMA Style

Cieślik A, Turgut MB. Estimating the Growth Effects of 2004 Eastern Enlargement of the European Union. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2021; 14(3):128. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14030128

Chicago/Turabian Style

Cieślik, Andrzej, and Mehmet Burak Turgut. 2021. "Estimating the Growth Effects of 2004 Eastern Enlargement of the European Union" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 14, no. 3: 128. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14030128

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop