Next Article in Journal
Definition of Optimal Maize Seeding Rates Based on the Potential Yield of Management Zones
Previous Article in Journal
Introducing Grasslands into Crop Rotations, a Way to Restore Microbiodiversity and Soil Functions
Previous Article in Special Issue
Farmer Decision-Making on the Concept of Coexistence: A Comparative Analysis between Organic and Biotech Farmers in the Philippines
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Impacts of China’s Minimum Grain Procurement Price Program on Agrochemical Use: A Household-Level Analysis

1
China Resources, Environment and Development Academy, Nanjing Agricultural University, Nanjing 210095, China
2
Environmental Policy Group, Wageningen University, 6706 KN Wageningen, The Netherlands
3
Development Economics Group, Wageningen University, 6706 KN Wageningen, The Netherlands
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Agriculture 2021, 11(10), 910; https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture11100910
Submission received: 1 August 2021 / Revised: 6 September 2021 / Accepted: 15 September 2021 / Published: 23 September 2021
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Agricultural Policy and Farmer Behavior)

Abstract

:
China’s minimum grain procurement price program aims to boost grain production and ensure food self-sufficiency. It may also affect the already very high levels of chemical fertilizer and pesticides consumption, but little is known about these potential side-effects. In this paper, we apply panel data regression techniques to a large rural household-level data set for the period 1997–2010 to examine whether and how the minimum grain procurement price program affected households’ agrochemical use. We find that the minimum grain procurement price program negatively affected both chemical fertilizer and pesticides use, with pesticides use being more responsive than the use of fertilizer. The higher wheat and rice prices that resulted from the program stimulated the use of agrochemicals, but they also stimulated area expansion which contributed to lower agrochemical use per unit of land. These counteracting indirect effects were overshadowed by the large negative direct effect of the minimum procurement price of rice on the use of fertilizer and pesticides.

1. Introduction

Minimum support price policy has been widely used in developing countries, such as Bangladesh, Brazil, Chile, Ethiopia, India, Indonesia, Kenya, Malawi, Nigeria, Pakistan, Thailand, Turkey, and Zambia [1,2]. The common goals behind this policy are to increase food production and ensure food security [2]. China implemented a minimum procurement price program for rice in 2005 and for wheat in 2006, aiming to boost grain production and ensure food self-sufficiency [3,4]. As grain production fell to a historical low of 431 million tons in 2003 and the government grain stock decreased to its lowest level in 2004 [4], China replaced its centuries-old policy of taxing agriculture by subsidizing and providing price support to grain producers [4,5,6]. The minimum prices were relatively low in the first few years of implementation, rose rapidly after the world food crisis in 2008, and slightly declined recently [7,8].
Minimum support price may strongly affects the use of agricultural production inputs [9,10,11]. According to standard economic theory, minimum support price is expected to raise the grain price (see e.g., Li et al. [7], Kozicka et al. [9], Qian et al. [12], Kim and Chavas [13], Lyu and Li [14], Qian et al. [15], and Tripathi [16]), and thereby stimulate the use of agrochemicals and other variable inputs [5,17,18,19]. However, only a limited number of studies, such as Li et al. [7], Qian et al. [12], Ali et al. [20], Aditya et al. [21], Krishnaswamy [22], Chintapalli and Tang [23], and Ritu et al. [24], provided empirical evidence of this. Most of these studies focus on minimum support price influencing land area in India. They do not consider the influence on other inputs, particularly agrochemical use, which may pollute the environment [25,26]. Using a village computable general equilibrium model in which land is a non-tradable, Heerink et al. [5] estimated that the 36.6% increase in the rice price in China during the period 2000–2004 caused 34% and 90% increases in fertilizer use in the two examined villages, respectively; estimated increases in pesticides use amounted to 28% and 80%. The estimated increases were partly caused by a shift in production from other crops towards rice, for given land-holding sizes.
The minimum grain procurement price may also affects agrochemical use in an indirect way. Higher procurement price may stimulates the expansion of land sown with grain, particularly when land is tradable as is the case in China in recent years with the rapid development of the rural land rental market. Given that farm size or sown area is generally found to have a negative effect on agrochemical use per unit of land (e.g., [25,27,28]), this implies that a negative indirect relationship may exist between higher grain (procurement) price and agrochemical use with land area sown with grain being the intermediate variable. The net effect on agrochemical use of these two counteracting mechanisms is unclear a priori.
Whether and how the minimum grain procurement price affects Chinese households’ agrochemical use is an issue of great importance since China is the largest chemical fertilizer and pesticides consumer in the world [25]. After introducing the minimum grain procurement price program, China’s grain output achieved a growth rate of 54% from 2003 to 2019. However, chemical fertilizer and pesticides consumption also rose by 22.5% and 4.5%, respectively, during the same period [29]. Since 2007, the amounts of chemical fertilizer and pesticides used in China are both higher than the amounts used by major crop exporters such as the USA, France, and Japan [25]. To reduce the use of chemical fertilizer and pesticides, China’s Ministry of Agriculture has launched programs in recent years aimed at reducing the growth rate of agrochemical use [30], regulating high-toxic pesticides and stimulating low-toxic biological pesticides use and encouraging the use of organic fertilizer in fruit, vegetable, and tea production [31,32].
Despite its relevance for policy making, little is known about the impact of China’s minimum grain procurement price program on the use of agrochemicals [4,6]. To address this knowledge gap, we use a large-scale household-level panel data set to examine whether and how the minimum grain procurement price program affected households’ agrochemical use. The data set that we use for this purpose comprises Rural Fixed Observation Points survey data, a large-scale household-level panel data set collected since 1986 by the Research Center for Rural Economy (RCRE) of the Ministry of Agriculture. We have access to the survey data that were collected until the year 2010. Although we do not have access to more recent data, important insights about the impact of the minimum grain procurement price program on the use of fertilizer and pesticides can be obtained from such an analysis.
This study makes two contributions to the available literature. First, it expands the literature on the effects of minimum procurement price by focusing on agrochemical use at the rural household level. It thereby provides insights into potentially important environmental effects in China and other developing countries applying minimum support price, that may either conflict with or reinforce ongoing policies aimed at reducing agrochemical use. Second, our study takes into account the potential indirect effect of grain price on agrochemical use through changes in land areas sown with grain, which is not examined in the available literature on grain price and agrochemical use [5,19].
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly introduces the minimum grain procurement price policy in China. Section 3 describes the methodology and data set. Section 4 presents and discusses the estimation results. Section 5 provides conclusions and discusses potential policy implications.

2. China’s Minimum Grain Procurement Price Policy

The minimum procurement price program for rice (PMR) and wheat (PMW) aims to ensure that grain prices are high enough to cover production costs and to help rural households earn a profit from growing grain crops. They are regarded as measures that stimulate grain production and protect farmers’ interest [3,6]. The core of the minimum grain procurement price program is an assurance to farmers that authorities will not allow prices to fall, which sent a “strong signal” to help the rural households build expectations on ever-rising prices [6].
Following the PMR and PMW that started in 2005 and 2006, respectively, a temporary storage program was implemented for maize, soybean, and rapeseeds in 2008 with the aim to stimulate production of a wider range of major crops [4]. Given that the focus of our study is the minimum grain procurement price program, we confine the analysis to rice and wheat.
The minimum grain procurement price is set by China’s National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC), Ministry of Agriculture (MOA, called Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Affairs since 2018) and other governmental institutions based on production costs and market conditions. It is announced before the crops are sown (September for wheat, January for rice) each year [6,33]. If the prevailing domestic market price falls below the minimum price, the state-owned China Grain Reserve Corporation (Sinograin) and its branches as well as qualified enterprises entrusted by Sinograin are authorized to directly purchase qualified grain from farmers at the applied minimum grain prices in designated major grain production areas [3,33].
Table 1 provides an overview of the officially applied minimum prices for wheat and rice in the designated major grain production areas. Some provinces joined the PMR in 2008 only. As can be seen from the table, the minimum grain procurement prices were raised considerably during the years 2008/2009–2014. In recent years, they remained constant and were even lowered in some years.

3. Methods and Materials

To examine whether and how China’s minimum grain procurement price affects households’ agrochemical use, we carried out an empirical study taking the following steps. First, a theoretical framework was developed and used to derive testable hypotheses are given. Second, an empirical model that can be used for testing these hypotheses was developed based on available (agricultural) economic theory and taking into account the available information in the panel data set that we used for this study. Below we explain these two steps, followed by an introduction into the data set that was used and a discussion of the method used for estimating the empirical model.

3.1. Theoretical Framework

Using the standard approach in agricultural economics, e.g., Sadoulet and De Janvry [17], we consider a risk-neutral rural household using chemical fertilizer X 1 , chemical pesticides X 2 , land area A , and other regular productive inputs X z to produce output Y that aims to maximize profit π , and with P ,   p 1 , p 2 , p A , and p z defined as the prices of Y ,   X 1 , X 2 , A , and X z , respectively. Following Lichtenberg and Zilberman [35], we specify chemical pesticides use as a damage control agent G ( · ) that represents the effectiveness of pesticides in limiting yield losses, with G ( · ) [ 0 ,   1 ] . The output generated by other inputs is assumed to satisfy a Cobb–Douglas production function F ( · ) . This gives the damage-abatement production function Y ( · ) , in which θ represents the probability of occurrence of pests, weeds, and diseases in crops, with θ [ 0 ,   1 ] . Following Schreinemachers et al. [36], we use the exponential specification for the damage control agent G ( · ) in this study. Referring to Li et al. [7], Li and Chavas [8], and Qian et al. [12], the grain price P depends on the world market grain price W P and on domestic factors, i.e., the minimum grain procurement price P M and other factors Z affecting the supply of grain. This gives:
Max   π = P Y p 1 X 1 p 2 X 2 p A A p z X z
subject to:
P = P ( P M , W P , Z )
Y = ( 1 θ ) F ( X 1 , A , X z ) + θ F ( X 1 , A , X z ) G ( X 2 )
F ( X 1 , A , X z ) = α X 1 φ 1 A φ 2 X z φ 3
G ( X 2 ) = 1 e λ X 2
Given that the minimum grain procurement price intends to raise the prices that farmers receive for the rice and wheat they produce, we assume that P P M > 0 . This gives the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1.
The minimum grain procurement price positively affects the grain price that rural households receive.
Let X 1 * A = X 1 * / A and X 2 * A = X 2 * / A be the optimum quantities per unit land of fertilizer and pesticides, respectively. Applying first-order conditions gives:
A * = P ( 1 φ 2 ) 1 [ p A 1 φ 2 α X 1 φ 1 X z φ 3 ( 1 θ e λ X 2 ) ] ( 1 φ 2 ) 1
X 1 * A = P ( 1 φ 1 ) 1 [ A ( φ 1 + φ 2 1 ) p 1 1 φ 1 α X z φ 3 ( 1 θ e λ X 2 ) ] ( 1 φ 1 ) 1
X 2 * A = ( λ A ) 1 ( l n P + l n λ + l n θ + l n α + φ 1 l n X 1 + φ 2 l n A + φ 3 l n X Z l n p 2 )
Given that G ( · ) = 1 e λ X 2 [ 0 , 1 ] and θ [ 0 , 1 ] , we obtain ( 1 θ e λ X 2 ) [ 0 , 1 ] . Assuming positive values for the variables P , p A , X 1 , X z , A , p 1 , and for the parameters ( 1 φ 1 ) , φ 1 , ( 1 φ 2 ) , φ 2 , α , and λ , the relationship between domestic grain price and the optimum land area and agrochemical use per unit of land can be derived: A * P > 0 , X 1 * A P > 0 , and X 2 * A P > 0 . This gives the following two hypotheses:
Hypothesis 2.
The grain price received by a household positively affects the area sown with grain by that household.
Hypothesis 3.
The grain price received by a household positively affects the use of agrochemicals per unit of land by that household.
Following Benjamin [37], by assuming a Cobb–Douglas production function with constant returns to scale and assuming a relationship between farm size and the (shadow) price of agrochemicals in imperfect markets,
p 1 = d 1 A ρ 1
p 2 = d 2 A ρ 2
The relationship between agrochemical use per unit of land and land area can be derived, after substituting Equation (9) into Equation (7) and Equation (10) into Equation (8):
X 1 * A A = ( φ 1 + φ 2 1 ρ 1 ) ( 1 φ 1 ) 1 A ( 2 φ 1 + φ 2 2 ρ 1 1 φ 1 ) [ d 1 1 φ 1 α X z φ 3 ( 1 θ e λ X 2 ) P ] ( 1 φ 1 ) 1
X 2 * A A = ( λ 1 A 2 ) ( l n P λ θ α d 2 1 X 1 φ 1 A φ 2 ρ 2 X z φ 3 φ 2 + ρ 2 )
Assuming positive values for the variables A , X z , P and for the parameters ( 1 φ 1 ) , d 1 , φ 1 , α , and ( 1 θ e λ X 2 ) in Equation (11), the sign of X 1 * A A depends on ( φ 1 + φ 2 1 ρ 1 ) and can in theory be either positive or negative. Empirical evidence indicates that generally it is negative (see e.g., [25,27,28,38]). Likewise, assuming that parameter λ and variable A are positive in Equation (12), the sign of X 2 * A A depends on ( l n P λ θ α d 2 1 X 1 φ 1 A φ 2 ρ 2 X z φ 3 φ 2 + ρ 2 ) and can in theory be either positive or negative. Empirical studies such as Nie et al. [25], Wu et al. [27], and Ren et al. [28], suggest that it is generally negative.
Note that if lower amounts of agrochemicals were used for non-grain crops planted before wheat or rice was grown on it, a switch towards planting grain crops will imply higher agrochemical use. This ‘crop switching effect’ is not considered in our mathematical model. Hence, taken together, the impact of land area sown with grain can in theory either be positive or negative. This gives the following hypotheses:
Hypothesis 4a.
The area sown with grain positively affects agrochemical use per unit of land.
Hypothesis 4b.
The area sown with grain negatively affects agrochemical use per unit of land.
The theoretical model analyzed above is presented schematically in Figure 1. The higher grain price that results from the minimum grain procurement price policy increases the profitability of grain and is thereby expected to increase the use of agrochemicals per unit of land. However, the price increase will also induce farmers to use more land for growing grain, which may either increase or reduce the use of agrochemicals per unit of land. Empirical research is needed to provide quantitative estimates of the sign (positive or negative) and magnitude of the net effect of these two counteracting forces.

3.2. Estimation Model Specification

In order to test the hypotheses developed in Section 3.1, we build a model consisting of three equations that can be used to estimate step by step the relationships shown in Figure 1. First, the price model in Equation (13) aims to examine the impact of the minimum grain procurement price on the grain price that rural households received. Second, the area model specified in Equation (14) intends to examine the impact of the grain (procurement) price on the area sown with grain. Following Nerlove [39,40] and Nerlove and Bessler [41], we account for possible time lags in area responses to price changes by including the one-period lagged land area. Third, the agrochemicals model in Equation (15) aims to estimate the impacts of the grain (procurement) price and the land area sown with grain on agrochemical use.
P G , i t = α G 1 P M G , i t + α G 2 D G , i t * P M G , i t + α G 3 W P G , t + α G 4 s u n t + α G 5 p r e t + α G 6 t e m t + μ i + ε G , i t
A G , i t = β G 1 P G , i t 1 + β G 2 Δ P M G , i t + β G 3 D G , i t * Δ P M G , i t + β G 4 A G , i t 1 + β G 5 c o n i t + μ i + λ t + ε G , i t
X C , i t A = G = W , R ( γ G C 1 P G , i t 1 + γ G C 2 Δ P M G , i t + γ G C 3 D G , i t * Δ P M G , i t + γ G C 4 A G , i t ) + C = 1 , 2 γ C 5 p C , i t + γ C 6 c o n i t + μ i + λ t + ε C , i t
The index G represents the type of grain (either W = wheat, or R = rice), while the index C represents the type of agrochemical (either 1 = chemical fertilizer, or 2 = chemical pesticides); i and t indicate household and year, respectively, μ i - μ i are the household fixed effects, λ t - λ t are the year fixed effects, α, β, and γ are sets of unknown coefficients, and ε G , i t - ε C , i t are error terms with standard properties.
The variable P represents the grain price that a household received, while P M indicates the minimum procurement price. The dummy variable D takes a value 1 if the household lives in a province that applied the minimum procurement price policy and 0 otherwise. Hence, the coefficient α G 1 reflects the impact of P M on the grain price received by households in those provinces that did not implement the policy, while α G 2 represents the extent to which the impact differs between provinces that implemented the policy and those that did not. The coefficient α G 3 reflects the impact of world market price W P on the grain price. Year effects are not included due to their perfect correlation with W P and P M . Instead, sunshine ( s u n ), precipitation ( p r e ), temperature ( t e m ) are included to reflect the impact of domestic supply factors on grain price. Hypothesis 1 is supported when α G 1 is significantly positive or, in case α G 1 does not differ significantly from zero, α G 2 is significantly positive.
The variable A denotes the land areas sown with grain, i.e., wheat and rice respectively. We use two alternative measures for this variable, the sown area (in hectares) and the share of the grain in total sown area. Following a commonly used Nerlovian approach [17], the areas sown with wheat and rice are assumed to depend on the area sown with the same crop in the previous year and the expected price for the crop. Besides the price received in the previous season, it may be assumed that the change in the minimum grain procurement price between the previous year and the current year, Δ P M , will also influence the price that farmers expect to receive. Minimum procurement prices are announced before the start of the season, and hence Δ P M and D * Δ P M are likely to be taken into account by farmers in their decision making. Finally, c o n is a control variable, i.e., the price of maize—the third major grain crop in China—in the previous year. Hypothesis 2 is supported when the coefficient β G 1 is positive and significantly different from zero.
The variable X A represents the use of agrochemicals, i.e., fertilizer and pesticides respectively, per hectare of cultivated land. It is assumed to depend on the expected grain price, proxied by the grain price in the previous year P , Δ P M and D * Δ P M , on the price of the agrochemicals p in year t, and on the land areas sown with the two grains A in the current year. The control variable c o n is the same as in Equation (14). Hypothesis 3 is supported when the estimated coefficient γ G C 1 is significantly positive, while Hypothesis 4a and Hypothesis 4b are supported when γ G C 4 is significantly positive or negative, respectively.

3.3. Data

We use a large-scale household-level panel data set, the Rural Fixed Observation Points (RFOP) survey data set, covering the period 1997–2010, to estimate the model presented in Equations (13)–(15). The RFOP is a nationwide longitudinal data set collected by the Research Center for Rural Economy (RCRE) of the Ministry of Agriculture [25,42,43]. It annually covers more than 20,000 rural households living in more than 300 villages in 31 provincial-level administrative units [43]. The sampling method of the RFOP is as follows: to represent national rural development, different weights were allocated at the province-level according to the number of villages and their topographic and economic characteristics; then 3 to 25 villages were selected in each province-level unit, and households were randomly selected in each village [42]. The surveyed households are revisited annually, and information on household characteristics, land use, fixed assets, agricultural production, income, expenditure, etc. is recorded with the help of survey assistants [25,42]. The first survey was held in 1986, and it has been conducted each year since then except for 1992 and 1994 [25]. If a household left the village due to migration, a similar household was chosen to stabilize the sample size [42]. RFOP’s panel nature allows us to track the changes in grain price, land areas sown with grain, and agrochemical use of households over time. We had access to the RFOP data for all years until 2010, so our analysis covers the eight/nine years before the introduction of the minimum procurement price program and the first five/six years after its introduction. We do not include the year before 1997, because Chongqing was still part of Sichuan at that time.
Information on minimum grain prices, weather conditions and world grain price indices was obtained from official statistics. Using the information provided in Table 1, the indicator of the minimum wheat procurement price (PMW) used in the empirical analysis was simply calculated as the mean value of the officially applied minimum prices of the three subspecies of wheat. The indicator of the minimum rice procurement price (PMR) was calculated in a similar manner, i.e., as the mean value of the officially applied minimum prices of mid/late Indica rice and Japonica rice; the price for early Indica rice was not included, because its minimum price was applied in a few provinces only (see Table 1). Data on weather conditions are only available for the capital city of each province. We assume that these city-level data are representative for the entire province.
Table 2 provides an overview of the mean values in each year of all variables used in the empirical analysis. Average chemical fertilizer use per hectare shows a fluctuating but increasing trend over time, with a total increase of 21% over the entire period. Pesticides use per hectare increased more rapidly, with the average value in 2010 equal to more than twice the value in 1997. Interestingly, the wheat and rice sown areas show a decreasing trend before 2004/2005, then they slightly increased for wheat and first increased but then declined again for rice. The average grain prices that households received decreased before 2003 but steadily increased after 2004 and coincided with the fluctuating but increasing average applied minimum grain prices. In the Appendix A, we provide a chart showing the time trends in the average wheat and rice prices (Figure A1)

3.4. Estimation Method

Difference-in-differences (DID) is the most frequently used impact evaluation method in non-experimental settings when before-after and treatment-control group data are available. Applying DID hinges upon several assumptions, with the “parallel trends” assumption being the most important one [46]. The data set that we used for this study is suitable for applying DID, given that we have rural households before and after the minimum grain procurement price program was implemented and households in a treatment group (designated provinces) and in a control group (other provinces). But unfortunately, the two main outcome variables (i.e., chemical fertilizer and pesticides use per hectare of land) do not satisfy the “parallel trends” assumption (see Figure A2 and Figure A3 in Appendix A). Instead, we follow other studies examining the effect of the major subsidy programs on rural household production decisions in applying multiple regression panel data analysis [42,47].
Previous studies using the panel data sets to examine the driving forces of sown areas and agrochemical use, Nie et al. [25], Wu et al. [27], Yi et al. [42], and Gao et al. [43], applied fixed effect regressions to control for potential endogeneity problems caused by unobserved time-invariant household-specific variables. Likewise, we apply fixed effect regression in this study to estimate Equations (13) and (15). The dynamic nature of Equation (14), caused by the lagged A variable leads to biased and inconsistent OLS estimators [48]. To solve this problem, we follow Yu and You [49] and apply the difference generalized methods of moments (GMM) regression to estimate Equation (14).

4. Results and Discussion

In this section, we first present and discuss the regression results for each of the three equations specified in Section 3.2. Based on these estimates, we present an integrated assessment of the effects of the observed changes in minimum grain procurement prices during the period 2005/2006–2010 at the end of the section.

4.1. Grain Price

The fixed effects regression results obtained for wheat and rice prices, based on Equation (13), are summarized in Table 3. Columns (1) and (2) in Table 3 present the results for the wheat price, and columns (3) and (4) for the rice price.
As expected, the minimum procurement prices positively affect the wheat and rice prices that households received. This finding provides support for Hypothesis 1 postulated in Section 3.1, and is consistent with the results obtained in Qian et al. [12]. We further find that the positive effect of the minimum procurement price for wheat does not differ significantly between provinces that implemented the policy and provinces that did not implement it, suggesting that wheat markets in the country are highly integrated. Keeping other factors constant, an increase in the minimum price for wheat of 0.10 yuan/kg is found to increase the wheat price that farmers receive by 0.015 yuan/kg. For rice, we find that the impact of the minimum procurement price is slightly higher in provinces that did not implement the program. Keeping other factors fixed, these estimates indicate that an increase in the minimum price for rice of 0.10 yuan/kg increases the rice price by 0.018 yuan/kg in provinces that implemented the program and by 0.022 yuan/kg in provinces that did not implement it. The reason for this difference remains unclear and needs further research. As expected, the world market prices of wheat and rice significantly affect the domestic prices of these crops, which is consistent with the findings in Li et al. [7] for China’s wheat market. We further find that the estimated effect of the world market price is considerably larger for rice than for wheat.

4.2. Land Areas Sown with Grain

The difference GMM estimation results for land areas sown with grain, based on Equation (14), are summarized in Table 4. Column (1) presents the results for wheat area and column (2) for rice area; results for the shares of land sown with wheat and rice are shown in columns (3) and (4).
As expected, the wheat and rice prices positively affect the land areas sown with wheat and rice, respectively. This finding provides support for Hypothesis 2 (see Section 3.1). Similar results were found by Mushtaqa and Dawson [11] for cotton, sugarcane and high yielding variety rice in Pakistan, by Bayramoglu and Chakir [19] for rapeseed in France, by Siad et al. [50] for durum wheat in Italy, and by Wang et al. [51] and Lu [52] for wheat, maize, and rice in three Chinese provinces, i.e., Zhejiang, Shandong, and Henan. The price elasticity of the wheat sown area equals 0.560, while the price elasticity for rice sown area equals 0.943 (see Table A1 in Appendix A). The impact of the wheat area in the previous year does not differ significantly from zero, which indicates that wheat farmers respond instantaneously to price changes. Responses of rice farmers are less prompt, given the significant coefficient estimate for the lagged rice area. The estimated long-term price elasticity of rice sown area equals 1.274 (see Table A1).
As argued in Section 3.2, we assume that expected prices depend at least partly on the minimum procurement prices which are announced before the start of the growing season. The estimation results in Table 4 confirm that these procurement prices positively affect the land areas sown with wheat and rice. This is consistent with the findings in Ali et al. [20], Krishnaswamy [22], and Ritu et al. [24] for India, and Li et al. [7] and Qian et al. [12] for China. Estimated elasticities equal 0.009 for wheat and 0.049 for rice (see Table A1). The impact of the minimum procurement prices does not differ significantly between provinces that implemented the policies and those that did not, except for the share of land sown with rice. This finding seems to indicate that price expectations do not differ much between the two groups of provinces due to the high degree of integration in wheat and rice markets in China.

4.3. Agrochemical Use

Fixed effects regression results for agrochemical use, based on Equation (15), are summarized in Table 5. Column (1) presents the results for fertilizer and column (2) for pesticides; columns (3) and (4) present the results when the sown land areas are replaced by the shares of land sown with wheat and rice.
The main finding is that the prices of wheat and rice positively affect both chemical fertilizer use and pesticides use. Hence, we find empirical support for Hypothesis 3 in the case of fertilizer as well as pesticides. It is consistent with results obtained by Heerink et al. [5] for Jiangxi province in China and Bayramoglu and Chakir [19] for France. The elasticities that correspond to the estimated coefficients are presented in Table A2 in Appendix A. They indicate that fertilizer use is slightly more responsive to wheat and rice prices than pesticides use.
As expected, the change in the minimum procurement price of wheat between the current year and the previous year has a significant positive impact on the use of both types of agrochemical. For pesticides use, the impact is somewhat larger in provinces where the program was implemented, whereas the impact is not significantly different between the two groups of provinces for fertilizer use. For the minimum rice procurement price, however, we find negative instead of positive effects. This finding conflicts with a priori expectations derived from theory. A possible explanation is that rice farmers are willing to take more risk when the minimum rice procurement price increases, and rely more on organic fertilizer and biological pest control methods for increasing yields. More research is needed to examine this conjecture.
With regard to the sown areas, we find significant negative effects of both the wheat sown area and the rice sown area on chemical fertilizer and pesticides use. These findings indicate that Hypothesis 4a should be rejected and provides support for Hypothesis 4b postulated in Section 3.1. They suggest that the negative relationship between land area and agrochemical use per unit of land found for China by Nie et al. [25], Wu et al. [27], Ren et al. [28], and for Nigeria by Rahman and Chima [53] also exists for individual grain crops. Interestingly, the estimated effect is stronger for the area sown with wheat as compared to the rice sown area, as can be seen from the elasticities presented in Table A2.

4.4. Integrated Assessment

As analyzed in Section 3.1, the minimum support price affects the grain price that households received and thereby affects the use of agrochemicals per hectare of land. The minimum grain procurement price also affects land for growing grain through expected grain crop price and then affects agrochemical use per unit of land. By respectively multiplying all the mediators’ estimated coefficients in the two channels referred above and adding them, the total effects of the minimum grain procurement price program on the use of agrochemicals hence could be derived [54]. To this end, we use the changes in the (deflated) official minimum wheat and rice procurement prices from 2005/2006–2010 presented in Table 2, and combine them with the estimated coefficients presented in Table 3 and Table 4 to derive the effects of these changes on the prices and sown areas of wheat and rice. The resulting effects are combined with the estimated coefficients presented in Table 5 and the mean annual changes in the minimum procurement prices to derive the effects presented in Table 6.
The main conclusion is that, assuming other factors remained constant, the minimum procurement prices had negative effects on the use of chemical fertilizer and on the use of pesticides during the period 2005/2006–2010. For the provinces that implemented the policy, our calculations suggest that without the minimum grain procurement price program the use of fertilizer would have been 8.7% (=100 × 94.35/1094.22) higher in 2010, and the use of pesticides would have been 12.2% (=100 × 2.23/18.28) higher. Similarly, for the provinces that did not implement the policy, the use of fertilizer would have been 6.8% higher in 2010, and the use of pesticides would have been 11.77% higher, without the minimum grain procurement price program.
A closer look at the different effects presented in the table gives insight into their relative strengths. The positive effects of the minimum procurement prices on the prices of wheat and rice indeed stimulated larger use of the two agrochemicals, while the increases in the areas sown with wheat and rice that resulted from the procurement price program induced a lower use of agrochemicals per unit land. However, these two counteracting effects were overshadowed by the direct effects of the minimum procurement prices on the use of chemical fertilizer and pesticides. Higher minimum procurement prices lead to both higher expected output prices and to lower output price risk. We find that these direct effects stimulated the use of agrochemicals in the case of wheat procurement prices, but reduced the use of agrochemicals in the case of rice procurement prices, with the latter effect considerably outweighing the former. The net result of these different counteracting forces of higher minimum procurement prices were lower levels of chemical fertilizer and pesticides use (assuming other forces remained constant) than would have been the case without the program.

5. Conclusions

The aim of this study was to investigate whether and how China’s minimum grain procurement price program affected rural households’ agrochemical use. Using a large household-level data set that covers the years 1997–2010, we find that the program negatively affected both chemical fertilizer and pesticides use, with pesticides use being more responsive than the use of fertilizer. The dominating force that caused these negative effects is the direct impact of the minimum procurement price for rice on the use of chemical fertilizer and pesticides. The minimum procurement price for wheat, on the other hand, is found to stimulate the use of agrochemicals. But its effect was smaller than the effect of the minimum rice procurement price. The indirect effects through changes in market prices and changes in areas sown with the two crops are found to be relatively small.
In the empirical analysis, we made a distinction between provinces that were designated to implement the program and other provinces, but we found only very small or insignificant differences between the two groups. This finding confirms outcomes of earlier research showing that agricultural output markets in China are highly integrated [55,56].
Some important implications for policy-making can be drawn from these findings. First, it is essential to realize that the minimum grain procurement price policy has positive environmental effects by encouraging lower levels of chemical fertilizer and pesticides use in the case of rice, but negative environmental effects in the case of wheat. To some extent, the minimum price policy for wheat conflicts with recently introduced policies aimed at reducing agrochemical use in China. This points to the need for carefully designing and applying price intervention policies. Second, the mediating roles that the land areas sown with grain played in affecting agrochemical use per unit of land shows that farm size has a substantial influence on agricultural sustainability from the aspect of the environment. Addressing farm size and expanding large-scale operations can be an important way to promote sustainable agriculture, given the small farm sizes that are still dominant in Chinese agriculture. Considering that large-scale farming may increase the likelihood that pests and diseases occur, promoting large-scale operation should preferably be integrated with technological innovation and providing better information on pest control and prevention, including the use of biopesticides and options for integrated pest management.
Our study points to the need for further research in several ways. First, more research is needed to check the robustness of our finding that the minimum procurement price of rice negatively affects the use of chemical fertilizer and pesticides. In particular, researchers with access to the RFOP data from 2011 onwards should examine whether this crucial finding also holds for the later period in which the policy was implemented. Second, more insight is needed into the reasons why rice farmers use lower levels of agrochemicals when the minimum rice price announced at the start of the season is raised. Is it because farmers are willing to use more risky organic and biological inputs, or are there other reasons? Examining farmers’ risk preferences when assessing the impacts of the minimum procurement price on agrochemical use may be a fruitful future research direction. Third, our measurements of fertilizer and pesticides use are not perfect, because detailed information on the use of agrochemicals in rice cultivation and in wheat cultivation is not available in the RFOP survey data set. Research based on more detailed data sets, e.g., including the use of organic fertilizer and biopesticides, is needed to obtain deeper insights into the impact of China’s minimum grain procurement price program on rural households’ agrochemical use.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.S., N.H. and P.O.; methodology, M.S., N.H. and S.F.; software, M.S.; validation, M.S., N.H. and S.F.; formal analysis, M.S., S.F. and T.T.; investigation, M.S., S.F. and T.T.; resources, T.T.; data curation, M.S. and T.T.; writing—original draft preparation, M.S.; writing—review and editing, M.S., N.H., P.O. and S.F.; visualization, M.S. and N.H.; supervision, N.H., P.O. and S.F.; project administration, N.H., P.O. and S.F.; funding acquisition, S.F. and N.H. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the China Scholarship Council (CSC) [grant number 201906850076], National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC) [grant numbers 71673144 and 71773046], the 111 Project (B17024) and by the Program for Strategic Scientific Alliances (PSA) of the Royal Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences (KNAW) [project number PSA-SA-E-01] and the National Key R&D Program of China of the Ministry of Science and Technology (MOST) [grant number 2016YFE0103100].

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Informed consent was obtained from all subjects involved in the study.

Data Availability Statement

Restrictions apply to the availability of the RFOP data. Data was obtained from the Research Center for Rural Economy (RCRE) of the Ministry of Agriculture and are available at RCRE with the permission of RCRE.

Acknowledgments

We gratefully acknowledge the support from the CSC, the NSFC, the KNAW and the MOST.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Estimated elasticities for sown land areas.
Table A1. Estimated elasticities for sown land areas.
Outcome VariablesSown Area (ha)Share of Land (%)
WheatRiceWheatRice
(1)(2)(3)(4)
One-period lagged wheat-sown area0.131 **---
(0.065)---
One-period lagged rice-sown area-0.260 **--
-(0.114)--
One-period lagged share of wheat-sown area--0.084-
--(0.059)-
One-period lagged share of rice-sown area---0.078 ***
---(0.027)
Wheat price0.560 ***-0.972 ***-
(0.150)-(0.123)-
Rice price-0.943 ***-0.876 ***
-(0.261)-(0.126)
Change in minimum price wheat (ΔPMW)0.009 ***-0.008 ***-
(0.002)-(0.002)-
Change in minimum price rice (ΔPMR)-0.049 **-0.072 ***
-(0.020)-(0.010)
Long-run price elasticity-1.274-0.950
Note: Standard errors in parentheses; * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Table A2. Main estimated elasticities for agrochemical use.
Table A2. Main estimated elasticities for agrochemical use.
Outcome VariablesFertilizer Use
(kg/ha)
Pesticides Use
(kg/ha)
Fertilizer Use
(kg/ha)
Pesticides Use
(kg/ha)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Wheat price (PriceWt−1)0.042 ***0.028 **0.044 ***0.032 **
(0.008)(0.013)(0.008)(0.013)
Rice price (PriceRt−1)0.039 ***0.039 ***0.043 ***0.045 ***
(0.008)(0.012)(0.008)(0.012)
Change in minimum price wheat (ΔPMW)0.019 ***0.034 ***0.018 ***0.036 ***
(0.002)(0.003)(0.002)(0.003)
Dummy for PMW province (DW) * ΔPMW−0.0000.001 ***−0.0000.001 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Change in minimum price rice (ΔPMR)−0.063 ***−0.124 ***−0.061 ***−0.123 ***
(0.007)(0.012)(0.007)(0.012)
Dummy for PMR province (DR) * ΔPMR−0.005 ***−0.003 **−0.005 ***−0.001 ***
(0.001)(0.002)(0.001)(0.002)
Wheat-sown area (AreaW)−0.031 ***−0.039 ***--
(0.002)(0.003)--
Rice-sown area (AreaR)−0.015 ***−0.024 ***--
(0.002)(0.003)--
Wheat-sown land share (AreaW)--−0.092 ***−0.187 ***
--(0.005)(0.008)
Rice-sown land share (AreaR)--−0.0050.038 ***
--(0.005)(0.008)
Note: Standard errors in parentheses; * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Figure A1. Trends of average price for (A) Wheat and (B) Rice; In yuan/kg; All prices have been deflated to 1997 prices, using national consumer price index data. Source: Calculated from the RFOP survey data set 1997–2010 combined with [3].
Figure A1. Trends of average price for (A) Wheat and (B) Rice; In yuan/kg; All prices have been deflated to 1997 prices, using national consumer price index data. Source: Calculated from the RFOP survey data set 1997–2010 combined with [3].
Agriculture 11 00910 g0a1aAgriculture 11 00910 g0a1b
Figure A2. Parallel trends of the PMW program for (A) Fertilizer and (B) Pesticides; In kg/ha; For a 95% confidence interval. Source: Calculated from the RFOP survey data set 1997–2010.
Figure A2. Parallel trends of the PMW program for (A) Fertilizer and (B) Pesticides; In kg/ha; For a 95% confidence interval. Source: Calculated from the RFOP survey data set 1997–2010.
Agriculture 11 00910 g0a2aAgriculture 11 00910 g0a2b
Figure A3. Parallel trends of the PMR program for (A) Fertilizer and (B) Pesticides. In kg/ha; For a 95% confidence interval. Source: Calculated from the RFOP survey data set 1997–2010.
Figure A3. Parallel trends of the PMR program for (A) Fertilizer and (B) Pesticides. In kg/ha; For a 95% confidence interval. Source: Calculated from the RFOP survey data set 1997–2010.
Agriculture 11 00910 g0a3aAgriculture 11 00910 g0a3b

References

  1. Aragie, E.; Balie, J. Supporting Farmers and Consumers under Food Price Uncertainty: The Role of Price Support Policies. In Proceedings of the 5th International Conference of African Association of Agricultural Economists, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 23–26 September 2016. [Google Scholar]
  2. Guda, H.; Dawande, M.; Janakiraman, G.; Rajapakshe, T. An Economic Analysis of Agricultural Support Prices in Developing Economies. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Cheng, G. China’s Agricultural Subsidies, 1st ed.; China Development Press: Beijing, China, 2011; pp. 37–38. [Google Scholar]
  4. Huang, J.; Yang, G. Understanding recent challenges and new food policy in China. Glob. Food Secur. 2017, 12, 119–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Heerink, N.; Kuiper, M.; Shi, X. Farm household responses to China’s new rural income support policy: A village-level analysis. In Dragons with Clay Feet? Transition, Sustainable Land Use, and Rural Environment in China and Vietnam, 1st ed.; Spoor, M., Heerink, N., Qu, F., Eds.; Lanham: Lexington, KY, USA, 2010; pp. 147–160. [Google Scholar]
  6. Gale, F. Growth and Evolution in China’s Agricultural Support Policies. Economic Research Report No. (ERR-153); United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service: Washington, DC, USA, 2013. Available online: https://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/pub-details/?pubid=45118 (accessed on 20 June 2021).
  7. Li, J.; Liu, W.; Song, Z. Sustainability of the Adjustment Schemes in China’s Grain Price Support Policy—An Empirical Analysis Based on the Partial Equilibrium Model of Wheat. Sustainability 2020, 12, 6447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Li, J.; Chavas, J. How Have China’s Agricultural Price Support Policies Affected Market Prices? A Quantile Regression Evaluation. In Proceedings of the 30th International Conference of Agricultural Economists, Vancouver, British, 28 July–2 August 2018. [Google Scholar]
  9. Kozicka, M.; Kalkuhl, M.; Brockhaus, J. Food Grain Policies in India and their Implications for Stocks and Fiscal Costs: A Dynamic Partial Equilibrium Analysis. J. Agric. Econ. 2017, 68, 98–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Traill, B. The Effect of Price Support Policies on Agricultural Investment, Employment, Farm Incomes and Land Values in the U.K. J. Agric. Econ. 1982, 33, 369–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Mushtaq, K.; Dawson, P. Acreage response in Pakistan: A co-integration approach. Agric. Econ. 2002, 27, 111–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Qian, J.; Ito, S.; Zhao, Z. The effect of price support policies on food security and farmers’ income in China. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 2020, 64, 1328–1349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Kim, K.; Chavas, J. A dynamic analysis of the effects of a price support program on price dynamics and price volatility. J. Agr. Resour. Econ. 2002, 27, 495–514. [Google Scholar]
  14. Lyu, J.; Li, X. Effectiveness and Sustainability of Grain Price Support Policies in China. Sustainability 2019, 11, 2478. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Qian, J.; Ito, S.; Mu, Y.; Isoda, H. Effect of Grain Price Support Policy in China: A Grey Relational Analysis. J. Fac. Agric. Kyushu Univ. 2013, 58, 485–491. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Tripathi, A. Agricultural price policy, output, and farm profitability—Examining linkages during post-reform period in India. Asian J. Agric. Dev. 2012, 10, 1–21. [Google Scholar]
  17. Sadoulet, E.; Janvry, A. Quantitative Development Policy Analysis, 1st ed.; The Johns Hopkins University Press: Baltimore, MD, USA, 1995; Chapter 3; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  18. Koester, U. Foundations of Agricultural Market Analysis and Agricultural Policy; Vahlen Franz GmbH: München, Germany, 2020; pp. 60–65. [Google Scholar]
  19. Bayramoglu, B.; Chakir, R. The impact of high crop prices on the use of agro-chemical inputs in France: A structural econometric analysis. Land Use Policy 2016, 55, 204–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Ali, S.; Sidhu, R.; Vatta, K. Effectiveness of minimum support price policy for paddy in India with a case study of Punjab. Agric. Econ. Res. Rev. 2012, 25, 231–242. [Google Scholar]
  21. Aditya, K.; Subash, S.; Praveen, K.; Nithyashree, M.; Bhuvana, N.; Sharma, A. Awareness about Minimum Support Price and Its Impact on Diversification Decision of Farmers in India. Asia Pac. Policy Stud. 2017, 4, 514–526. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Krishnaswamy, N. At What Price? Price Supports, Agricultural Productivity, and Misallocation. 2017. Available online: https://pacdev.ucdavis.edu/files/conference-schedule/session/papers/1D/Krishnaswamy.pdf (accessed on 20 August 2021).
  23. Chintapalli, P.; Tang, C. The Impact of Crop Minimum Support Prices on Crop Production and Farmer Welfare. 2018. Available online: http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3262407 (accessed on 20 August 2021).
  24. Ritu, V.; Mehta, D.; Malik, R.; Nisha, S. Impact of agricultural price policy on major food crops in Haryana. Econ. Aff. 2020, 65, 267–274. [Google Scholar]
  25. Nie, Z.; Heerink, N.; Tu, Q.; Jin, S. Does certified food production reduce agrochemical use in China? China Agr. Econ. Rev. 2018, 10, 386–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Jin, S.; Bluemling, B.; Mol, A.P. Information, trust and pesticide overuse: Interactions between retailers and cotton farmers in China. NJAS-Wagening. J. Life Sci. 2015, 72–73, 23–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Wu, Y.; Xi, X.; Tang, X.; Luo, D.; Gu, B.; Lam, S.K.; Vitousek, P.M.; Chen, D. Policy distortions, farm size, and the overuse of agricultural chemicals in China. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2018, 115, 7010–7015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Ren, C.; Liu, S.; van Grinsven, H.; Reis, S.; Jin, S.; Liu, H.; Gu, B. The impact of farm size on agricultural sustainability. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 220, 357–367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. NBS. China Rural Statistical Yearbook 1998–2020. Available online: https://navi.cnki.net/knavi/yearbooks/YMCTJ/detail (accessed on 16 September 2021).
  30. MOA. Plan for Zero Growth in Chemical Fertilizer and Pesticides Use in 2020. Available online: http://www.moa.gov.cn/nybgb/2015/san/201711/t20171129_5923401.htm (accessed on 29 May 2021).
  31. MOA. Plan for Regulating High-Toxic Pesticides Sold in Designated Stores and Giving Subsidies to Low-Toxic Biological Pesticide in Pilot Demonstration Areas Since 2015. Available online: http://www.moa.gov.cn/nybgb/2015/si/201711/t20171129_6134100.htm (accessed on 20 May 2021).
  32. MOA. Action Plan for Replacing Chemical Fertilizer with Organic Fertilizer Targeted at Fruit, Vegetable and Tea. Available online: http://www.moa.gov.cn/nybgb/2017/derq/201712/t20171227_6130977.htm (accessed on 29 May 2021).
  33. NDRC. Notice on Issuing the Wheat and Rice Minimum Purchase Price Implementation Plan. Available online: http://www.gov.cn/xinwen/2018-05/19/content_5292117.htm (accessed on 29 May 2021).
  34. USTR. China-Domestic Support for Agricultural Producers (DS511). Available online: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/enforcement/DS/US.Sub1.fin_1.pdf (accessed on 3 September 2021).
  35. Lichtenberg, E.; Zilberman, D. The Econometrics of Damage Control: Why Specification Matters. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 1986, 68, 261–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Schreinemachers, P.; Grovermann, C.; Praneetvatakul, S.; Heng, P.; Nguyen, T.T.L.; Buntong, B.; Le, N.T.; Pinn, T. How much is too much? Quantifying pesticide overuse in vegetable production in Southeast Asia. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 244, 118738. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Benjamin, D.; Brandt, L. Property rights, labour markets, and efficiency in a transition economy: The case of rural China. Can. J. Econ. /Rev. Can. d’économique 2002, 35, 689–716. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Ju, X.; Gu, B.; Wu, Y.; Galloway, J.N. Reducing China’s fertilizer use by increasing farm size. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2016, 41, 26–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Nerlove, M. The Dynamics of Supply: Estimation of Farmers’ Response to Price, 1st ed.; Johns Hopkins University Press: Baltimore, MD, USA, 1958; pp. 35–90. [Google Scholar]
  40. Nerlove, M. The Dynamics of Supply: Retrospect and Prospect. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 1979, 61, 874–888. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  41. Nerlove, M.; Bessler, D. Expectations, information and dynamics. In Handbook of Agricultural Economics, 1st ed.; Gardner, B., Rausser, G., Eds.; Elsevier Science: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2001; Volume 1, pp. 155–206. [Google Scholar]
  42. Yi, F.; Sun, D.; Zhou, Y. Grain subsidy, liquidity constraints and food security—Impact of the grain subsidy program on the grain-sown areas in China. Food Policy 2015, 50, 114–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Gao, J.; Peng, C.; Shi, Q. Study on the High Chemical Fertilizer Consumption and Fertilization Behavior of Small Rural Household in China: Discovery from 1995–2016 National Fixed Point Survey Data. Manag. World 2019, 35, 120–132. [Google Scholar]
  44. FRED. Global Price of Wheat. Available online: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/PWHEAMTUSDA (accessed on 3 September 2021).
  45. FAO. FAO Rice Price Update. Available online: http://www.fao.org/economic/est/publications/rice-publications/the-fao-rice-price-update/en/ (accessed on 3 September 2021).
  46. Fredriksson, A.; Oliveira, G. Impact evaluation using Difference-in-Differences. RAUSP Manag. 2019, 54, 519–532. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Huang, J.; Wang, X.; Zhi, H.; Huang, Z.; Rozelle, S. Subsidies and distortions in China’s agriculture: Evidence from producer-level data. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 2011, 55, 53–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  48. Nickell, S. Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects. Econometrica 1981, 49, 1417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Yu, B.; Liu, F.; You, L. Dynamic Agricultural Supply Response Under Economic Transformation: A Case Study of Henan, China. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2011, 94, 370–376. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  50. Siad, S.M.; Gioia, A.; Hoogenboom, G.; Iacobellis, V.; Novelli, A.; Tarantino, E.; Zdruli, P. Durum Wheat Cover Analysis in the Scope of Policy and Market Price Changes: A Case Study in Southern Italy. Agriculture 2017, 7, 12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  51. Wang, Q.; Li, F.; Yu, J.; Fleskens, L.; Ritsema, C.J. Price decline, land rental markets and grain production in the North China Plain. China Agric. Econ. Rev. 2020, 13, 124–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Lu, W. Effects of agricultural market policy on crop production in China. Food Policy 2002, 27, 561–573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Rahman, S.; Chima, C.D. Determinants of Pesticide Use in Food Crop Production in Southeastern Nigeria. Agriculture 2018, 8, 35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  54. Baron, R.M.; Kenny, D.A. The moderator-mediator variable distinction in social psychological research: Conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 1986, 51, 1173–1182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Huang, J.; Rozelle, S.; Chang, M. Tracking Distortions in Agriculture: China and Its Accession to the World Trade Organization. World Bank Econ. Rev. 2004, 18, 59–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  56. Huang, J.; Rozelle, S. The emergence of agricultural commodity markets in China. China Econ. Rev. 2006, 17, 266–280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Theoretical framework.
Figure 1. Theoretical framework.
Agriculture 11 00910 g001
Table 1. Officially applied minimum grain prices (yuan/kg, current-year prices).
Table 1. Officially applied minimum grain prices (yuan/kg, current-year prices).
Crop & TypeWhite WheatRed/Mixed WheatEarly Indica RiceMid/Late Indica RiceJaponica Rice
Designated
Provinces
Henan, Hebei, Jiangsu, Anhui, Shandong, HubeiSee ‘White Wheat’Hunan, Hubei, Jiangxi, Anhui, Guangxi aJilin, Anhui, Jiangxi, Hubei, Hunan, Sichuan, Heilongjiang, Liaoning a, Jiangsu a, Guangxi a, Henan aSee ‘Mid/Late Indica Rice’
Year
2005 1.401.441.50
20061.441.381.401.441.50
20071.441.381.401.441.50
20081.441.381.541.581.64
20091.741.661.801.841.90
20101.801.721.861.942.10
20111.901.862.042.142.56
20122.042.042.402.502.80
20132.242.242.642.703.00
20142.362.362.702.763.10
20152.362.362.702.763.10
20162.362.362.662.763.10
20172.362.362.602.723.00
20182.302.302.402.522.60
20192.242.242.402.522.60
20202.242.242.422.542.60
20212.262.262.442.562.60
Note: a Policy started in 2008. Sources: [3,4] for 2005–2011, [34] for 2012–2015, and various online policy documents after 2016 (details available upon request from first author).
Table 2. Mean values of variables used in empirical analysis.
Table 2. Mean values of variables used in empirical analysis.
1997199819992000200120022003 a2004200520062007200820092010
Fertilizer use (kg/ha)903.88900.13900.04917.58901.21949.601028.461006.00963.93991.371026.04956.081054.371094.22
Pesticides use (kg/ha)9.079.7910.3510.8811.5112.4014.3916.0717.4018.4717.4017.2217.4018.28
Wheat price (yuan/kg)1.351.341.220.961.020.99.1.391.321.351.361.421.481.65
Rice price (yuan/kg)1.421.531.241.121.241.11.1.561.631.561.741.761.691.99
Wheat-sown area b (ha)0.140.130.140.130.120.110.090.070.070.080.090.090.090.09
Rice-sown area b (ha)0.190.180.190.170.160.150.140.160.170.160.140.130.140.13
Share of wheat-sown area (%)18.4417.2116.8316.1615.0115.0414.3310.5111.0311.2713.5913.7913.3813.22
Share of rice-sown area (%)28.0727.7027.9527.0826.1225.7925.5128.0728.0026.7323.5422.0223.1421.50
Fertilizer price (yuan/kg)1.371.271.221.131.101.121.181.311.511.521.561.941.761.75
Pesticides price (yuan/kg)23.0922.0022.7922.4421.2820.5121.4322.6924.3824.9126.8628.3430.2531.24
Maize price (yuan/kg)1.181.221.091.010.981.02.1.201.141.221.411.271.391.95
Minimum price wheat (PMW, yuan/kg)0000000001.311.251.181.441.44
Minimum price rice (PMR, yuan/kg)000000001.391.371.311.351.581.64
Dummy for PMW province (DW)0000000000.340.270.280.280.28
Dummy for PMR province (DR)000000000.390.390.320.490.510.51
Change in PMW (∆PMW, yuan/kg) c0000000000−0.06−0.070.260
Change in PMR (∆PMR, yuan/kg) c000000000−0.02−0.060.040.230.06
Annual total sunshine ( × 100 h)19.5519.0718.9218.7019.4218.4618.1719.9818.6718.5519.0519.4519.3718.95
Annual total precipitation ( × 100 m)8.8910.409.608.988.729.4410.009.1810.139.468.079.428.8810.34
Annual average temperature (degrees Celsius)14.2614.9314.3314.0614.3414.5314.2314.5314.1114.7214.9314.3214.4514.08
World wheat price index (1997 = 100)10075.3863.3162.8064.4878.8776.9676.3771.2890.06119.69146.0796.1296.11
World rice price index (1997 = 100) 10099.5685.6573.9463.6962.3770.1385.9490.0495.75116.11204.10158.71159.30
Notes: a Crop price information is missing in 2003 in the Rural Fixed Observation Points (RFOP) data set; All price variables have been deflated to 1997 prices, using national consumer price index data. b Mis-recordings of sown areas were identified by comparing its data for the same household for different years. We corrected those mis-recorded data multiplying them by (various dimensions) of 0.1 or 10. c The value of Δ P M is assumed to be zero during the years before the start of the procurement price program and the year when it started. Source: RFOP survey data set and [3,29,44,45].
Table 3. Fixed effects regression results for wheat and rice price.
Table 3. Fixed effects regression results for wheat and rice price.
Wheat Price Rice Price
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Coefficient SE Coefficient SE
Minimum price wheat (PMW)0.147 ***(0.002)--
Dummy for PMW province (DW) * PMW−0.001(0.002)--
Minimum price rice (PMR)--0.218 ***(0.002)
Dummy for PMR province (DR) * PMR--−0.037 ***(0.003)
World wheat price (WPW) 0.146 ***(0.005)--
World rice price (WPR) --0.262 ***(0.004)
Annual total sunshine (sun)0.030 ***(0.001)0.009 *** (0.001)
Annual total precipitation (pre)0.020 ***(0.000)0.007 ***(0.000)
Annual average temperature (tem)−0.026 ***(0.001)0.003(0.002)
Household fixed effectsYes Yes
Observations191,439 234,810
R20.150 0.194
Note: Household clustered standard errors in parentheses; * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01; World wheat price index and World rice price index were divided by 100.
Table 4. Difference generalized methods of moments (GMM) regression results for sown land areas.
Table 4. Difference generalized methods of moments (GMM) regression results for sown land areas.
Outcome VariablesLand Area (ha)Share of Land (%)
WheatRiceWheatRice
(1)(2)(3)(4)
One-period lagged wheat-sown area (AreaWt−1)0.215---
(0.134)---
One-period lagged rice-sown area (AreaRt−1)-0.285 ***--
-(0.062)--
One-period lagged wheat-sown area share (AreaWt−1)--0.048-
--(0.037)-
One-period lagged rice-sown area share (AreaRt−1)---0.040 ***
---(0.014)
Wheat price (PriceWt−1)0.112 **-9.090 ***-
(0.044)-(0.921)-
Rice price (PriceRt−1)-0.116 **-7.836 ***
-(0.046)-(1.281)
Change in minimum price wheat (ΔPMW)0.168 ***-6.897 ***-
(0.028)-(1.272)-
Dummy for PMW province (DW) * ΔPMW−0.000-0.240-
(0.010)-(0.270)-
Change in minimum price rice (ΔPMR)-0.328 ***-34.911 ***
-(0.052)-(2.874)
Dummy for PMR province (DR) * ΔPMR-0.006-−3.745 ***
-(0.015)-(0.824)
Maize price, year t − 10.067 *−0.024−0.4611.268
(0.039)(0.041)(0.914)(1.370)
Observations94,778105,59194,778105,589
AR(1) test p-value0.0000.0000.0000.000
AR(2) test p-value0.0560.1430.0310.688
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses; * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Table 5. Fixed effects regression results for agrochemical use.
Table 5. Fixed effects regression results for agrochemical use.
Outcome VariablesFertilizer Use
(kg/ha)
Pesticides Use
(kg/ha)
Fertilizer Use
(kg/ha)
Pesticides Use
(kg/ha)
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Wheat price (PriceWt−1)31.874 ***0.308 ** 33.238 ***0.342 **
(6.285)(0.143)(6.382)(0.143)
Rice price (PriceRt−1)26.029 ***0.367 ***28.171 ***0.420 ***
(5.042)(0.112)(5.081)(0.113)
Change in minimum price wheat (ΔPMW)1771.208 ***45.606 ***1711.530 ***44.491 ***
(176.246)(4.290)(175.853)(4.266)
Dummy for PMW province (DW) * ΔPMW−28.7134.036 ***−39.0273.858 ***
(64.388)(1.515)(63.777)(1.494)
Change in minimum price rice (ΔPMR)−2612.994 ***−73.951 ***−2538.162 ***−73.000 ***
(308.339)(7.275)(307.070)(7.219)
Dummy for PMR province (DR) * ΔPMR−445.303 ***−3.615 **−389.970 ***−1.672
(82.597)(1.783)(81.557)(1.760)
Wheat-sown area (AreaW)−239.801 ***−4.298 ***--
(15.062)(0.328)--
Rice-sown area (AreaR)−102.024 ***−2.301 ***--
(12.001)(0.326)--
Wheat-sown land share (AreaW)--−5.095 ***−0.148 ***
--(0281)(0.006)
Rice-sown land share (AreaR)--−0.1980.023 ***
--(0.195)(0.005)
ln (Fertilizer price)−598.742 ***1.610 ***−602.962 ***1.561 ***
(12.028)(0.173)(12.045)(0.172)
ln (Pesticides price)70.896 ***−10.772 ***66.978 ***−10.859 ***
(5.173)(0.152)(5.101)(0.152)
Maize price, year t − 122.030 **0.06823.492 **0.133
(10.481)(0.176)(10.448)(0.173)
Household fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Observations128,536128,536128,536128,536
R20.1040.1720.1070.182
Note: Household clustered standard errors in parentheses; * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Table 6. Estimated effects for the provinces that implemented the minimum grain procurement price policy until 2010.
Table 6. Estimated effects for the provinces that implemented the minimum grain procurement price policy until 2010.
Chemical FertilizerChemical Pesticides
CoefficientEffect (kg/ha)CoefficientEffect (kg/ha)
Wheat price (PriceWt−1)31.8740.6090.3080.006
Rice price (PriceRt−1)26.0291.1780.3670.017
Change in minimum price wheat (△PMW)1771.20846.05145.6061.186
Dummy for PMW province (DW) * △PMW004.0360.105
Change in minimum price rice (△PMR)−2612.994−108.875−73.951−3.081
Dummy for PMR province (DR) * △PMR−445.303−18.554−3.615−0.151
Wheat-sown area (AreaW)−239.801−5.751−4.298−0.103
Rice-sown area (AreaR)−102.024−9.011−2.301−0.203
Total-−94.352-−2.225
Note: Derived from coefficient estimates presented in Table 5, actual increases in minimum procurement prices for rice and estimated changes in wheat and rice prices and areas caused by these increases (only for the sown area instead of the share of the grain in total sown area).
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Su, M.; Heerink, N.; Oosterveer, P.; Tan, T.; Feng, S. Impacts of China’s Minimum Grain Procurement Price Program on Agrochemical Use: A Household-Level Analysis. Agriculture 2021, 11, 910. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture11100910

AMA Style

Su M, Heerink N, Oosterveer P, Tan T, Feng S. Impacts of China’s Minimum Grain Procurement Price Program on Agrochemical Use: A Household-Level Analysis. Agriculture. 2021; 11(10):910. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture11100910

Chicago/Turabian Style

Su, Min, Nico Heerink, Peter Oosterveer, Tao Tan, and Shuyi Feng. 2021. "Impacts of China’s Minimum Grain Procurement Price Program on Agrochemical Use: A Household-Level Analysis" Agriculture 11, no. 10: 910. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture11100910

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop