Next Article in Journal
Leveraging Big Data Tools and Technologies: Addressing the Challenges of the Water Quality Sector
Previous Article in Journal
Stability of Deep Underground Openings through Large Fault Zones in Argillaceous Rock
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Coordination Contracts in a Dual-Channel Supply Chain with a Risk-Averse Retailer

1
Academy of Chinese Energy Strategy, China University of Petroleum-Beijing, 18 Fuxue Road, Changping, Beijing 102200, China
2
Mathematical Sciences, University of Southampton, University Road, Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK
3
School of Industrial Management Engineering, Korea University, Anamdong 5-ga, Seongbuk-gu, Seoul 136-713, Korea
4
School of Business and Management, Queen Mary University of London, Mile End Road, London E1 4NS, UK
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2017, 9(11), 2148; https://doi.org/10.3390/su9112148
Submission received: 7 October 2017 / Revised: 18 November 2017 / Accepted: 19 November 2017 / Published: 22 November 2017

Abstract

:
Dual channels have become popular strategies for manufacturers due to the development of innovative selling platforms. Examples in practice also show that the lack of relationship management, such as cooperation and sharing, may cause an unsustainable supply chain performance. However, previous studies on coordination of dual-channel supply chains always focus on the contribution to profits and neglect the sustainability of relationship development between channel members. In this paper, we study the coordination of a dual-channel supply chain including a direct channel and a traditional channel. Under the fact that sustainable economy, instead of profit maximization, is the more appropriate objective in channel members’ decision making, we consider the retailer’s risk exposure and assume the risk degree is also a factor that impacts decision making. We assume the manufacturer is risk-neutral and the retailer is risk-averse, and measure the risk attitude with Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) approach. Two traditional contracts widely used in single-channel supply chains, i.e., revenue-sharing contract and buy-back contract, are analyzed first. Although some researchers have discussed that traditional contracts cannot coordinate the dual-channel supply chain, our results show that traditional contracts can still come into play with restrictions on the risk-averse degree. Then we propose a risk-sharing contract which could distribute profits between two channel members and coordinate the system under varied risk-averse degrees with a fixed risk-sharing degree. Finally, we analyze the sensitivity of different parameters to illustrate the stable coordinating outcomes of this contract, and prove its generalization with more powerful channel members. The results provide important managerial insights.

1. Introduction

Internet is an area that has experienced tremendous recent development. It has not only changed people’s life-style, but has also brought about a dramatic alteration among the structure of supply chain. For example, the expansion of some new platforms, such as mobile devices, provides new channels in many industries. Although a multi-channel structure provides more opportunities for companies, it is also creating a challenge to traditional channels, thus changing the strategies and operations of companies [1]. Therefore, new distribution systems, also known as dual-channel supply chains, become a possible option, and manufacturers, such as Dell, HP, IBM, Nike and Mattel, extend their selling activities from single channels to a dual-channel approach in which manufacturers tend to acquire consumers’ subliminal need, enhance the efficiency of the supply chain and gain huge profits [2,3].
In fact, a growing number of studies have focused on electronic supply chains and the competition between direct channels and traditional channels. Whether new channels should be established is a crucial question for companies, and literature shows that adding new channels may generally benefit the performance of a company [4,5,6]. Researchers also discuss this question through a game theoretical approach, where pricing competition is a main focus in this horizontal channel conflict. For example, Chiang, Chhajed [7] model a price-setting game between a manufacturer and its independent retailer in a dual-channel supply chain and find that direct marketing can improve the manufacturer’s overall profitability. Cattani, Gilland [8] find that the manufacturer, the retailer and consumers can prefer the same equal-pricing strategies when the manufacturer opens up a direct channel with a traditional channel partner. Huang and Swaminathan [9] find that a new competing channel sometimes benefits the incumbent firm because of the new consumers brought by the new channel and the cost advantage of the incumbent; in this case, a mixed firm might have a higher pricing strategy. Matsui [10] investigates the pricing competition between two symmetric manufacturers and compares their different channel policies. In addition, some literature has considered inventory decisions. For example, Yao, Yue [11] study three inventory strategies in retail and e-tail stores. Chiang [12] assumes that the supplier and the retailer could choose their own base-stock level, and finds that the positive effect of combined vertical-horizontal competition on supply chain efficiency may not always exist in a dual-channel supply chain. Moreover, Dumrongsiri, Fan [13] study the decision-making in both price and order quantity choices, and find that the manufacturer may benefit from the dual-channel. Huang, Yang [14] consider the changes to the prices and production plan under a demand disruption, and they conclude that the optimal pricing decisions are affected by consumers’ preference for the direct channel and the market scale change. Apart from the pricing and inventory management, Tsay and Agrawal [3] discuss the manufacturer’s channel selection through optimizing the sales effort in each channel. Much research indicates that manufacturers and retailers tend to introduce direct channels as a beneficial strategy.
Dual channels force manufacturers to face both vertical channel conflicts (e.g., double marginalization) and horizontal channel conflicts (e.g., retailers’ rival), thus, it is important for them to find a feasible way to remain their profitability continuously and sustainability. Although manufacturers’ profits may increase to some extent, the competition with retailers may lead to counterproductive results [3]. As an example, Compaq Computer used to be a famous computer producer with its highest market share (around 26%) in 1995. Nevertheless, it blindly followed Dell’s dual-channel strategy, and deprived distributors of their profits, then Compaq Computer finally acquired by HP because of distributors’ counterattacks in 2001. The example of Compaq Computer can be seen as a lesson of unsustainable development. Therefore, apart from the value creating activities, companies should also focus on the sustainable economy which is described as “a system that built on collaboration and sharing, rather than aggressive competition” (p. 43) [15]. In this case with incorporating a new channel, efficient coordinating the supply chain with the traditional channel and online channel has been a new major issue that should be paid more attention on.
In order to promote the inter-organizational relationship and address the problem of profitable but unsustainable development, supply chain coordination is an appropriate solution in the literature and practice, which promotes a way of corporation instead of brutal competition. A large volume of literature has focused on dual-channel supply chain coordination that increases the channel members’ profits, and the results are quite different from that in a single channel supply chain. Some papers have argued that most of the well-known contracts in single-channel situation, such as price-only, buy-back, rebate, revenue-sharing and vendor manage inventory contracts, fail to coordinate a multi-channel distribution system [16], a risk-neutral dual-channel supply chain can be coordinated by some new contracts. For example, a profit-sharing contract [17,18], a compensation-commission contract [16], a two-part tariff contract [17] and a combination of a revenue-sharing contract and a pricing scheme [19]. However, under the sustainability consideration, profit maximization is not the only objective for channel members. The decision makers are facing more intense competition now than years ago, especially in a dual-channel case, which implies that they would consider uncertainties as a necessary factor when they are making decisions. The competitive new direct channel of manufacturers boosts the risk exposure of downstream retailers, thus it is reasonable and necessary for retailers to consider the risk factor as well as the profits and combine them to make their decisions. In contrast to the papers above, we consider the risk preference of firms and assume the retailers are risk-averse. Although there is a growing stream of research in the dual-channel supply chain coordination, there has been relatively little focused on the increasing risk averseness under updated market environment. As exceptions, several studies develop contracts to coordinate a dual-channel supply chain with risk-averse entities, such as profit-sharing contracts [20], a two-way revenue sharing contract [2] and a risk-sharing contract [21]. However, apart from these complex contracts, the common contracts used in reality are the simple ones, e.g., buy-back contracts. Although the simple contracts are not perfect in a risk-averse situation, they are widely exploited because of the simplification and operability [22], thus it is insightful to discuss their application in a risk-averse circumstance within a multi-channel supply chain.
How to measure the impact of risk-averse degree on entities’ optimal decisions and profits is an important question that contributes to the operations efficiency. Mean-variance and Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) are two major risk models that are widely used in literature. Some studies considered risk-averse newsvendor problems with the mean-variance approach and compared the different strategies developed for risk-averse and risk-neutral objectives [2,23]. Some papers used the CVaR framework to study the newsvendor problem with price and order decisions [24,25,26,27,28,29] and measured service levels [30]. However, the mean-variance model is only suitable for the case where the profit distribution is symmetric, which means that this model may have bias on risk measure [31]. As applied widely both in theoretical research and practical areas, CVaR model makes a balance between the expected profit and the risk [32]. Therefore, in this paper, we use CVaR model instead of maximizing the profit to measure the risk attitude of the retailer.
Motivated by these facts, this paper aims to discuss the coordination of several single contracts from a risk-averse perspective and design a different yet practical contract. We consider a two-echelon supply chain model consisting of a risk-neutral manufacturer and a risk-averse retailer. The manufacturer sells its single product through a traditional retail channel as well as a direct channel. We develop a quantity-decide model, and coordinate the manufacturer and the retailer with our risk-averse contract. Besides, we assume that the demand model depending linearly on the prices, market shares and substitutability of the product in two channels.
This study contributes to the literature in two main ways. First, we analyze the limitations of traditional contracts which might lose efficacy under the risk-averse condition. Previous research has argued that traditional contracts such as revenue-sharing contract and wholesale price contract cannot coordinate a dual-channel supply chain [16,21]. However, their assumptions simplify the cost structure and thus amplify the side effect of double marginalization. For example, the assumption of zero producing cost narrows down the scope of possible wholesale price [21], which may influence the coordination results significantly. Actually, our results show that these contracts can still coordinate the supply chain in a low risk-averse supply chain. Problems only arise when a negative wholesale price is required in traditional contracts when the retailer’s risk-averse degree is higher than a threshold. The limitation of traditional contracts on the risk-averse degree cannot be ignored, thus, we also contribute to the literature as well as practice by proposing a risk-sharing contract. A negative wholesale price restricts the usage rate of traditional contracts in this risk-averse situation. Therefore, calling for new coordination schemes is of important significance in practical application. Compared with traditional contracts, the new risk-sharing contract sets the wholesale price within a threshold which can ensure the manufacturer’s acceptance. A fixed risk-sharing degree can coordinate the system under varied risk-averse degrees, which has significant advantage when the retailer’s risk degree is vibrating under uncertainties and challenges. This property benefits the stability and sustainability of the long-term relationship. Results also show that the risk-sharing contract can also be applicable when channel members have the power to control selling prices. We provide managerial insights in the conclusion to connect our research closely with practice.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we detail our model assumptions. In Section 3, we model the retailer’s risk aversion by CVaR model and verify two coordinating contracts designed for channels consisting of risk-neutral channel members. In Section 4, we propose a new risk-sharing contract that achieves the coordination and then provide detailed discussions about the sensitivity. We also extend our research by considering the cases when channel members have the power to decide selling prices. In Section 5, we conclude the paper and provide managerial insights. All proofs are presented in Appendix A.

2. Model Assumptions

We first assume there are one manufacturer and one retailer. With the rising of e-commerce, the manufacturer adds an additional channel through Internet called online channel, (i.e., direct channel) as a graphical structure in Figure 1. Therefore, the manufacturer extends its operations to both producting and selling activities, and this dual-channel strategy can reduce its risks with a portfolio [3]. The retailer, however, has more risk exposure, and its situation has changed from cooperating with a single retail-channel manufacturer to competing with the manufacturer’s vertical integration strategy. Therefore, we consider the case when the manufacturer is risk-neutral and the retailer is risk-averse.
The notations used in this paper are listed as follows:
p i Price per unit of the retail channel and the direct channel, i = 1 , 2 ;
q i Sales volume of the retail channel and the direct channel, i = 1 , 2 ;
u Market share of the retail channel ( 0 < u < 1 );
X Stochastic consumer demand with X [ 0 , X ¯ ] ;
θ i Substitutability of the products in two channels ( 0 < θ < 1 ), i = 1 , 2 ;
F ( x ) Cumulative distribution function of x ;
f ( x ) Probability density function of x ;
w Wholesale price per unit;
c Production cost per unit;
s i Salvage value per unit for the retailer and the manufacturer, i = 1 , 2 ;
Q i Order quantity of the retail channel and the direct channel, i = 1 , 2 ;
π R Profit of the retailer;
π M Profit of the manufacturer;
C V a R R CVaR value of the retailer.
We consider a linear demand function with selling prices and market demand in each channel, where subscript 1 and 2 denote the retail channel and direct channel, respectively. In line with [9], the demands for the retail and online channels are defined as:
q 1 = u X p 1 + θ 1 p 2 ,
q 2 = ( 1 u ) X p 2 + θ 2 p 1 ,
where 0 u 1 , 0 θ 1 , X is a random variable with X [ 0 , X ¯ ] and denotes the stochastic consumer demand. The cumulative distribution function and probability density function of X is F ( x ) and f ( x ) , respectively.
We use the parameter u to represent the market share of the retail channel, then u would increase if more consumers prefer to purchase in retail stores instead of the online shop. The range of u is not simply determined by the difference in service quality and the number of retail stores, it is also affected by individuals’ acceptance of network resources, consumption patterns and residence location. Generally, the online channel has significantly developed and it is more convenient for people who will not prefer wasting extra travelling time [33]. However, the online channel still has some limits such as the uncertain quality, increased risk and the consumers’ preference for traditional retailers. For example, the acceptance of online shopping is much higher for young people than older people, and there exist consumers who prefer to search online and purchase in retail stores [34,35,36]. Note that although we present a fixed parameter u for the consumer segmentation, this doesn’t mean that a single consumer’s channel preference is constant. In fact, consumers’ purchasing attitude is changing from time to time, while we aim to capture a general ratio in the whole market. In practice, consumer segmentation is an important factor for companies’ decision making, and many third-party companies, such as IBM and Alibaba, release reports to capture consumers’ behavior and preference annually [37].
The θ i ( i = 1 , 2 ) denotes the channel substitutability as the single product is selling in the market. Normally we assume 0 < θ i < 1 ( i = 1 , 2 ) [38]. More specifically, θ i ( i = 1 , 2 ) measures the percentage change of demand in one channel that occurs in response to a percentage change of price in the other channel. Perishable products with a short shelf life, for example vegetables, are more suitable to offline purchasing. Whereas products with a steady consumption rate and long shelf life, for example shampoo, are more likely to be switched to online channel from traditional offline channel. Therefore, the substitutability of shampoo is expected to be larger than that of other perishable products. In this linear demand function, although consumers have their initial preferred channel, their purchasing decision may change according to the selling prices in channels.
We assume the products sold in two channels are identical and thus they have the production cost ( c ) and salvage value ( s i ). The inventory cost can be derived from the salvage value ( s i ): unsold items can be sold in next selling-period and a holding cost ( h i ) would be expended, thus a salvage cost represents the sourcing cost minus the holding cost. For example, the salvage value for the retailer can be interpreted as s 1 = w h 1 , and the salvage value for the retailer can be interpreted as s 2 = c h 2 . For simplification purpose, we assume that the order quantity of the retailer can always be fulfilled by the manufacturer. The retailer orders quantity Q 1 and the manufacturer produces quantity Q 2 for its direct selling online. Therefore, the profit functions of the manufacturer and the retailer are:
π M ( Q 2 , w ) = w Q 1 + p 2 m i n ( Q 2 ,   q 2 ) + s 2 [ Q 2 m i n ( Q 2 , q 2 ) ] ( Q 1 + Q 2 ) c ,
π R ( Q 1 ) = p 1 m i n ( Q 1 ,   q 1 ) + s 1 [ Q 1 m i n ( Q 1 , q 1 ) ] w Q 1 ,
Assuming the manufacturer’s product is highly substitutable with other similar products selling in the market, then consumers in this case tend to be more price sensitive. Thus in a competitive market, channel members may have no power to control the online and retail prices [11], in which case horizontal retailers have reached a balance where the selling price can neutralize the production and operating costs and ensure certain profit margin to maintain the running of channel members in the supply chains. If a product remains a higher selling price than other similar products, the demand would become low and channel members would loss the consumers; although a lower selling price can attract consumers, companies marketing other products would adjust their prices to win back consumers, thus the pricing competition would achieve the equilibrium as would be expected and the price is determined by factors as the products’ quality, market potential and consumers’ purchasing behaviors instead of the seller’s individual willingness. Following Yao, Yue [11] and Boyaci [16], we consider the case when the selling prices are exogenous and channel members can only decide their order quantities based on their inventory level and the market demand. In our discussion about the risk-sharing contract, we also test the contract by extending our model to the case when selling prices become endogenous.
In line with Li, Chen [28], we follow the Nash bargaining framework and assume that the manufacturer and the retailer has the identical bargaining power and move simultaneously in the retailing level, i.e., the manufacturer decides its wholesale price and then both the manufacturer and the retailer order certain numbers of products which are fulfilled by the manufacturer later.

3. Supply Chain Coordination

In this section, we consider the decentralized and centralized optimal order quantities and then compare several traditional contracts used in practice. A centralized supply chain system usually behaves better than a decentralized system; a contract which helps to coordinate a supply chain makes the entities’ optimal decisions equal to the centralized system and should be acceptable for each entity which means their utilities should be higher or at least steady [39,40].
Definition 1.
A contract can coordinate a supply chain if (1) the profit of the manufacturer is no less than the initial profit in the decentralized case; (2) the CVaR value of the retailer is no more than the initial CVaR value; (3) and the total profit of the supply chain reach the maximin, i.e., the manufacturer and the retailer’s order quantities equal that in the centralized system.
Let C V a R R ( Q 1 ) denote the retailer’s function of CVaR value without supply chain contracts. According to Rockafellar and Uryasev [32], the retailer’s CVaR value is:
C V a R R ( Q 1 ) = ( p 1 w ) Q 1 + u ( p 1 s 1 ) 1 β 0 Q 1 + p 1 θ 1 p 2 u F ( x ) d x .
In the centralized system, the order quantities are deducted from the profit in the whole supply chain. In the decentralized system, however, the manufacturer and the retailer set their order quantities, respectively. Gotoh and Takano [41] had provided the optimal solution of minimizing CVaR in a newsvendor model. We denote Q 1 C * and Q 2 C * as the centralized optimal order quantity of the retail and the direct channels and denote Q 1 D * and Q 2 D * as the decentralized optimal order quantity.
Theorem 1.
The optimal order quantities in the centralized and decentralized system are distinguished as detailed in Table 1, where F 1 ( x ) denotes the inverse function of F ( x ) .
Corollary 1.
If the random variable X follows a uniform distribution, i.e., X ~ U [ 0 , X ¯ ] , the optimal order quantities and optimal wholesale price in a decentralized system are:
Q 1 D * = u X ¯ p 1 w p 1 s 1 ( 1 β ) p 1 + θ 1 p 2 ;
Q 2 D * = ( 1 u ) X ¯ p 2 c p 2 s 2 p 2 + θ 2 p 1 .
w D * = p 1 + c 2 ( p 1 θ 1 p 2 ) ( p 1 s 1 ) 2 u ( 1 β ) X ¯ .
The manufacturer’s expected profits and the retailer’s CVaR value in the decentralized system are:
C V a R R ° = ( p 1 w D * ) Q 1 D * + u ( p 1 s 1 ) 1 β 0 Q 1 D * + p 1 θ 1 p 2 u F ( x ) d x ;
E π M ° = ( w D * c ) Q 1 D * + ( p 2 c ) Q 2 D * ( 1 u ) ( p 2 s 2 ) 0 Q 2 D * + p 2 θ 2 p 1 u F ( x ) d x .
As shown in Table 1, the decentralized order quantity equals the centralized order quantity in the direct channel, thus the main purpose of coordination contracts is to change the retailer’s order quantity to satisfy that in the centralized situation. Although we can have w = ( c β p 1 ) / ( 1 β ) < c (i.e., if Q 1 C * = Q 1 D * , we have p 1 c p 1 s 1 = p 1 w p 1 s 1 ( 1 β ) , then w = c β p 1 1 β . As w β = c p 1 ( 1 β ) 2 < 0 , thus w = c β p 1 1 β is decreasing in β and w = c β p 1 1 β < w ( β = 0 ) = c ) in a simple wholesale-price contract which unifies the retailer’s order quantity in two systems (i.e., centralized and decentralized), it is not acceptable for the manufacturer without any compensation for its loss in the retailing activities (i.e., the wholesale price is smaller than the production cost). Therefore, another requirement for the coordination contracts is their feasibility that will not cause the obvious loss for the entities.

3.1. Traditional Coordination Contracts

We test the channel coordination efficiency of several traditional contracts including revenue-sharing and buy-back contracts. First, we consider four revenue-sharing contracts, in first two contracts the manufacturer shares part of its revenue or profit to the retailer: 1 k portion of total revenue, i.e., ( 1 k ) [ w Q 1 + p 2 min ( Q 2 ,   q 2 ) + s 2 max ( Q 2 q 2 , 0 ) ] or 1 k portion of whole profit, i.e., ( 1 k ) π M . The manufacturer can also reduce the wholesale price to inspire the retailer, and the retailer shares part of its revenue to the retailer as an exchange. The portion that the retailer shares here in two retailer’s revenue-sharing contracts include: k portion of its revenue, i.e., k [ p 1 min ( Q 1 ,   q 1 ) + s 1 max ( Q 1 q 1 , 0 ) ] or k portion of its whole profit, i.e., k π R .
Lemma 1.
(1) In the contract where the manufacturer shares 1 k portion of total revenue to the retailer, the retailer can order the centralized order quantity and the supply chain’s total profit is maximized when
w = c β p 1 k ( 1 β ) ;
(2) In the contract where the retailer shares k portion of its revenue to the manufacturer, can make the retailer order the centralized order quantity and maximize the supply chain’s profit only when
w = ( 1 k ) ( c β p 1 ) 1 β   a n d   w < c .
(3) In the contract where the retailer shares k portion of its profit to the manufacturer, can make the retailer order the centralized order quantity and maximize the supply chain’s profit when
w = c β p 1 1 β   a n d   w < c .
These outcomes in Lemma 1 yield a number of insights. One might conjecture that the compensation from the manufacturer’s profits or revenue to the retailer can be an appropriate way to reduce the channel conflict if the manufacturer is adding another online channel. However, we have shown that this is not always the case. Actually, our unintuitive results illustrate that the lower wholesale price is a better way to influence the retailer’s order quantity and approach the coordination. As shown in Lemma 1, a dual-channel supply chain can still choose a traditional revenue-sharing contract with the condition w < c . This condition is also proved in a single-channel supply chain with a risk-averse retailer [39] as well as a risk-neutral single-channel supply chain [42]. In a dual-channel supply chain, a lower wholesale price is not only a constraint for the manufacturer when the retailer promises to share its revenue in the traditional channel, but also some compensation for the retailer when the manufacturer raises another channel. Let the manufacturer’s revenue-sharing contract, retailer’s revenue-sharing contract and retailer’s profit-sharing contract represent three contracts in Lemma 1, respectively. We will further illustrate their relationship with each other in the following discussion.
Second, with a buy-back contract, the manufacturer promises to buy the excess products back with price p b from the retailer. Compared with a quantity-discount contract, the retailer prefers a buy-back contract because it can reduce the downstream channel member’s risk. We denote p b as the buy-back price, and 0 < p b < p 1 .
Lemma 2.
A buy-back contract can make the retailer order the centralized order quantity and maximize the supply chain’s profit only when
w = p b ( p 1 c ) ( p 1 s 1 ) ( β p 1 c ) ( 1 β ) ( p 1 s 1 )   a n d   w < c .
Theorem 2.
When k = p b p 1 s 1 , the retailer’s profit-sharing contract and retailer’s revenue-sharing contract have the same coordination influence as the buy-back contract on the supply chain with either a risk-neutral or risk-averse retailer.
As shown in Theorem 2, the retailer’s revenue/profit-sharing and buy-back schemes have the same impact on entities’ profit change. No matter what the retailer shares to the manufacturer, i.e., revenue or profit, their profit changes are identical as they will accept different wholesale prices which cause the same result. Lemmas 1 and 2 and Theorem 2 also illustrate that there exists restriction (i.e., if w 0 , we have β c p 1 in Lemma 1.) on the risk-averse degree due to the nonnegative wholesale price. Thus, traditional contracts are also applicable when the risk-averse degree β c p 1 .
Corollary 2.
If the retailer is more risk-averse, in the four channels discussed above (i.e., manufacturer’s revenue-sharing contract, retailer’s profit-sharing contract, retailer’s revenue-sharing contract, and the buy-back contract), the wholesale price would be lower.
The finding in Corollary 2 is intuitive that in order to coordinate a supply chain with a risk-averse retailer, a contract should provide more compensation to the retailer through the wholesale activities. In the retailer’s revenue-sharing contract and profit-sharing contract, the retailer sacrifices part of its revenue or profit to gain a low wholesale price, while the manufacturer should provide a lower wholesale price when the retailer’s risk-averse degree is high.

3.2. Discussion

To generate insightful implications from the analytical results, we conduct a numerical analysis to further compare the contracts and explore deeper insights. Recap that E π M ° and C V a R R ° denote the manufacturer’s expected profits and the retailer’s CVaR value in the decentralized system, respectively. We assume Δ E π M = E π M E π M ° to represent the increment of manufacturer’s expected profits after adopting a contract, thus, the manufacturer will accept the contract when its profit with the contract exceeds its initial profit, i.e., Δ E π M 0 . In addition, as the retailer will accept the contracts if its CVaR value decreases, we also assume Δ C V a R R = C V a R R ° C V a R R to represent the opposite difference caused by the contracts. Thus, the retailer would accept the contracts only when Δ C V a R R 0 . Then the pareto zone can be found when both Δ E π M and Δ C V a R R are nonnegative, i.e., the contract can benefit both entities and thus coordinate the supply chain. We use the example with c = 1 , p 1 = p 2 = 3 , u = 0.5 , θ 1 = θ 2 = 0.5 , s 1 = s 2 = 0 and we consider the uniform distribution with X ¯ = 100 .
Figure 2 shows profits of the manufacturer and CVaR values of the retailer in different contracts. Specially, Figure 2b illustrates three contracts in Theorem 1 that have identical impact on the changes of profit and CVaR value. Here, k denotes the contract parameter in the retailer’s profit-sharing contract and revenue-sharing contract, we also have p b = k ( p 1 s 1 ) denotes the buy-back price in the buy-back contract. Although the contracts can maximize the supply chain’s total profit, Figure 2a shows that the manufacturer revenue-sharing contract cannot increase the utilities of the manufacturer and the retailer simultaneously.
Previous research, assuming the producing cost is zero [24] or the constraint that the wholesale price is larger than the production cost [16], argues that traditional contracts cannot coordinate the dual-channel supply chain within their assumptions. However, this is not necessarily the case when we release the constraints on the wholesale price. Our result is inconsistence with previous research and shows that traditional contracts can still play their roles as coordinating the supply chain in Figure 2b. The condition that the wholesale price is lower than the production cost illustrates a negative profit in the manufacturer’s retail channel, however, this is not unacceptable because the extra profit from the direct channel can mitigate the loss and balance the manufacturer’s total profit in two channels. Actually, our finding is consistent with business practice in the real world. Single contracts are still in common practice due to their simplification and ease of process [22], for example, Apple is still holding a revenue-sharing agreement with AT&T’s Cingular Wireless, the second largest provider of mobile telephone services, although Apple operates direct and indirect channels together.

4. A Risk-Sharing Contract

We have discussed some traditional contracts in Section 3. Although the revenue-sharing and buy-back contracts can coordinate the dual-channel supply chain with a risk-averse retailer, they have some constraints on the retailer’s risk-averse degree. A retailer who is quite risk-averse will not accept such contracts and the contracts may fail to coordinate the system. In this section, we introduce a risk-sharing contract adoptable with any risk-averse degree to coordinate the supply chain in this case.

4.1. Design of the Risk-Sharing Contracts

According to Cachon [22], single coordinating contracts are not equally costly to different channel members. Our former discussion has also shown that benefits for different channel members vary from changing contract parameters even in the same contract. Therefore, we develop a risk-sharing contract as a combination of a wholesale-price contract, a revenue-sharing contract and a buy-back contract to address the coordination of the risk-averse supply chain. Actually, hybrid contracting schemes have been explored in related literature [2,17]. As an example, Pasternack [43] proposes a contract in which both revenue sharing and a wholesale-price contract exist in a single-retailer newsvendor model.
The constraints in the traditional contracts are derived from the assumption that the wholesale price is positive, therefore, we can begin with an assumption that
w = ( 1 γ ) p 1 + γ c ,
where γ denotes the risk-sharing degree. According to this assumption, the wholesale price will remain at the level between the manufacturer’s cost and the retail price. This is also seen as a guarantee of the manufacturer’s profitability. Then considering the compensation for the retailer, with a guaranteed wholesale price the risk-averse retailer prefers more protection to avoid risks. Thus, we add a buy-back contract and a profit-sharing contract in this risk-sharing contract. The downstream protection to the retailer will increase its order quantity to reach the centralized optimal order quantity, which may increase the risk-neutral manufacturer’s profit. This shows that in the circumstance of intensified competition, the cooperation among channel members needs changes to remain long-term and sustainable relationships. Also, dynamic sharing contract design can highlight the bond between dyadic members and improve relationship quality, which is crucial for sustainable business. We assume the manufacturer shares γ portion of its direct channel’s profit to retailer and pays for the unsold productions with p b per unit to the retailer. The risk-sharing contract can be expressed as follows:
(1)
the manufacturer promises to repurchase the retailer’s unsold products at price p b ;
(2)
the manufacturer promises to share γ portion of its direct channel’s profit to retailer;
(3)
the wholesale price satisfies w = ( 1 γ ) p 1 + γ c .
Therefore, the retailer’s CVaR value and the manufacturer’s profit functions are:
C V a R R ( Q 1 ) = ( p 1 w ) Q 1 γ ( p 2 c ) Q 2 + u ( p 1 s 1 p b ) 1 β 0 Q 1 + p 1 θ 1 p 2 u F ( x ) d x + γ ( 1 u ) ( p 2 s 2 ) 0 Q 2 + p 2 θ 2 p 1 1 u F ( x ) d x ,
π M ( Q 2 ) = π M ° ( Q 2 )   p b [ Q 1 m i n ( Q 1 , q 1 ) ] γ [ p 2 m i n ( Q 1 ,   q 2 ) Q 2 c ] .
Theorem 3.
A risk-sharing contract can coordinate the supply chain when
p b = [ 1 ( 1 β ) γ ] ( p 1 s 1 ) .
As shown in Figure 3, both the manufacturer and the retailer can be satisfied with different risk-averse degree, the risk-sharing contract can coordinate with efficiency. The range of the risk-sharing degree that can coordinate the system increases in the risk-averse degree. In addition, the slope of the CVaR value is fixed regardless of the risk-averse degree. In traditional contracts mentioned above, however, decision coefficients (e.g., the sharing portion and the buy-back price) exert greater impacts on the retailer’s CVaR value when it is more risk-averse (as shown in Figure 2). In these cases, the retailer tends to have a stronger reaction to the contract. Thus, the risk-sharing contract can adjust the retailer’s responses to the risk-sharing degree and ensure the contract’s reasonable implementation.

4.2. Sensitivity Analysis

To gain further insights on how different parameters influence the profits, we make a comparative statics analysis here. Figure 4 shows the manufacturer’s profit and retailer’s CVaR value before and after coordination with different direct channel prices, market share distributions and product’s substitutability.
In general, a key factor between the traditional channel and the direct channel is the price. We assume the retail price ( p 1 ) is fixed. As shown in Figure 4a,b, without coordination, the relatively higher price of the direct market continually benefits both the manufacturer and the retailer. For the manufacturer, the higher direct price can raise its profits in the direct channel and reduce its reliance on the retail channel. Therefore, the manufacturer’s profits increase greatly. For the retailer, the high direct price may raise products’ substitutability in the retail channel and increase its utility slightly. With the risk-sharing contract, the manufacturer keeping more profits in the direct channel will share more to the retailer, therefore leading to a less margin increment in the manufacturer’s total profit and a larger increment in the retailer’s utility (CVaR value).
Considering the market share of the retail channel ( u ) that impacts the coordination, as would be expected in Figure 4c,d, the market share of the traditional channel impacts profits’ distribution between two channel members without coordination, i.e., the traditional channel’s dominance is beneficial to the retailer and reduces the manufacturer’s profits. In this case, however, the manufacturer tends to make more profits from the retail channel and share less to the retailer in the risk-sharing contract. Thus, the manufacturer’s profit increase more and the retailer’s utility increases less with a higher market share of retail channel. Apart from the intuitive findings, we also find that our risk-sharing contract can mitigate the impact of the change of u on the channel members’ utility, i.e., the manufacturer’s profit and the retailer’s CVaR value change slightly when u varies from 0 to 1.
In addition, the channel substitutability ( θ ) in Figure 4e,f shows that the homogeneity of the traditional and online channels can benefit both channel members. According to the consumers’ initial channel preference, they are divided into two segments that preferring the retail channel or the direct channel. The difference between two channels distinguishes the consumers significantly and less of them would switch to a new channel. If the channel substitutability ( θ ) is large and the difference becomes vague, it is easier for the consumers to purchase from their less preferred channel, thus increasing the market potential for two channels. Figure 4 also illustrates our risk-sharing contract seems more beneficial to the retailer, and not always increase the profit of the manufacturer.

4.3. Risk Sensitivity

In Figure 5 we assume p b = 2.1 and γ = 0.23 to compare the coordination of traditional buy-back contract (retailer’s profit/revenue-sharing contract) and the risk-sharing contract. As shown in Figure 5, the buy-back contract (retailer’s profit/revenue-sharing contract) would decrease the manufacturer’s profit when the retailer’s risk-averse degree is high, and the retailer’s utility increases dramatically in this case. However, under the risk-sharing contract, the manufacturer and the retailer’s utilities increase steadily regardless of the retailer’s risk-averse degree, thus this contract can always coordinate the supply chain with a certain risk-sharing degree. Then the risk-sharing contract can satisfy the retailers with different risk-averse degrees. This is an improvement in the contract and coordination. Therefore, this contract is suitable for the retailer whose attitude toward the risk is changing continuously. Figure 5 reveals the flexibility of coordination contracts, and apparently the buy-back contract cannot ensure the steady profits distribution between two channel members, while a fixed risk-sharing degree can contribute to both channel members even though the risk attitude of the retailer is changing.

4.4. Extension

Although channel members cannot determine the selling price in some cases, there also exists the market where the products are not highly substitutable and selling companies can deliver extra value, such as value-adding service, superior quality and unique design, to consumers, then channel members are powerful enough to consider pricing as their decision variables. To gain further insights on how the risk-sharing contract performs under different power structures, we analyze the case when the channel members can determine both order quantities and selling prices as decision variables.
One scenario is that the manufacturer can decide the selling price in the direct channel, then the selling prices in two channels may be distinct. This may happen when the manufacturer is a multinational corporation and doesn’t have many local resources as the local retailer. Thus, the marketing and entry costs are high for the direct channel, and the delivery time is also a factor that impacts consumers’ channel preference. The identical pricing strategy may be not appropriate for the manufacturer; as an example, Thermos sells at a higher price level in its online store than Sainsbury’s in the UK.
Another scenario can happen when the selling prices in different channels are identical. This is a common strategy as many companies adopt the click-and-collect service to build seamless buying experience for consumers and consumers can collect price information online and then buy in brick and mortar stores. Considering the case when the manufacturer is more powerful and the selling price is the manufacturer’s decision variable, the optimal wholesale price then becomes negative based on backward induction and the manufacturer cannot gain profits. Actually, in this case, the manufacturer would skip intermediaries and integrate the selling activity through a manufacturer-owned direct channel [44]. Therefore, we consider the case when the selling price is decided by the retailer and the manufacturer follows this selling price in its direct channel.
Theorem 4.
(1) When channel members adopt identical pricing strategy in which the retailer determines the selling price, the risk-sharing contract can still coordinate the supply chain in this case. (2) When channel members adopt inconsistent pricing strategy, the risk-sharing contract can coordinate the supply chain when the retailer is risk-neutral.
Theorem 4 (1) verifies the coordinating results of the risk-sharing contract when the retailer is more powerful to control selling price while the manufacturer is not. Theorem 4 (2) reveals that the retailer would still accept the contract if it is risk-neutral. However, the result is unknown for a risk-averse retailer whose upstream manufacturer decides to adopt an inconsistent pricing strategy in the manufacturer-owned channel. One of the reasons for these phenomena is that the uncertainty increases for the retailer who cannot forecast the manufacturer’s online marketing strategies. The manufacturer’s value-adding activities can increase the product differentiation in distinct channels, while low-price strategy may weaken the retailer’s competitiveness and limit its development. The retailer is more likely to become hesitant to advance the coordinating process especially in a risk-averse situation. Therefore, the risk-sharing contract is built on the appropriate communication on product marketing design between channel members.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we studied a dual-channel supply chain in which the manufacturer uses both vertical integration online and an offline intermediary. Demand is dependent on selling prices, degree of channel substitutability as well as the market segmentation. We considered a risk-neutral manufacturer and a risk-averse retailer whose risk attitude is measured with CVaR approach. We first studied common contracts widely used in single-channel supply chains, including revenue-sharing contracts and a buy-back contract. Although these contracts could coordinate the supply chain, there are still limitations on the retailer’s risk-averse degree. We then developed a risk-sharing contract which is a hybrid with multiple contracts: the wholesale-price contract can mitigate the side effect of double marginalization; the revenue-sharing contract and buy-back contract with different contract parameters neutralize distribution of profits to avoid the extreme unbalance. Sensitive analysis showed that the risk-sharing contract can perform steadily when the market circumstance varies. We also explored the risk-sharing contract when the channel members are more powerful and considered different pricing strategies as decision variables.
Our study has several managerial insights. First, traditional contracts are not necessarily inefficient in dual-channel supply chains; they can still coordinate the supply chain under low risk exposure, which is ignored by other literature. Inconsistence with previous research, our results prove the coordinating function of these contracts in a low risk-averse situation. This seems to corroborate the business model of Apple and AT&T's Cingular Wireless. Given the conflict between practice and previous literature, it is fair to raise an interesting question: is contract change the necessary process encountering the change of channel structure? Our findings have shown that the answer is no. In a low risk exposure circumstance, the retailer’s cooperation behavior is affected but not significantly, and the change may increase extra operational and administrative burden and uncertainties in a stable inter-organizational relationship. Therefore, traditional contracts can still come into play and boost the cooperation outcomes in the supply chain.
Our results have also shown that when the situation changes dramatically, new contracting schemes should be introduced for the coordination purpose. The risk-sharing contract we presented is one of many ways. As we discussed in the risk-sharing contract, contract design among multi-channel companies should consider the distribution of profit in separate channels. Vertical competition raises the problem of double marginalization which restricts the application of single contracts in practice. Although channel members’ total profits may reach the peak under some coordinating schemes, they may not accept them because of the visible loss in a single channel. The multiple channels operated by a focal company are always treated as “swim lanes” and seek for the profitability in each channel. Therefore, contracts that can bring about nonnegative profits in single channels are more likely to be considered in practice. When the contractual vertical marketing relationship is built between upstream and downstream channel members, the consideration of balanced profit distribution among channels cannot be ignored no matter which channel member designs the contract.
Second, relationship building and appropriate information sharing are needed especially for a more powerful manufacturer. The risk-sharing contract developed in this paper enables positive profit margin for channel members and thus coordinates the entire supply chain. This is applicable not only when channel members cannot control selling prices in a competitive market with highly substitutable products, but also when the retailer has the power to decide retail price and the manufacturer chooses to follow. However, this is not always the case when the manufacturer decides their online price separately. The risk-averse retailer may adopt a conservative strategy instead of processing the risk-sharing contract especially when the manufacturer is powerful and can get access to rich resources in the market. Also, the manufacturer tends to unify the vertical supply chain if it can significantly influence the retailer’s selling price. Therefore, unforeseeable competition becomes a poisoning factor to the contractual relationship building. From the retailer’s perspective, our finding shows that the retailer’s bargaining power is vital in this case to pull the relationship back on a proper track, therefore, the retailer should develop its power through actions such as reducing its dependence on a single manufacturer and increasing the value added to the manufacturer through introducing new markets and brand promotion.
Last but not least, sustainable issues explored in this research focus on the sustainable contracting relationship building with other channel members. The risk-sharing contract here can coordinate the supply chain steadily when market factors and risk attitude vary from time to time, which is vital to remain the cooperation. In addition, a fixed risk-sharing degree can coordinate the supply chain under varied risk-averse degrees. We highlight the sustainability through pointing out the relatively stable contracting strategy under a series of uncertainties and challenges. The long-term relationship marketing is the first step forward to the goal of fulfilling “triple bottom line”, as this sustainability need be reached through the network of business and corporation instead of one single company. Further research can explore this question from an in-depth perspective to address the issue of sustainable business in a multi-channel market.

Acknowledgments

The work was supported by the Ministry of Education in China (MOE) Project of Humanities and Social Sciences (Project No. 15YJC630195). This work was also supported by the Science Foundation of China University of Petroleum, Beijing (No. 2462014YJRC036). In addition, this research was supported under the framework of international cooperation program managed by National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-2016K2A9A2A11938449).

Author Contributions

Lijing Zhu proposed the idea. Yumeng Zhang contributed to the preparation of the whole paper and the model development. Xiaohang Ren participated in methodology discussions and Chulung Lee contributed to the numerical analysis.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Proof of Theorem 1.
In the centralized scenario, π = π R + π M = p 1 m i n ( Q 1 ,   q 1 ) + p 2 m i n ( Q 2 ,   q 2 ) + s 1 [ Q 1 m i n ( Q 1 , q 1 ) ] + s 2 [ Q 2 m i n ( Q 2 , q 2 ) ] ( Q 1 + Q 2 ) c . Assume Q 1 = u x 1 p 1 + θ 1 p 2 , Q 2 = ( 1 u ) x 2 p 2 + θ 2 p 1 , then
E π = ( p 1 c ) Q 1 u ( p 1 s 1 ) A x 1 F ( x ) d x + ( p 2 c ) Q 2 ( 1 u ) ( p 2 s 2 ) A x 2 F ( x ) d x .
And E π Q 1 = p 1 c ( p 1 s 1 ) F ( x 1 ) , 2 E π ( Q 1 ) 2 = p 1 s 1 u f ( x 1 ) < 0 ; E π Q 2 = p 2 c ( p 2 s 2 ) F ( x 2 ) , 2 E π ( Q 2 ) 2 = p 2 s 2 1 u f ( x 2 ) < 0 . Thus, E π is concave in Q 1 and Q 2 . Set E π Q 1 = 0 and E π Q 2 = 0 , we have the optimal order quantity:
Q 1 c * = u F 1 ( p 1 c p 1 s 1 ) p 1 + θ 1 p 2 ;   Q 2 c * = ( 1 u ) F 1 ( p 2 c p 2 s 2 ) p 2 + θ 2 p 1 .
In the decentralized scenario, similarly, we have Q 1 D * = u F 1 [ p 1 w * p 1 s 1 ( 1 β 1 ) ] p 1 + θ 1 p 2 , Q 2 D * = ( 1 u ) F 1 ( p 2 c p 2 s 2 ) p 2 + θ 2 p 1 , where w * satisfies E π M ( Q 1 D * , Q 2 D * ) w = 0 .
Proof of Corollary 1.
If the random variable X follows a uniform distribution, i.e., X ~ U [ 0 , X ¯ ] , we have F 1 ( x ) = X ¯ x , thus Q 1 D * = u X ¯ p 1 w p 1 s 1 ( 1 β ) p 1 + θ 1 p 2 and Q 2 D * = ( 1 u ) X ¯ p 2 c p 2 s 2 p 2 + θ 2 p 1 . Here
E π M ( Q 1 D * , Q 2 D * ) = ( w D c ) Q 1 D * + ( p 2 c ) Q 2 D * ( 1 u ) ( p 2 s 2 ) A x 2 D * F ( x ) d x .
Assume E π M ( Q 1 D * , Q 2 D * ) w D = 0 , we have w D * = p 1 + c 2 ( p 1 θ 1 p 2 ) ( p 1 s 1 ) 2 u ( 1 β ) X ¯ .
Proof of Lemma 1.
First, in the contract that the manufacturer shares 1 k portion of total revenue, i.e., ( 1 k ) [ w Q 1 + p 2 min ( Q 2 ,   q 2 ) + s 2 max ( Q 2 q 2 , 0 ) ] to the retailer, then C V a R R ( Q 1 ) = ( p 1 w ) Q 1 + u ( p 1 s 1 ) 1 β A x 1 F ( x ) d x ( 1 k ) w Q 1 ( 1 k ) ( p 2 s 2 ) [ Q 2 ( 1 u ) A x 2 F ( x ) d x ] and π M ( Q 2 , w ) = π M ° ( Q 2 ) ( 1 k ) [ w Q 1 + p 2 m i n ( Q 2 ,   q 2 ) + s 2 max ( Q 2 q 2 , 0 ) ] . We have 2 C V a R R ( Q 1 ) 2 = p 1 s 1 u ( 1 β ) f ( x 1 ) > 0 and 2 π M ( Q 2 ) 2 = k ( p 2 s 2 ) 1 u f ( x 2 ) < 0 , thus C V a R R is convex in Q 1 and π M is concave in Q 2 . Let C V a R R Q 1 = 0 , E π M Q 2 = 0 , we have F ( x 2 ) = p 2 c p 2 s 2 = F ( x 2 * ) and F ( x 1 ) = p 1 k w p 1 s 1 ( 1 β ) . If Q 1 = Q 1 c * , we have w = c β p 1 k ( 1 β ) .
Second, in the contract that the manufacturer shares 1 k portion of whole profit, i.e., ( 1 k ) π M to the retailer. Similarly, we have 2 C V a R R ( Q 1 ) 2 = p 1 s 1 u ( 1 β ) f ( x 1 ) > 0 and 2 π M ( Q 2 ) 2 = k ( p 2 s 2 ) 1 u f ( x 2 ) < 0 , thus C V a R R is convex in Q 1 and π M is concave in Q 2 . Let F ( x 1 ) = F ( x 1 * ) equals, we have p 1 + ( 1 k ) ( w c ) w p 1 s 1 ( 1 β ) = p 1 c p 1 s 1 , so w = 1 ( 1 k ) ( 1 β ) ( 1 β ) k c β p 1 ( 1 β ) k . Since w β = k ( p 1 c ) ( 1 β ) 2 k 2 < 0 means w is decreasing in β , and 0 < β < 1 , we have w ( β ) < w ( 0 ) = c . Thus, the manufacturer has to share its revenue to the retailer and provide a low wholesale price, which means negative profit for the manufacturer. Apparently, it is not acceptable and this contract cannot coordinate the supply chain.
Third, in the contract that the retailer shares k portion of its revenue, i.e., k [ p 1 min ( Q 1 ,   q 1 ) + s 1 max ( Q 1 q 1 , 0 ) ] . The retailer’s CVaR value and the manufacturer’s profit functions are C V a R R ( Q 1 ) = [ ( 1 k ) p 1 w ] Q 1 u ( 1 k ) ( p 1 s 1 ) 1 β A x 1 F ( x ) d x and π M ( Q 2 , w ) = π M ° ( Q 2 ) + k p 1 m i n ( Q 1 , q 1 ) . Similarly, we have C V a R R is convex in Q 1 and π M is concave in Q 2 . F ( x 1 ) = ( 1 k ) p 1 w ( 1 k ) ( p 1 s 1 ) ( 1 β ) and F ( x 2 ) = p 2 c p 2 s 2 = F ( x 2 C * ) . Here F ( x 1 ) =   F ( x 1 C * ) means ( 1 k ) p 1 w ( 1 k ) ( p 1 s 1 ) ( 1 β ) = p 1 c p 1 s 1 , thus, w = ( 1 k ) ( c β p 1 ) 1 β . Since w β 1 = ( 1 k ) ( p 1 c ) ( 1 β ) 2 < 0 , w ( β ) is decreasing in β . Therefore, 0 < β < 1 indicates w ( β ) < w ( 0 ) = ( 1 k ) c < c .
Fourth, in the contract that the retailer shares k portion of its whole profit, i.e., k π R . We have F ( x 1 ) = p 1 w p 1 s 1 ( 1 β ) and thus w = c β p 1 1 β < c . In this case, although the wholesale price is similar to that in the case without coordination, the manufacturer can receive extra profit from the retailer, thus the manufacturer may accept the contract.
Proof of Lemma 2.
The retailer’s CVaR value and the manufacturer’s profit functions are given by
C V a R R ( Q 1 ) = ( p 1 w ) Q 1 + u ( p 1 s 1 p b ) 1 β A x 1 F ( x ) d x ;
π M ( Q 2 , w ) = π M ° ( Q 2 ) p b [ Q 1 m i n ( Q 1 , q 1 ) ] .
Let C V a R R Q 1 = 0 , E π M Q 2 = 0 , we have F ( x 1 ) = p 1 w p 1 s 1 p b ( 1 β ) and F ( x 2 ) = p 2 c p 2 s 2 = F ( x 2 C * ) . If F ( x 1 ) =   F ( x 1 C * ) , we have p b = ( p 1 s 1 ) [ β p 1 + ( 1 β ) w c ] p 1 c .
Proof of Theorem 2.
In the retailer’s profit-sharing contract, the manufacturer’s expected profit after coordination is E π M = ( k p 1 + w c ) Q 1 C u ( p 1 s 1 ) k A x 1 x f ( x ) d x . As w = ( 1 k ) ( c β p 1 ) 1 β , E π M = ( k β ) ( p 1 c ) u ( p 1 s 1 ) k A x 1 x f ( x ) d x . In the retailer’s revenue-sharing contract, the manufacturer’s expected profit after coordination is E π M = ( k p 1 + w c ) Q 1 C u ( p 1 s 1 ) k A x 1 x f ( x ) d x . As w = c β p 1 1 β , E π M = ( k β ) ( p 1 c ) u ( p 1 s 1 ) k A x 1 x f ( x ) d x . In the buy-back contract, the manufacturer’s expected profit after coordination is E π M = ( w c ) Q 1 C u p b A x 1 x f ( x ) d x , assume k =   p b p 1 s 1 = β p 1 + ( 1 β ) w c p 1 c , we have E π M = ( k β ) ( p 1 c ) u ( p 1 s 1 ) k A x 1 x f ( x ) d x . Therefore, when k = p b p 1 s 1 , the retailer’s profit-sharing contract and retailer’s revenue-sharing contract have the same coordination influence as the buy-back contract on the supply chain with either a risk-neutral or risk-averse retailer.
Proof of Corollary 2.
We have proved in the previous proof that the wholesale price is decreasing in β in manufacturer’s revenue-sharing contract, retailer’s profit-sharing contract and retailer’s revenue-sharing contract. In the buy-back contract, as w = p b ( p 1 c ) ( β p 1 c ) ( p 1 s 1 ) ( p 1 s 1 ) ( 1 β ) , w β = ( p 1 c ) ( p 1 s 1 p b ) ( p 1 s 1 ) ( 1 β ) 2 < 0 , thus the wholesale price is decreasing in β .
Proof of Theorem 3.
According to Equations (16) and (17), in the risk-sharing contract, if w = ( 1 γ ) p 1 + γ c , we have
C V a R R ( Q 1 ) = γ ( p 1 c ) Q 1 γ ( p 2 c ) Q 2 + u ( p 1 s 1 p b ) 1 β 0 Q 1 + p 1 θ 1 p 2 u F ( x ) d x + γ ( 1 u ) ( p 2 s 2 ) 0 Q 2 + p 2 θ 2 p 1 1 u F ( x ) d x ;
E π M ( Q 2 ) = ( 1 γ ) ( p 1 c ) Q 1 + ( 1 γ ) ( p 2 c ) Q 2 u p b 0 Q 1 + p 1 θ 1 p 2 u F ( x ) d x ( 1 γ ) ( 1 u ) ( p 2 s 2 ) 0 Q 2 + p 2 θ 2 p 1 1 u F ( x ) d x .
The first-order derivatives are C V a R R Q 1 = 0 and E π M Q 2 = 0 , then we have F ( x 1 ) = p 1 w p 1 s 1 p b ( 1 β ) =   F ( x 1 C * ) and w = ( 1 γ ) p 1 + γ c . Thus, p b = [ 1 ( 1 β ) γ ] ( p 1 s 1 ) .
Proof of Theorem 4.
(1) Recap that we follow the Nash bargaining framework and channel members move simultaneously. When channel members can decide both order quantities and inconsistent selling prices, in the centralized situation, according to zero first-order derivatives, i.e., E π Q 1 = 0 , E π Q 2 = 0 , E π p 1 = 0 and E π p 2 = 0 , optimal order quantities and optimal selling prices satisfy: F ( Q 1 C * + p 1 C * θ 2 p 2 C * u ) = p 1 C * c p 1 C * s 1 , F ( Q 2 C * + p 2 C * θ 2 p 1 C * 1 u ) = p 2 C * c p 2 C * s 2 , Q 1 C * u 0 Q 1 C * + p 1 C * θ 2 p 2 C * u F ( x ) d x ( p 1 C * s 1 ) 0 Q 1 C * + p 1 C * θ 2 p 2 C * u F ( x ) d x ( 1 θ 2 ) ( p 2 C * s 2 ) F ( Q 2 C * + p 2 C * θ 2 p 1 C * 1 u ) = 0 , and Q 2 C * ( 1 u ) 0 Q 2 C * + p 2 C * θ 2 p 1 C * 1 u F ( x ) d x ( p C * s 2 ) 0 Q 2 C * + p 2 C * θ 2 p 1 C * 1 u F ( x ) d x ( 1 θ 1 ) ( p 1 C * s 1 ) F ( Q 1 C * + p 1 C * θ 2 p 2 C * u ) = 0 . Considering the Hessian matrix, the first-order principal minor determinant is ( p 1 C * s 1 ) f ( x 1 C * ) u < 0 ; the second-order principal minor determinant is ( p 1 C * s 1 ) f ( x 1 C * ) u ( p 2 C * s 2 ) f ( x 2 C * ) 1 u > 0 ; the Hessian matrix is negative definite if the third-order and fourth-order principal minor determinants satisfy [ 1 F ( x 1 C * ) ] 2 < m i n ( ( p 1 C * s 1 ) f ( x 1 C * ) u [ 2 F ( x 2 C * ) ] , { ( p 1 C * s 1 ) f ( x 1 C * ) u [ 1 F ( x 1 C * ) ] 1 u ( p 2 C * s 2 ) f ( x 2 C * ) [ 1 F ( x 2 C * ) ( p 2 C * s 2 ) f ( x 2 C * ) 1 u ] } [ 2 + ( θ 2 ) 2 ( p 2 C * s 2 ) f ( x 2 C * ) 1 u F ( x 1 C * ) ] ) , where x 1 C * = Q 1 C * + p 1 C * θ 2 p 2 C * u and x 2 C * = Q 2 C * + p 2 C * θ 2 p 1 C * 1 u .
Under the risk-sharing contract, according to C V a R R Q 1 = 0 , E π M Q 2 = 0 , C V a R R p 1 = 0 and E π M p 2 = 0 , the first three equations can be reached, however, the last one becomes Q 2 C * ( 1 u ) 0 Q 2 * + p 2 * θ 2 p 1 * 1 u F ( x ) d x ( p 2 * s 2 ) 0 Q 2 * + p 2 * θ 2 p 1 * 1 u F ( x ) d x 1 ( 1 β ) γ ( 1 β ) ( 1 γ ) ( 1 θ 1 ) ( p 1 * s 1 ) F ( Q 1 * + p 1 * θ 2 p 2 * u ) = 0 . When β = 0 , we have 1 ( 1 β ) γ ( 1 β ) ( 1 γ ) = 1 , then the equation equals that in the centralized situation.
When β = 0 , we have E π R = C V a R R , thus, with the risk-sharing contract, we have E π R = C V a R R = γ E π and E π M = ( 1 γ ) E π u β ( p 1 s 1 ) 1 β 0 Q 1 + p 1 θ 1 p 2 u F ( x ) d x = ( 1 γ ) E π . Here the profit can be distributed between two channel members w.r.t parameter γ , thus, there always exist a γ to improve both the manufacturer and the retailer’s profits.
(2) When channel members can decide both order quantities and identical selling price ( p 1 = p 2 = p ), the demand functions are q 1 = u X p 1 + θ 1 p 2 = u X ( 1 θ 1 ) p and q 2 = ( 1 u ) X ( 1 θ 2 ) p . Therefore, the total profit in the supply chain is E π ( Q 2 , Q 2 , p ) = ( p c ) Q 1 + ( p c ) Q 2 u ( p s 1 ) 0 Q 1 + ( 1 θ 1 ) p u F ( x ) d x ( 1 u ) ( p s 2 ) 0 Q 2 + ( 1 θ 2 ) p 1 u F ( x ) d x . In the centralized situation, according to first-order derivatives, i.e., E π Q 1 = 0 , E π Q 2 = 0 and E π p = 0 , optimal order quantities and optimal selling price satisfy: F ( Q 1 C * + ( 1 θ 1 ) p C * u ) = p C * c p C * s 1 , F ( Q 2 C * + ( 1 θ 2 ) p C * 1 u ) = p C * c p C * s 2 , Q 1 C * + Q 2 C * u 0 Q 1 C * + ( 1 θ 1 ) p C * u F ( x ) d x ( 1 θ 1 ) ( p C * s 1 ) F ( Q 1 C * + ( 1 θ 1 ) p C * u ) ( 1 u ) 0 Q 2 C * + ( 1 θ 2 ) p C * 1 u F ( x ) d x ( 1 θ 2 ) ( p C * s 2 ) F ( Q 2 C * + ( 1 θ 2 ) p C * 1 u ) = 0 . The Hessian matrix is
[ Y 1 0 1 F ( x 1 C * ) θ 1 ' Y 1 0 Y 2 1 F ( x 2 C * ) θ 2 ' Y 2 1 F ( x 1 C * ) θ 1 ' Y 1 1 F ( x 2 C * ) θ 2 ' Y 2 2 θ 1 ' F ( x 1 C * ) ( θ 1 ' ) 2 Y 1 2 θ 2 ' F ( x 2 C * ) ( θ 2 ' ) 2 Y 2 ]
where x 1 C * = Q 1 C * + ( 1 θ 1 ) p C * u , x 2 C * = Q 2 C * + ( 1 θ 2 ) p C * 1 u , Y 1 = ( p C * s 1 ) f ( x 1 C * ) u , Y 2 = ( p C * s 2 ) f ( x 2 C * ) 1 u , θ 1 = 1 θ 1 and θ 2 = 1 θ 2 . The first-order principal minor determinant is ( p C * s 1 ) f ( x 1 C * ) u < 0 ; the second-order principal minor determinant is Y 1 Y 2 > 0 ; the Hessian matrix is negative definite if the third-order principal minor determinant satisfies [ 1 F ( x 1 C * ) ] 2 Y 1 + [ 1 F ( x 2 C * ) ] 2 Y 2 ( θ 1 + θ 2 ) Y 1 Y 2 < 0 .
Under the risk-sharing contract, according to zero first-order derivatives, i.e., C V a R R Q 1 = 0 , E π M Q 2 = 0 and C V a R R p = 0 , we have optimal order quantities and optimal selling price F ( Q 1 * + ( 1 θ 1 ) p * u ) = p * c p * s 1 , F ( Q 2 * + ( 1 θ 2 ) p * 1 u ) = p * c p * s 2 ; Q 1 * + Q 2 * u 0 Q 1 * + ( 1 θ 1 ) p * u F ( x ) d x ( 1 θ 1 ) ( p * s 1 ) F ( Q 1 * + ( 1 θ 1 ) p * u ) ( 1 u ) 0 Q 2 * + ( 1 θ 2 ) p * 1 u F ( x ) d x ( 1 θ 2 ) ( p * s 2 ) F ( Q 2 * + ( 1 θ 2 ) p * 1 u ) = 0 . The optimal quantities and prices are reached.

References

  1. Geyskens, I.; Gielens, K.; Dekimpe, M.G. The market valuation of internet channel additions. J. Mark. 2002, 66, 102–119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Xu, G.; Dan, B.; Zhang, X.; Liu, C. Coordinating a dual-channel supply chain with risk-averse under a two-way revenue sharing contract. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2014, 147, 171–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Tsay, A.A.; Agrawal, N. Channel conflict and coordination in the e-commerce age. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2004, 13, 93–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Shipley, D.; Egan, C.; Edgett, S. Meeting source selection criteria: Direct versus distributor channels. Ind. Mark. Manag. 1991, 20, 297–303. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Cheng, J.M.; Tsao, S.; Tsai, W.; Tu, H.H. Will eChannel additions increase the financial performance of the firm?—The evidence from Taiwan. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2007, 36, 50–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Choi, S.C. Expanding to direct channel: Market coverages as entry barrier. J. Int. Mark. 2003, 17, 25–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Chiang, W.; Chhajed, D.; Hess, J.D. Direct marketing, indirect profits: A strategic analysis of dual-channel supply-chain design. Manag. Sci. 2003, 49, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Cattani, K.; Gilland, W.; Heese, H.S.; Swaminathan, J. Boiling frogs: Pricing strategies for a manufacturer adding a direct channel that competes with the traditional channel. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2006, 15, 40. [Google Scholar]
  9. Huang, W.; Swaminathan, J. Introduction of a second channel: Implications for pricing and profits. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2009, 194, 258–279. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Matsui, K. Asymmetric product distribution between symmetric manufacturers using dual-channel supply chains. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 248, 646–657. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Yao, D.; Yue, X.; Mukhopadhyay, S.; Wang, Z. Strategic inventory deployment for retail and e-tail stores. Omega 2009, 37, 646–658. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Chiang, W.K. Product availability in competitive and cooperative dual-channel distribution with stock-out based substitution. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2010, 200, 111–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Dumrongsiri, A.; Fan, M.; Jain, A.; Moinzadeh, K. A supply chain model with direct and retail channels. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2008, 187, 691–718. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Huang, S.; Yang, C.; Zhang, X. Pricing and production decisions in dual-channel supply chains with demand disruptions. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2012, 62, 70–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Bocken, N.; Short, S.W.; Rana, P.; Evans, S. A literature and practice review to develop sustainable business model archetypes. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 65, 42–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Boyaci, T. Competitive stocking and coordination in a multiple-channel distribution system. IIE Trans. 2005, 37, 407–427. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Chen, J.; Zhang, H.; Sun, Y. Implementing coordination contracts in a manufacturer Stackelberg dual-channel supply chain. Omega 2012, 40, 571–583. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Yan, R. Profit sharing and firm performance in the manufacturer-retailer dual-channel supply chain. Electron. Commer. Res. 2008, 8, 155–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Cai, G.G. Channel selection and coordination in dual-channel supply chains. J. Retail. 2010, 86, 22–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Shang, W.; Yang, L. Contract negotiation and risk preferences in dual-channel supply chain coordination. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2015, 53, 4837–4856. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Li, B.; Hou, P.; Chen, P.; Li, Q. Pricing strategy and coordination in a dual channel supply chain with a risk-averse retailer. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2016, 178, 154–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Cachon, G.P. Supply chain coordination with contracts. Handbooks Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2003, 11, 227–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Agrawal, V.; Seshadri, S. Impact of uncertainty and risk aversion on price and order quantity in the newsvendor problem. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2000, 2, 410–423. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Caliskan-Demirag, O.; Chen, Y.F.; Li, J. Customer and retailer rebates under risk aversion. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 133, 736–750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Chen, Y.; Xu, M.; Zhang, Z.G. Technical note-a risk-averse newsvendor model under the CVaR criterion. Oper. Res. 2009, 57, 1040–1044. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Eeckhoudt, L.; Gollier, C.; Schlesinger, H. The risk-averse (and prudent) newsboy. Manag. Sci. 1995, 41, 786–794. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Zhao, Y.; Wang, S.; Cheng, T.C.E.; Yang, X.; Huang, Z. Coordination of supply chains by option contracts: A cooperative game theory approach. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2010, 207, 668–675. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Li, B.; Chen, P.; Li, Q.; Wang, W. Dual-channel supply chain pricing decisions with a risk-averse retailer. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2014, 52, 7132–7147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Zhu, L.; Lee, C. Risk analysis of a two-level supply chain subject to misplaced inventory. Appl. Sci. 2017, 7, 676. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Sawik, T. On the risk-averse optimization of service level in a supply chain under disruption risks. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2016, 54, 93–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Wu, M.; Zhu, S.X.; Teunter, R.H. A risk-averse competitive newsvendor problem under the CVaR criterion. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2014, 156, 13–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Rockafellar, R.T.; Uryasev, S. Optimization of conditional value-at-risk. J. Risk 2000, 2, 21–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Kumar, N.; Ruan, R. On manufacturers complementing the traditional retail channel with a direct online channel. Quant. Mark. Econ. 2006, 4, 289–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Berman, B.; Thelen, S. A guide to developing and managing a well-integrated multi-channel retail strategy. Int. J. Retail. Distrib. Manag. 2004, 32, 147–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Noble, S.M.; Griffith, D.A.; Weinberger, M.G. Consumer derived utilitarian value and channel utilization in a multi-channel retail context. J. Bus. Res. 2005, 58, 1643–1651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Verhoef, P.C.; Neslin, S.A.; Vroomen, B. Multichannel customer management: Understanding the research-shopper phenomenon. Int. J. Res. Mark. 2007, 24, 129–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Wang, W.; Li, G.; Cheng, T.C.E. Channel selection in a supply chain with a multi-channel retailer: The role of channel operating costs. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2016, 173, 54–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Mukhopadhyay, S.K.; Yao, D.Q.; Yue, X. Information sharing of value-adding retailer in a mixed channel hi-tech supply chain. J. Bus. Res. 2008, 61, 950–958. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Gan, X.; Sethi, S.P.; Yan, H. Channel coordination with a risk-neutral supplier and a downside-risk-averse retailer. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2005, 14, 80–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Agrawal, V.; Seshadri, S. Risk intermediation in supply chains. IIE Trans. 2000, 32, 819–831. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Gotoh, J.; Takano, Y. Newsvendor solutions via conditional value-at-risk minimization. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2007, 179, 80–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Cachon, G.P.; Lariviere, M.A. Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: Strengths and limitations. Manag. Sci. 2005, 51, 30–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Pasternack, B.A. Using revenue sharing to achieve channel coordination for a newsboy type inventory model. In Supply Chain Management: Models, Applications, and Research Directions; Kluwer Academic Publishers: London, UK, 2002; pp. 117–136. ISBN 1-4020-0487-7. [Google Scholar]
  44. Cai, G.; Zhang, Z.G.; Zhang, M. Game theoretical perspectives on dual-channel supply chain competition with price discounts and pricing schemes. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2009, 117, 80–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Dual-Channel Framework.
Figure 1. Dual-Channel Framework.
Sustainability 09 02148 g001
Figure 2. Changes of profit and Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) value with contracts under different contract parameters (i.e., k , p b and λ ) when β = 0.1 ,   0.2 ,   0.3 : (a) Manufacturer’s revenue-sharing contract; (b) Retailer’s profit-sharing contract, retailer’s revenue-sharing contract and buy-back contract.
Figure 2. Changes of profit and Conditional Value-at-Risk (CVaR) value with contracts under different contract parameters (i.e., k , p b and λ ) when β = 0.1 ,   0.2 ,   0.3 : (a) Manufacturer’s revenue-sharing contract; (b) Retailer’s profit-sharing contract, retailer’s revenue-sharing contract and buy-back contract.
Sustainability 09 02148 g002
Figure 3. Supply chain coordination with the risk-sharing contract (Variation of the Profit and CVaR Value for Different Value of γ).
Figure 3. Supply chain coordination with the risk-sharing contract (Variation of the Profit and CVaR Value for Different Value of γ).
Sustainability 09 02148 g003
Figure 4. The change of manufacturer’s profit and the retailer’s CVaR value in the risk-sharing contract (variation of the profits for different value of p 2 , u and θ ): (a) Manufacturer’s profits w.r.t. p 2 ; (b) Retailer’s CVaR value w.r.t. p 2 ; (c) Manufacturer’s profits w.r.t. u ; (d) Retailer’s CVaR value w.r.t. u ; (e) Manufacturer’s profits w.r.t. θ ; (f) Retailer’s CVaR value w.r.t.
Figure 4. The change of manufacturer’s profit and the retailer’s CVaR value in the risk-sharing contract (variation of the profits for different value of p 2 , u and θ ): (a) Manufacturer’s profits w.r.t. p 2 ; (b) Retailer’s CVaR value w.r.t. p 2 ; (c) Manufacturer’s profits w.r.t. u ; (d) Retailer’s CVaR value w.r.t. u ; (e) Manufacturer’s profits w.r.t. θ ; (f) Retailer’s CVaR value w.r.t.
Sustainability 09 02148 g004
Figure 5. The change of manufacturer’s profit and the retailer’s CVaR value in different contracts (variation for different value of β ): (a) The change of manufacturer’s profits w.r.t. β ; (b) The change of retailer’s CVaR value w.r.t. β .
Figure 5. The change of manufacturer’s profit and the retailer’s CVaR value in different contracts (variation for different value of β ): (a) The change of manufacturer’s profits w.r.t. β ; (b) The change of retailer’s CVaR value w.r.t. β .
Sustainability 09 02148 g005
Table 1. Optimal Order Quantity in Centralized System and Decentralized System.
Table 1. Optimal Order Quantity in Centralized System and Decentralized System.
CentralizedDecentralized
Q 1 Q 1 C * = u F 1 ( p 1 c p 1 s 1 ) p 1 + θ 1 p 2 Q 1 D *   = u F 1 [ p 1 w p 1 s 1 ( 1 β ) ] p 1 + θ 1 p 2
Q 2 Q 2 C * = ( 1 u ) F 1 ( p 2 c p 2 s 2 ) p 2 + θ 2 p 1 Q 2 D * = ( 1 u ) F 1 ( p 2 c p 2 s 2 ) p 2 + θ 2 p 1

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhu, L.; Ren, X.; Lee, C.; Zhang, Y. Coordination Contracts in a Dual-Channel Supply Chain with a Risk-Averse Retailer. Sustainability 2017, 9, 2148. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9112148

AMA Style

Zhu L, Ren X, Lee C, Zhang Y. Coordination Contracts in a Dual-Channel Supply Chain with a Risk-Averse Retailer. Sustainability. 2017; 9(11):2148. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9112148

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhu, Lijing, Xiaohang Ren, Chulung Lee, and Yumeng Zhang. 2017. "Coordination Contracts in a Dual-Channel Supply Chain with a Risk-Averse Retailer" Sustainability 9, no. 11: 2148. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9112148

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop