Next Article in Journal
Indigenous Kinabatangan Perspectives on Climate Change Impacts and Adaptations: Factors Influencing Their Support and Participation
Previous Article in Journal
General Defense Response under Biotic Stress and Its Genetics at Pepper (Capsicum annuum L.)
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Imbalance of Embodied CO2 in China’s Imports, Exports and Its Causes

College of Northeast Asian Studies, Jilin University, No. 2699 Qianjin Street, Changchun 130012, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2022, 14(11), 6460; https://doi.org/10.3390/su14116460
Submission received: 28 March 2022 / Revised: 14 May 2022 / Accepted: 20 May 2022 / Published: 25 May 2022
(This article belongs to the Topic Climate Change and Environmental Sustainability)

Abstract

:
Constraining the embodied CO2 from international trade is a crucial part of China’s efforts to achieve emission peak and carbon neutrality. By referring to the WIOD, this article applies the Global Multi-Regional Input-Output (GMRIO) Model and the Value-added Trade Accounting Method to calculate the amount of embodied CO2 in China’s international trade from 2000 to 2014. Results indicate that China’s embodied CO2 in imports and exports is imbalanced in three dimensions: product, region, and industry. One direct cause of this phenomenon is China’s higher carbon emission factors compared to its trading partner. However, the real cause is the global relocation of energy-intensive industries, which leads China to undertake the production of high-carbon industries. To achieve the 3060 Dual Carbon Goal and high-quality economic development, China needs comprehensive and systematic reforms in its economic structure.

1. Introduction

Since the beginning of the 1980s, a new international demarcation of the global value chains (GVCs) has gradually taken place, and countries at different degrees of economic development have been integrated into the global production network. The production processes have been characterized by fragmentation, with countries participating in different production segments according to their natural advantages. During the reform and opening-up period, China has actively participated in it. With the advantages of labor and resources, China has become the world factory for manufacturing and processing trade. After joining WTO in 2001, China’s exports have been driven rapidly by the global market and China became the world’s largest exporter in 2009. However, China did not have many advantages in terms of industrial knowledge and leading technology in the GVCs; hence, the exported products were mainly in the labor-intensive and Capital-intensive industries [1]. Accordingly, this has led to certain drawbacks in China’s trade model. First, relying on the ever-increasing scale of exportation could boost China’s economic growth in the short term; however, this would not drive the quality of the economy concurrently. Moreover, the long-term exportation of low value-added products would also lead to environmental damages and an excessive consumption of resources [2].
With global warming and frequent extreme weather events, there has also been greater concerns over the severity of China’s climate change issues. According to the International Energy Agency (IEA) accessed on 6 May 2022 (IEA: https://www.iea.org/data-and-statistics, accessed on 1 May 2020), China’s CO2 emissions totaled 5449.5 Mt in 2005, surpassing the United States; hence China has become the world’s top carbon emitter, accounting for 20.12% of the world’s total emissions. In 2019, China’s total carbon emissions rose to 9919.1 Mt, equivalent to 29.50% of the world’s total emissions. The continuous expansion of CO2 emissions has posed challenges to China, facing public pressures from the international society for emission reduction as well as balancing domestic economic development and environmental protection. To mitigate it, China has proposed emission peak and carbon neutrality goals (3060 Dual Carbon Goal) in 2020 (The 3060 dual carbon goal is that China achieve carbon peaking by 2030 and carbon neutrality by 2060. Source: Central People’s Government of the People’s Republic of China accessed on 6 May 2022, “China will adopt stronger policies and measures to peak CO2 emissions by 2030 and strive to achieve carbon neutrality by 2060”, http://www.gov.cn/gongbao/content/2020/content_5549875.htm, accessed on 1 May 2020). Achieving reduction in carbon emission requires a systematic approach and restraining the embodied CO2 from international trade is crucial. Excessive embodied CO2 emission in exports and its substantial imbalance with imports have been a realistic issue. In 2014, China’s embodied CO2 in exports were as high as 2035.22 Mt, accounting for 21.95% of China’s total CO2 emissions. In comparison, embodied CO2 in imports were only 652.05 Mt, equivalent to only 7.03%. Therefore, it is necessary to research the imbalance of embodied CO2 in China’s imports, exports and the causes.

2. Literature Review

CO2 emissions are caused by production and consumption activities such as the combustion of fossil fuels. Although international trade does not directly generate CO2 except for transportation, there is still a strong correlation between international trade and carbon emissions in real life [3]. The rationale is that international trade separates the production and consumption systems of products, making carbon emissions transferable and reallocated across borders. International trade leads to the international demarcations based on comparative advantages, which in turn change the distribution of production activities on a global scale. Thus, it indirectly changes the geographical distribution of CO2, shifting them from countries with comparative advantages in clean industries to those with comparative advantages in high pollution industries.
This phenomenon has long received academic attention. Baumol and Oates (1988) [4] proposed the pollution haven hypothesis (PHH), which believes that asymmetric environmental policies leads to the international migration of industries. To reduce the costs of environmental management, countries with strict environmental regulations tend to move high-carbon industries to those regions with less strict environmental regulations and then import back the desired goods. This often makes the countries and regions with less strict environmental regulations a haven of pollution. In general, developed countries are highly concerned about the environment and they will tighten the pollution regulations. In contrast, developing countries are more willing to ease environmental regulations to boost their economies, leading them to produce products in pollution-extensive industries. Data supporting this hypothesis have been provided by Robinson (1988) [5], who examined data over the period of 1973–1982 and found that the United States tended to import rather than produce pollution-intensive products. Lee and Roland-Holst (1993) [6] used a dual-country CGE model for trade between Japan and Indonesia and it appears that their bilateral trade effects a net transfer of environmental costs from the former to the latter. Copeland and Taylor (1994) [7,8] constructed a North-South model that demonstrated that trade mitigates environmental pollutions in the North (developed countries) and increases pollution levels in the South (developing countries). Mani and Wheeler (1998) [9] showed that pollution-intensive outputs as a percentage of total manufacturing had fallen consistently in the OECD countries and they had risen steadily in the developing world.
In addition to the theoretical and data support above, there are also literatures that use the Input-Output Analysis (IOA) approach to study the relationship between international trade and environment [10,11]. This method is more intuitive and it directly reveals the impacts of international trade on environment by calculating embodied CO2. With the improvement of technical tools and database, the method has changed from the initial Single-Region Input-Output (SRIO model) (Machado, 2001 [12]; Chen et al., 2008 [13]) through the Bilateral Region Input-Output (BRIO model) (Peters 2008 [14]) and the Multi-Region Input-Output (MRIO model) (Wiedmann, 2009 [15]; Ma et al., 2015 [16]), to the Global Multi-Region Input-Output (GMRIO model) (Xie et al., 2016 [17], Yuan et al., 2014 [18]). The I-O approach is still an effective tool for studying environmental economics. However, due to the fragmentation of production, countries around the world are included in the GVCs with intermediate goods being traded across borders often. Therefore, if the traditional trade accounting method is followed, it will result in a double counting of trade volume, which makes the accounting of embodied CO2 biased.
From the research objects and areas of concern, many scholars have paid higher attention to the embodied CO2 between specific countries [19,20]. Yan et al., 2017 [21] and Liu et al., 2020 [22] focused on the China-US trade, Pan et al., 2018 [23] and Jin et al., 2018 [24] studied the embodied CO2 in the trade between China and Japan. Zheng et al., 2018 [25] and Meng et al., 2019 [26] studied the issue of embodied CO2 from China-BRICS and China- “Belt and Road” countries, respectively. In addition, there are also some papers that focus on the embodied CO2 in foreign trade of a certain country [27]. For example, Tolmasquim and Machado, 2003 [28] analyzed the embodied CO2 in Brazil’s international trade in the 1990s and argued that the increase of CO2 emissions in the country was closely related to its specialization in energy-intensive industries. Whan-Sam Chung et al., 2011 [29] analyzed CO2 emissions and the affecting factors in South Korea from 1985 to 2005, and the findings proved that national energy policies such as those pertaining to the diversification of energy sources are effective. Numerous scholars have studied the issue of embodied CO2 in China from a particular perspective. Wang, 2010 [30] accounted for the embodied CO2 of exports in China’s industrial sector from 2003 to 2007, and he concluded that the expansion of exports was the main reason for the increase in the size of embodied CO2. Dai et al., 2015 [31] studied the embodied CO2 of Chinese agriculture from 1990 to 2010, and he used the Kaya constant equation decomposition principle to determine its driving factors. Fei et al., 2020 [32] measured embodied CO2 emissions of Chinese exports from 1995 to 2011 and found that the trade in intermediate goods was the main reason. However, due to the complexity of calculation, literatures about the issue of embodied CO2 across all industries and its imbalance between imports and exports are relatively limited. That is why we have conducted the research.
The marginal contributions of this article are explained below. First, with the inclusion of value-added trade in the GMRIO model, double counting has been removed and the heterogeneity of carbon emissions across countries has been considered. Hence, the calculation accuracy has been improved. Second, this paper focuses on the imbalance of embodied carbon in China’s imports and exports with an innovative approach. The following chapters of this paper is organized as follows: Part III introduces the accounting method of embodied CO2 emissions; Part IV describes the situation of imbalance of China’s embodied CO2 in imports and exports from three dimensions: product, industry and regional; Part V explains the causes of this Phenomenon; Part VI is the conclusion of this article.

3. Research Methodology

The traditional trade accounting method only takes the total amount of trade into consideration, without distinguishing the original country of a certain part of production in the commodity. In other words, if the final exporter is China, all the trade value of this commodity is counted as China’s exports. However, China has a large share of manufacturing and processing trade, importing many intermediate products, processing them into final consumer goods before exporting them worldwide. Accordingly, by using the traditional trade accounting method, the value of China’s export trade is overestimated as is the amount of embodied CO2 emissions, because the value of intermediate goods produced in other countries have not been removed from the equation [33].
Therefore, in order to improve the accuracy of calculation in embodied CO2, improvements in two aspects have been made in this article. First, we have adopted the value-added trade accounting method and decomposed the trade volume into three components: importing country, exporting country, and third-party country according to the place of origins. By doing so, the overestimation of trade volume caused by double counting of intermediate products has been mitigated. Second, the differences in carbon emission factors across countries have been considered (some previous literature assumed that the importing countries have the same carbon emission factors as their own countries). By identifying the source countries of production for each part of trade and correlating to their respective carbon emission factors, the accuracy of calculation has been significantly improved.

3.1. Data Source and Data Processing

The world input-output tables (WIOTs) and the CO2 data in various industries were obtained on 20 April 2022 from WIOD 2016, published by Groningen Growth and Development Centre (world input-output Database: https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/valuechain/wiod/wiod-2016-release, accessed on 27 March 2022) [34]. The reason for the choice is that it contains the annual data and trading trends for major trading countries of China. WIOD has two types of WIOTS, in current year’s prices and in previous year’s prices. We chose the latter because it allows for comparison of the annual data. The data has been processed as follows:
First, referring to the industry classification of Rahman and Zhao, 2013 [35] (Rahman, Zhao, 2013, Export Performance in Europe: What Do We Know from Supply Links? IMF Working Paper.), the 56 sectors were categorized into eight major industries: primary resource industry(P); labor-intensive manufacturing(L-M); capital-intensive manufacturing(C-M); knowledge-intensive manufacturing(K-M); labor-intensive services(L-S); capital-intensive services(C-S); knowledge-intensive services(K-S); and other services industries(O-S). It can also be categorized into three major industries: a primary resource industry, a manufacturing industry and a service industry. L-M, C-M, K-M are manufacturing industries, L-S, C-S, K-S and O-S are service industries. The detailed methodology of industry classification and combination is showed in the Appendix A at the end of article. Second, for the decomposition of data for trade value-addition, we used the codes provided by the Global Value Chain Institute of the University of International Business and Economics (UIBE) accessed on 20 April 2022 (RIGVC UIBE, 2016, UIBE GVC Indicators, http://rigvc.uibe.edu.cn/english/D_E/database_database/index.htm, accessed on 27 March 2022) and it was obtained using R Studio. The calculations involving embodied CO2 were obtained using Matlab2016b according to the equations provided below.

3.2. Construction of the Model

3.2.1. Value-Added Trade Accounting Method

The value-added trade accounting method (WWZ 2015) allows for the decomposition of trade volume ( E s r ) from country s to country r into 16 portions (refer to the original literature for derivation). The specific decomposed portions are as follows:
E s r = ( V s B s s ) T # Y s r + ( V s L s s ) T # ( A s r B r r Y r r ) + ( V s L s s ) T # ( A s r B r t Y t t ) + ( V s L s s ) T # ( A s r B r r Y r t ) + ( V s L s s ) T # ( A s r B r t Y t r ) + ( V s L s s ) T # ( A s r B r r Y r s ) + ( V s L s s ) T # ( A s r B r t Y t s ) + ( V s L s s ) T # ( A s r B r s Y s s ) + ( V s L s s ) T # [ ( A s r B r s ( Y s r + Y s t ) ] + ( V s B s s V s L s s ) T # ( A s r X r ) + ( V r B r s ) T # Y s r + ( V r B r s ) T # ( A s r L r r Y r r ) + ( V r B r s ) T # ( A s r B r r E r ) + ( V t B t s ) T # Y s r + ( V t B t s ) T # ( A s r L r r Y r r ) + ( V t B t s ) T # ( A s r L r r E r )
where # represents the multiplication of the matrix and T represents the transpose of the matrix. L s s , L r r represent the Leontief inverse matrix of countries s and r ;   V s , V r ,   V t represent the vectors of the value-added coefficients of the countries s , r and t ; X r ,   E r * represent the vectors of the total output and the total exports of country r . Each part of the above formula corresponds to T1 to T16.
Table 1 gives the specific meanings of the 16 decomposed components (from T1 to T16) of the gross exports from country s to country r (among them T9, T10, T13 and T16 are purely double-counted components hence they have been excluded).
In addition, we distinguish different product types in Table 1, where T2, T3, T4, T5, T8, T12 and T15 are intermediate products, whereas T1, T6, T7, T11 and T14 are final products. Meanwhile, we also distinguish the actual producing and consuming countries of the products.

3.2.2. GMRIO Model Based on Heterogeneity

  • GMRIO model
x i = j a i j x j + y i
where a i j x j = z i j and z i j is the intermediate product of industry i consumed by industry j .
The matrix can be expressed as X = A X + Y , X and Y are the column vectors of total output and the final demand of each industry. A is the matrix of the direct consumption coefficient.
The calculation yields:
X = ( I A ) 1 Y = L Y
wre L is the Leontief inverse matrix.
If there are G countries (regions), according to the GMRIO model, the output of each country can be expressed as:
[ x 1 x 2 x G ] = [ A 11 A 12 A 1 G A 21 A 22 A 2 G A G 1 A G 2 A G G ] [ x 1 x 2 x G ] + [ y 11 y 12 y 1 G y 21 y 22 y 2 G y G 1 y G 2 y G G ]
that is:
[ x 1 x 2 x G ] = [ L 11 L 12 L 1 G L 21 L 22 L 2 G L G 1 L G 2 L G G ] [ y 11 y 12 y 1 G y 21 y 22 y 2 G y G 1 y G 2 y G G ]
where the subscript G represents the number of countries that have trade with each other. For country s ( s = 1, …, G ), vector x s represents the country’s total outputs, A s s is the coefficient matrix of direct consumption, and vector y s s represents the final products that are being produced and consumed to meet final domestic demands.
2.
Calculation equation of embodied CO2
First, the embodied CO2 concept is introduced into Equation (1), and the output is substituted by CO2 to obtain Equation (2).
C = f ( I A ) 1 Y
where f is the direct CO2 emission factor, which is the directly consumed CO2 emissions divided by the total output of the industry.
Second, the final demand Y of Equation (2) is substituted by EX which yields the equation for the measurement of the embodied CO2 in a country’s exports.
C e x = f ( I A ) 1 E X
where EX is the export trade volume and C e x is the embodied CO2 in exports.
3.
Equation for the embodied CO2 decomposition in the perspective of heterogeneity
Embodied CO2 generated by exporting country:
C e x 1 = f s ( I A ) 1 ( D V A + R D V )
Embodied CO2 generated by importing country:
C e x 2 = f r ( I A ) 1 M V A
Embodied CO2 generated by third country:
C e x 3 = f t ( I A ) 1 O V A
where f s , f r , f t are the diagonal matrices of the direct CO2 factors of the exporting country, importing country, and third country, respectively.
Similarly, the equation for the embodied CO2 of imports can be obtained by replacing the export value with the import value to correspond to the respective CO2 emission factors.

4. The Imbalance of China’s Embodied CO2 in Imports and Exports

4.1. Imbalance in Product Amount and Product Type

First, during the period this study focuses on, China’s total embodied CO2 emissions in exports were much higher than that of imports and the imbalance has clearly indicated that China is clearly in the position of carbon transfer-in (Figure 1). From 2001 to 2007, the gap was widening. In 2001, the embodied CO2 emissions in exports was higher than that in imports by 432.53 Mt, and it reached a peak of 1590.93 Mt in 2007, which means that the amount of transferred carbon emission into China was from 432.53 Mt to 1590.93 Mt. From 2008 to 2010, the gap showed a V-shaped change of falling and then rising. This is mainly due to the financial crisis in 2008; the decline in exports led to the decline in embodied CO2, but after 2009, it gradually recovered. From 2010 to 2014, the difference tended to be stable, basically between 1300 and 1400 Mt.
Second, the types of imported and exported products with embodied CO2 are also imbalanced (Figure 2). The main source of embodied carbon in imports is from trade of intermediate goods, which accounts for more than 70%. However, more than 50% of the embodied carbon in exports trade is from final goods, although the trend is weakening slightly. In 2001, 53.1% of the embodied carbon in exports was generated from final goods. In 2014, the proportion dropped to 49.6%. In general, the difference of embodied carbon in various product types is consistent with China’s long-established manufacturing and processing trade pattern of importing intermediate goods and exporting final goods. It has indicated that the trade pattern has a great impact on carbon emissions.

4.2. Imbalance in Regions

China’s embodied CO2 in imports and exports have been in great imbalance with the major regions of the world and there have been significant differences among these regions. There have been no substantial changes in the characteristics during the study interval; hence 2010 has been chosen as an example for illustration (Figure 3). According to the geographical and economic development characteristics, the 43 countries and regions in the WIOD excluding China have been divided into six major regions (Euro Zone; Non-Euro Zone; BRIIAT; East Asia; NAFTA and ROW).
The embodied CO2 in China’s exports to all these regions are much higher compared with that in imports. Among them, NAFTA, Euro Zone and Non-Euro Zone are the three regions with the most substantial imbalanced. Reflected in data, embodied CO2 emissions from China’s exports to these regions are 11.23 times, 11.00 times and 6.18 times of that from imports, respectively. Moreover, the embodied CO2 in exports to these regions were dominated by final products. From the specific countries in Table 2 below, the US is the country with the largest imbalance of NAFTA, accounting for 81.03% of the total imbalance, mainly because China exports a large amount of embodied CO2 in final goods to the US, reaching 214.58 Mt. Germany, France, Italy and the Netherlands are the main imbalanced countries in the Euro Zone, and China’s exports to them are also quite large; the difference of product type is not very obvious, but in general the final products are higher than the intermediate goods. The UK is the country with the largest imbalance in the Non-Euro Zone, accounting for 51.03% of the region. A distinctive feature is that China imports very little from the UK, only 2.79 Mt, and exports 45.26 Mt (mainly final goods).
East Asia and BRIIAT belong to the zone with an intermediate imbalance, where the embodied CO2 in exports is 2.73 times and 2.13 times than that in imports, respectively. Moreover, it is observed that the CO2 in imports of the two regions is mainly from intermediate products. Among them, there is little difference in BRIIAT countries, with about 90% of the imported embodied CO2 from intermediate goods in the four countries (Australia, Brazil, India, and Russia). Japan is the country with the largest imbalance in East Asia, accounting for 88.01% of the total imbalance CO2. A relatively large share of China’s imports of embodied CO2 to Japan comes from intermediate goods, about twice as much as final goods. Besides, for embodied CO2 in exports, immediate goods carry less weight compared with final goods.
To summarize, the main source of China’s embodied CO2 in imports is intermediate products, basically from East Asia and BRIIAT, whereas the main source of embodied CO2 in exports is final goods, mainly from NAFTA and Euro Zone, followed by East Asia and BRIIAT, with the least inflow to Non-Euro Zone. Therefore, it is further clear that China, as the world factory, operates a typical triangular trade, importing intermediate goods from East Asia and emerging economies to meet the consumption demand of final goods in developed economies in Europe and the US.

4.3. Imbalance in Industries

As shown in Figure 4, in 2005, all industries had higher exported embodied CO2 than that from importation, dominated by the products of capital-intensive manufacturing industry and capital-intensive service industry. The total imbalance from all industries was 1203.49 Mt and the primary resources industry, manufacturing industry, and service industry accounted for 2.45%, 59.87% and 37.68%, respectively. The primary resources industry is the industry with the least imbalance with exports of embodied CO2 only 29.46 Mt higher than that from importation. This is mainly because of China’s dependence on imports for direct extraction of raw materials, fuels, etc. Manufacturing industries are with the most substantial imbalance. Further breakdown shows labor-intensive manufacturing, capital-intensive manufacturing, and knowledge-intensive manufacturing industry are out of balance by 69.89 Mt, 494.54 Mt and 156.14 Mt, respectively. Service industries are out of balance by a total of 453.46 Mt, mainly generated by the imbalance of capital-intensive service (439.36 Mt), with very few in labor-intensive service, knowledge-intensive service, and other services.
In 2014, the situation remained that all industries had higher exported embodied CO2 than that from importation, with a difference of 1383.17 Mt, although the share of each individual industry has changed. With the increase of imports in the primary resources industry, its imbalance of embodied CO2 decreased significantly and the proportion fell to 0.45%, which was the least imbalanced industry. The manufacturing industry still had the largest imbalance and the proportion rose to 65.81%. Among them, the imbalance of capital-intensive manufacturing is the largest, which is 696.39 Mt. Inevitably, it drove the rise of the imbalance of the whole manufacturing industry. The embodied CO2 in exports of knowledge-intensive manufacturing was higher than that from imports by 169.41 Mt. Labor-intensive manufacturing has the lowest imbalance (44.48 Mt). Thus, it can be seen that the structure of China’s embodied CO2 in exports has been optimized to a certain extent, with increase in the knowledge-intensive manufacturing exports and decrease in the labor-intensive manufacturing exports. However, as exports of capital-intensive manufacturing remain large, they still contribute to increased CO2. The imbalance proportion in the service sector has decreased slightly, from 37.68% of the total imbalance in 2005 to 33.74% in 2014. The imbalance in the capital-intensive services still dominates with relatively low imbalance in the other three services industries.
To summarize, the structure of China’s imports and exports of embodied CO2 has constantly been optimized, but the current imbalance is still substantial. As exports of labor-intensive manufacturing have declined and exports of knowledge-intensive manufacturing have increased, the shift towards knowledge-based manufacturing is beneficial to China’s reduction in emissions. However, the capital-intensive industries still have the biggest share of embodied CO2 emissions from exports. Capital-intensive industries have been labeled by high-carbon content; hence, they should be the focus of reducing carbon emissions in the future. In addition, the knowledge-intensive service industries and other service industries are low-carbon industries. The inclination towards such industries will help a great deal for achieving the overall emission reductions.

5. The Main Reasons for the Imbalance in China’s Embodied CO2

5.1. China’s Higher Carbon Emission Factor Compared to Its Major Trading Partner

One direct cause of the imbalance in embodied CO2 between imports and exports is that China produces higher CO2 per unit of output than its major trading countries in Europe, the US, and the developed East Asian countries. For instance, in 2002, China yielded 1.014 t of CO2 per thousand dollars of output compared to 0.255 t in the US, 0.245 t in Germany, and 0.152 t in Japan in the same year (Table 3). In other words, with the same amount of exports, China consumed 0.759 t, 0.769 t and 0.862 t of CO2 more than the US, Germany, and Japan, respectively. In particular, the carbon emission factors of capital-intensive manufacturing and capital-intensive services was as high as 1.460 and 3.926 (Figure 5), which were the leading products of China’s exports. However, due to improving environmental standards and emission reduction technologies, China’s carbon emission levels increased. For instance, the 2014 overall carbon emission factors fell to 0.312, already lower than India (0.505). At the same time, there were still noticeable differences compared to developed countries and even some developing countries. The differences in carbon emission levels between China and its major trading countries contribute directly to the imbalance of China’s embodied CO2 in imports and exports.

5.2. Global Relocation of Energy-Intensive Industries to China

Global relocation of manufacturing has a stepwise nature. According to the life cycle theory, the stages of industrial development include a start-up period, a growth period, a maturity period, and a decline period. An industry that enters the final stage will spread outward by seeking a transfer location. The differences in the economic development level of countries leads to the existence of gradient. The general rule is that when an industry in a country with a large economy of scale enters a period of decline, it will seek a new location and move to a country with a relatively small economy of scale. The world has experienced five major global manufacturing relocations involving changes in the geographic location of the world’s factories [36]. The fourth relocation was to China in the 1980s, which is one key factor in China’s imbalance of embodied CO2 in imports and exports. In this process, advanced East Asian nations such as Japan, Korea, Taiwan (China), and developed countries in Europe and NAFTA relocated their mature, labor-intensive, and capital-intensive industries to China, and created space for them to focus on knowledge-intensive industries. Although the transfer drove China’s economic development, many drawbacks followed. First, there is a large proportion of capital-intensive industries in China’s industrial structure. These industries tend to be energy-intensive and have high-carbon emission factors, as described above. In short, a drastic increase in carbon emissions can be excepted. The second drawback is carbon leakage from developed countries to China, meaning production in China and consumption in developed countries. In other words, after receiving the relocations from developed countries, China needs to produce and export those products. This process consumes energy and increases carbon dioxide emissions.
Data from 2005 and 2014 are used to illustrate the phenomenon. On the demand side, the 2005 shares of consumption, fixed capital, and inventory in China’s imported embodied CO2 were 36.27%, 60.24%, and 3.49% (Table 4). More than half of the imported embodied CO2 was used for fixed capital, indicating that imports dominated by capital goods. Moreover, the data also shows that China’s imported CO2 indicates investment dependence. In terms of regions, the main source of fixed capital was East Asia (31.90%), followed by Euro Zone (10.13%), NAFTA (6.24%) and BRIIAT (4.45%).
As for China’s embodied CO2 in exports, the proportions of consumption, fixed capital, and inventory were 63.03%, 35.60% and 1.37%, respectively. The data shows that consumer demand is the main dominant factor in China’s exports. In other words, exported CO2 indicates consumption dependence. In terms of regions, NAFTA is the main outflow region (26.85%), followed by East Asia (16.20%), Eurozone (12.54%), BRIIAT (5.96%) and non-Eurozone (5.79%), which shows that China exports a large amount of final products to meet the consumer demands from developed NAFTA countries, East Asia, and Euro Zone.
In addition, the main sources were China’s imported embodied CO2 from the industry include capital-intensive services, capital-intensive manufacturing, and knowledge-intensive manufacturing on the investment side (Figure 6). By contrast, the main destinations of China’s exported embodied CO2 include products of capital-intensive services, capital-intensive manufacturing, and labor-intensive manufacturing on the consumption side. Therefore, since the import and export industries are the same but from different sides, these industries can indicate that the global relocation of energy-intensive industries has imbalanced China’s embodied carbon.
However, this pattern of imbalance had eased primarily due to changes in the share of embodied CO2 in imports, the decreasing percentage of fixed capital, and increasing consumption. In 2014, the proportion of fixed capital decreased to 44.79%, while consumption increased to 50.23% (Table 5). This indicated that demand in China was shifting from investment-led to consumption-led scenarios, which would contribute to China’s industrial restructuring and reduce the embodied CO2 of exports.

6. Conclusions

The pattern of embodied CO2 emissions in China’s trade is closely linked to its natural advantages and the extent of its participation in the international demarcation. Since its accession to WTO, China has been integrated into the GVCs, and developed countries in Europe, NAFTA, and East Asia have relocated their industries without competitive advantages to China through foreign direct investment. As a result, China has become the world factory and has been vigorously developing its manufacturing industries regardless of the consumption of resources and damage to its environment, relying on an export-oriented economy [37,38]. However, nowadays China is seeking a balance between economic growth and environment protection. Seemingly as a problem between trade and environment, the imbalance of embodied CO2 in China’s imports and exports actually reflects China’s economic structure. The most crucial thing is the development of technology and knowledge, hence changing the way China participates in the GVCs, although it is not an easy task. Due to decades of reliance on labor and resources to drive its economy and its engagement in the production of energy-intensive industries, China is facing great difficulties in energy transition and emission reduction. A comprehensive and systematic change in its economic structure is crucial to achieve the 3060 Dual Carbon Goal.
First, it is important to realize that trade is one of the important drivers of China’s economic growth. The development of a high-quality economy is not to reduce the volume of trade, but to control the exports of high-energy-consuming, high-polluting, and resource-based products, while increasing the proportion of low-energy-consuming and low-emission goods and services in international trade. By doing so, a transition from a large trading country to a strong trading country can be achieved.
Second, industrial relocation is one of the causes of growth of carbon emissions; however, it is also one of the driving forces of economic growth. What China should do is not to deny or restrict the development of foreign investment, but to attract high-quality foreign investment, especially those focusing on the introduction of knowledge, technology, and other core elements in the GVCs. Ultimately, the upgrade and optimization of China’s industrial structure can be achieved.
Lastly, the Chinese government should formulate reasonable and effective policies to strengthen the regulations for pollution control and to support clean production. For example, environmental regulations can be tightened by establishing a unified carbon trading market system to raise the production costs of polluting industries, hence eventually removing them from the market. Another possibility is to strengthen financial support to clean technology and to guide local companies to engage in cleaner production.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Z.C. and Y.T.; methodology, Z.C.; software, Y.T.; validation, Z.C. and Y.T.; formal analysis, Y.T.; investigation, Y.T. and Z.C.; resources, Z.C.; data curation, Y.T.; writing—original draft preparation, Y.T.; writing—review and editing, Z.C. and Y.T.; visualization, Z.C.; supervision, Z.C.; project administration, Z.C.; funding acquisition, Z.C. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by Social Science Fund Project of China, grant No. 19BGJ050.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data sharing is not applicable to this article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Classification of Sector.
Table A1. Classification of Sector.
CategoriesSector NumberSector Name
Primary and Natural Resourcesr1, r2, r3, r4Agriculture, Hunting, Forestry, Fishing, Mining and Quarrying
Labor-Intensive Manufacturingr6,
r7,
r22
Textiles and Textile Products, Leather, Leather and Footwear
Wood and Products of Wood and Cork, Manufacturing
Capital-Intensive Manufacturingr5,
r8,
r9,
r10,
r13,
r14,
r15, r16,
r18
Food, Beverages and Tobacco
Paper and Paper Products,
Printing and Publishing
Coke, Refined Petroleum and Nuclear Fuel
Rubber and Plastics
Other Non-Metallic Mineral
Basic Metals and Fabricated Metal
Electrical equipment
Knowledge-Intensive Manufacturingr11, r12,
r17, r19,
r20, r21
Chemicals and Chemical Products Machinery
Electronic and Optical Equipment
Transport Equipment
Labor-Intensive Servicer27,
r28,
r29,
r30,
r34,
r36
Construction
Sale, Maintenance and Repair of Motor Vehicles
Wholesale Trade except of Motor Vehicles
Retail Trade except of Motor Vehicles and Motorcycles;
Other Supporting and Auxiliary Transport Activities
Accommodation and food service activities
Capital-Intensive Servicer23,
r24, r25, r26,
r31, r32, r33,
r35, r39,
r44
Repair and installation of machinery and equipment
Electricity, Gas and Water Supply
Inland Transport, Water Transport, Air Transport
Post and Telecommunications
Real Estate Activities
Knowledge-Intensive Servicer40,
r41, r42, r43, r45, r46,
r47,
r48,
r49,
r50
Computer programming, consultancy,
Financial Intermediation,
Architectural and engineering activities,
Scientific research and development,
Advertising and market research,
Other professional, scientific and technical activities,
Administrative and support service activities
Other Servicer37, r38,
r51,
r52,
r53,
r54,
r55,
r56
Publishing activities,
Public Admin and Defence, Compulsory Social Security
Education
Health and Social Work
Other Community,
Activities of households as employers
Activities of households as employers

References

  1. Yue, L.; Shuai, C.; Bin, S. Does Embedding the Global Value Chain Lead to Chinese Manufacture’s “Low-end Locking“. Manag. World 2018, 8, 11–29. [Google Scholar]
  2. Shuijun, P.; Wencheng, Z.; Chuanwang, S. China’s Production-Based and Consumption-Based Carbon Emissions and Their Determinants. Econ. Res. J. 2015, 1, 168–182. [Google Scholar]
  3. Yeru, Q.R.Z. The Best Way to Coordinate Trade and Environment: Internalization of Environmental Cost. China Popul. Resour. Environ. 2006, 16, 17–22. [Google Scholar]
  4. Baumol, W.J.; Oates, W. The Theory of Environmental Policy, 2nd ed.; Cambridge University Press: New York, NY, USA, 1988. [Google Scholar]
  5. Robison, H.D. Industrial Pollution Abatement. Can. J. Econ. 1988, 21, 187–199. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Lee, H.; Roland-Holst, D. International Trade and the Transfer of Environmental Costs and Benefits. OECD Work. Pap. 1993, 91, 1–47. [Google Scholar]
  7. Brain, R.; Copeland, M.S. Taylor, North-South Trade and the Environment. Q. J. Econ. 1994, 109, 755–787. [Google Scholar]
  8. Grossman, G.M.; Krueger, A.B. Environmental Impacts of a North American Free Trade Agreement; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar]
  9. Mani, M.; Wheeler, D. In Search of Pollution Havens? Dirty Industry in the World Economy, 1960 to 1995. J. Environ. Dev. 2016, 7, 215–247. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Huang, R.; Hubacek, K.; Feng, K.; Li, X.; Zhang, C. Re-Examining Embodied SO2 and CO2 Emissions in China. Sustainability 2018, 10, 1505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Zhang, Q.; Nakatani, J.; Moriguchi, Y. Compilation of an Embodied CO2 Emission Inventory for China Using 135-Sector Input-Output Tables. Sustainability 2015, 7, 8223–8239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Machado, G.; Schaeffer, R.; Worrell, E. Energy and carbon embodied in the international trade of Brazil: An input–output approach. Ecol. Econ. 2001, 3, 409–424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Ying, C.; Jiahua, P.; Laihui, X. Energy Embodied in Goods of International Trade in China: Calculation and Policy Implications. Econ. Res. J. 2008, 7, 11–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Peter, G.P.; Hertwich, E.G. CO2 embodied in international trade with implications for global climate policy. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2008, 42, 1401–1407. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  15. Wiedmann, T. A Review of Recent Multi-Region Input-Output Models Used for Consumption-based Emission and Resource Accounting. Ecol. Econ. 2009, 69, 211–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Jingmei, M.; Xinying, W. Transfer of Carbon Emissions Embodied in Sino-US Trade Based on MRIO Model. Stat. Inf. Forum 2015, 30, 40–47. [Google Scholar]
  17. Rui, X.; Guomei, Z. Investigating the Environment Effect of China’s Foreign Trade in Perspective of GMRIO Model. J. Quant. Tech. Econ. 2016, 33, 84–102. [Google Scholar]
  18. Zhigang, Y.; Can, Y. Globalization and the Development of China’s Production Service Industry—A Study Based on the Global Input-Output Model. Manag. World 2014, 3, 10–30. [Google Scholar]
  19. An, P. The Effect of GVC Division on Carbon Emission Embodied in China’s Foreign Trade. Int. Econ. Trade Res. 2017, 33, 14–26. [Google Scholar]
  20. An, P. Embodied Carbon in China-US Trade from Perspective of Global Value Chain. Stat. Res. 2018, 35, 53–64. [Google Scholar]
  21. Yunfeng, Y.; Rongping, C. The Trade Benefit of China and the US in Global Value Chain: A Trade in-Carbon Perspective. Int. Bus. 2017, 3, 17–26. [Google Scholar]
  22. Zhu, L.; Jing, M.; Zhu, D.; Lu, P.; Dabo, G.; Qiang, Z.; He, K.; Gong, P. Embodied carbon emissions in China-US trade. Sci. China Earth Sci. 2020, 50, 1633–1642. [Google Scholar]
  23. An, P.; Xiaoli, W. A Study on Embodied Carbon Emissions in Sino-Japan Trade from the Perspective of GVC Division. Contemp. Econ. Jpn. 2018, 2, 40–52. [Google Scholar]
  24. Jihong, J.; Yiyi, J. Shared Responsibility and Estimation of CO2 Emission Embodied in the China-Japan Trade. Manag. Rev. 2018, 30, 64–75. [Google Scholar]
  25. Zhenyuan, Z.; Xiaomin, L.; Maosheng, Z. A Comparative Study of China’s Trade Embodied Carbon with Other BRICS Countries. Asia Pac. Econ. Rev. 2018, 2, 62–67. [Google Scholar]
  26. Meng, F.; Su, M.; Hu, Y.C. Embodied carbon in trade of China and typical countries along the ‘Belt and Road’. China Popul. Resour. Environ. 2019, 29, 18–26. [Google Scholar]
  27. Sun, C.; Chen, L.; Huang, G. Decomposition Analysis of CO2 Emissions Embodied in the International Trade of Russia. Sustainability 2020, 12, 323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Tolmasquim, M.T.; Machado, G. Energy and Carbon Embodied in the International Trade of Brazil. Mitig. Adapt. Strateg. Glob. Change 2003, 8, 139–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Chung, W.S.; Tohno, S.; Choi, K.-H. Socio-technological impact analysis using an energy IO approach to GHG emissions issues in South Korea. Appl. Energy 2011, 88, 3747–3758. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Haipeng, W. Relationship between Foreign Trade and China’s CO2 Emissions. J. Int. Trade 2010, 7, 3–8. [Google Scholar]
  31. Xiaowen, D.; Yanbin, Q.; Hong, T. Embodied CO2 emission calculation and influence factors decomposition in China’s agriculture sector. Resour. Sci. 2015, 37, 1668–1676. [Google Scholar]
  32. Fei, R.; Pan, A.; Wu, X.; Xie, Q. How GVC division affects embodied CO2 in China’s exports? Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2020, 27, 36605–36620. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Wang, Z.; Wei, S.; Zhu, K. Gross Trade Accounting Method: Offical Trade Statistics and Measurement of the Global Value Chain. Soc. Sci. China 2015, 9, 108–206. [Google Scholar]
  34. Timmer, M.P.; Dietzenbacher, E.; Los, B.; Stehrer, R.; de Vries, G.J. An Illustrated User Guide to the World Input–Output Database: The Case of Global Automotive Production. Rev. Int. Econ. 2015, 23, 575–605. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Rahman, J.; Zhao, T. Export Performance in Europe: What Do We Know from Supply Links? IMF Working Paper; International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  36. Youjin, L.; Jian, Z. Make New Advances Amid Changes: A New Round of International Industrial Transfer and the Future of China’s Manufacturing Industry. J. Hunan Univ. Sci. Technol. (Social Sci. Ed.) 2021, 24, 63–70. [Google Scholar]
  37. Yuhuan, Z.; Lu, Z.; Sichen, L. Impact of Participating in Global Value Chains on Carbon Emissions Embodied in China’s Exports. J. Int. Trade 2021, 3, 142–157. [Google Scholar]
  38. Xiang, S.; Wen, T. Re-estimation of the Implicit CO2 Emissions in China’s Foreign Trade from the Perspective of New Value—Added Trade Statistics. Int. Econ. Trade Res. 2014, 30, 17–29. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. The embodied CO2 in China’s import and export from 2001 to 2014 (Unit: Mt). Source: The figure in this article is plotted by the calculations.
Figure 1. The embodied CO2 in China’s import and export from 2001 to 2014 (Unit: Mt). Source: The figure in this article is plotted by the calculations.
Sustainability 14 06460 g001
Figure 2. The product type of embodied CO2 in China’s import and export from 2001 to 2014. Note: The left one is embodied CO2 in import and the right is in export.
Figure 2. The product type of embodied CO2 in China’s import and export from 2001 to 2014. Note: The left one is embodied CO2 in import and the right is in export.
Sustainability 14 06460 g002
Figure 3. Region distribution of China’s embodied CO2 in import and export in 2010. (Unit: Mt). Note: (1) NAFTA refers to North American Free Trade Area, BRIIAT includes Brazil, Russia, India, Indonesia, Australia and Turkey, East Asia includes Japan, South Korea and Taiwan (China), and ROW refers to the rest of the world. Since the rest of the world ROW is counted as a whole, the description of this article does not include ROW. (2) This table divides the EU into the Euro Zone and Non-Euro Zone. The former contains Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Germany, Spain, Estonia, Finland, France, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia and Slovenia. Non-Euro Zone contains Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Denmark, the United Kingdom, Croatia, Hungary, Lithuania, Latvia, Poland Romania and Sweden. Since Switzerland CHE and Norway NOR are not part of the EU, they are not included in the statistical results.
Figure 3. Region distribution of China’s embodied CO2 in import and export in 2010. (Unit: Mt). Note: (1) NAFTA refers to North American Free Trade Area, BRIIAT includes Brazil, Russia, India, Indonesia, Australia and Turkey, East Asia includes Japan, South Korea and Taiwan (China), and ROW refers to the rest of the world. Since the rest of the world ROW is counted as a whole, the description of this article does not include ROW. (2) This table divides the EU into the Euro Zone and Non-Euro Zone. The former contains Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Germany, Spain, Estonia, Finland, France, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia and Slovenia. Non-Euro Zone contains Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Denmark, the United Kingdom, Croatia, Hungary, Lithuania, Latvia, Poland Romania and Sweden. Since Switzerland CHE and Norway NOR are not part of the EU, they are not included in the statistical results.
Sustainability 14 06460 g003
Figure 4. Industry distribution of China’s imports and exports of embodied CO2 in 2005 and 2014 (Unit: Mt). Note: (1) The left one is industry distribution of embodied CO2 in 2005 and the right is in 2014. (2) P, L-M, C-M, K-M, L-S, C-S, K-S, O-S represent primary industries, labor-intensive manufacturing, capital-intensive manufacturing, knowledge-intensive manufacturing, labor-intensive services, capital-intensive services, knowledge-intensive services and other services, respectively.
Figure 4. Industry distribution of China’s imports and exports of embodied CO2 in 2005 and 2014 (Unit: Mt). Note: (1) The left one is industry distribution of embodied CO2 in 2005 and the right is in 2014. (2) P, L-M, C-M, K-M, L-S, C-S, K-S, O-S represent primary industries, labor-intensive manufacturing, capital-intensive manufacturing, knowledge-intensive manufacturing, labor-intensive services, capital-intensive services, knowledge-intensive services and other services, respectively.
Sustainability 14 06460 g004
Figure 5. China’s direct carbon emission factors of specific industries in 2005, 2010 and 2014. Note: P, L-M, C-M, K-M, L-S, C-S, K-S, O-S represent primary industries, labor-intensive manufacturing, capital-intensive manufacturing, knowledge-intensive manufacturing, labor-intensive services, capital-intensive services, knowledge-intensive services and other services, respectively.
Figure 5. China’s direct carbon emission factors of specific industries in 2005, 2010 and 2014. Note: P, L-M, C-M, K-M, L-S, C-S, K-S, O-S represent primary industries, labor-intensive manufacturing, capital-intensive manufacturing, knowledge-intensive manufacturing, labor-intensive services, capital-intensive services, knowledge-intensive services and other services, respectively.
Sustainability 14 06460 g005
Figure 6. Demand-side imports and exports of industry distribution of China’s embodied CO2. (Unit: Mt). Note: (1) The upper left one is import in 2005, the lower left one is export in 2005, The upper right one is import in 2014, the lower right one is export in 2014. (2) P, L-M, C-M, K-M, L-S, C-S, K-S, O-S represent primary industries, labor-intensive manufacturing, capital-intensive manufacturing, knowledge-intensive manufacturing, labor-intensive services, capital-intensive services, knowledge-intensive services and other services, respectively.
Figure 6. Demand-side imports and exports of industry distribution of China’s embodied CO2. (Unit: Mt). Note: (1) The upper left one is import in 2005, the lower left one is export in 2005, The upper right one is import in 2014, the lower right one is export in 2014. (2) P, L-M, C-M, K-M, L-S, C-S, K-S, O-S represent primary industries, labor-intensive manufacturing, capital-intensive manufacturing, knowledge-intensive manufacturing, labor-intensive services, capital-intensive services, knowledge-intensive services and other services, respectively.
Sustainability 14 06460 g006
Table 1. The Decomposition of Country s’ Gross Exports.
Table 1. The Decomposition of Country s’ Gross Exports.
Value-Added
Parts
Contents of
Value-Add
Specific
Meaning
Producing
Country
Consuming Country
T1DVA_FINDomestic value-addition by direct importersr
T2DVA_INTDomestic value-addition by direct importersr
T3 + T4 + T5DVA_INTRE XDomestic value-addition by other countriesst
T6 + T7 + T8RDVDomestic value-addition returns homess
T11 + T12MVAForeign value-addition from direct importerrr
T14 + T15OVAForeign value-addition from other countriestr
Note: The meanings of DVA_FIN and DVA_INT are the same, but the former is the final product and the latter is the intermediate product. Besides, s, r and t represent exporting country, importing country and third country, respectively.
Table 2. China’s Embodied CO2 of Import and Export to Major Countries by Region in 2010 (Unit: Mt).
Table 2. China’s Embodied CO2 of Import and Export to Major Countries by Region in 2010 (Unit: Mt).
RegionCountryImmediate Product (Import)Final Product (Import)Immediate Product (Export)Final Product (Export)
EuroGermany9.0511.4335.7244.38
EuroFrance2.281.9521.2921.25
EuroItaly1.562.2417.0517.09
EuroThe Netherlands1.491.1614.7012.71
Non-EuroUK.1.291.5119.6925.58
East AsiaJapan26.5813.0974.4092.37
NAFTAUS17.339.0891.41214.58
BRIIATAustralia11.541.3619.4520.81
BRIIATBrazil7.060.6613.4913.68
BRIIATIndia11.091.3420.7817.40
Table 3. Direct carbon emission factors of China and its’ major trading countries.
Table 3. Direct carbon emission factors of China and its’ major trading countries.
RegionCountry2002200420062008201020122014
EuroGermany0.2450.1840.1490.1120.1060.0980.097
EuroFrance0.1270.0920.0740.0600.0550.0490.046
EuroItaly0.1610.1250.1040.0860.0750.0690.064
EuroNetherlands0.1960.1510.1170.0980.0980.0850.087
Non-EuroUK0.1650.1360.1070.0850.0950.0880.074
East AsiaJapan0.1520.1420.1270.1290.1060.1010.121
NAFTAUS0.2550.2340.1990.1810.1770.1490.142
BRIIATAustralia0.4660.3300.2430.1950.1940.1280.124
BRIIATBrazil0.3180.3080.1960.1400.1300.0950.116
BRIIATIndia0.9800.8250.6580.5450.5600.4560.505
East AsiaChina1.0141.0140.8420.6250.5020.3840.312
Table 4. Demand-side 2005 imports and exports of regional distribution of China’s embodied CO2 (Unit: Mt).
Table 4. Demand-side 2005 imports and exports of regional distribution of China’s embodied CO2 (Unit: Mt).
Import Export
Consumption Euro1.555.68%Consumption Euro76.7412.54%
Non-Euro0.511.87% Non-Euro35.445.79%
27.37BRIIAT2.428.84%612.21BRIIAT36.495.96%
36.27%East Asia4.4916.41%63.03%East Asia99.1616.20%
NAFTA1.826.64% NAFTA164.3626.85%
ROW16.4860.22% ROW196.9232.17%
Fixed Capital Euro4.6010.13%Fixed Capital Euro44.0912.75%
Non-Euro0.741.63% Non-Euro10.593.06%
45.45BRIIAT2.024.45%345.80BRIIAT23.406.77%
60.24%East Asia14.5031.90%35.60%East Asia61.8917.90%
NAFTA2.926.42% NAFTA113.7332.89%
ROW20.5645.23% ROW90.5026.17%
Inventories Euro0.186.79%Inventories Euro3.9129.33%
Non-Euro0.031.17% Non-Euro0.574.31%
2.63BRIIAT0.145.42%13.31BRIIAT1.9014.25%
3.49%East Asia0.8030.59%1.37%East Asia1.8113.59%
NAFTA0.165.98% NAFTA5.0337.80%
ROW1.3149.91% ROW0.000.00%
Table 5. Demand-side 2014 imports and exports of regional distribution of China’s embodied CO2 (Unit: Mt).
Table 5. Demand-side 2014 imports and exports of regional distribution of China’s embodied CO2 (Unit: Mt).
Import Export
Consumption Euro4.717.82%Consumption Euro68.299.81%
Non-Euro1.582.63% Non-Euro28.084.04%
60.17BRIIAT5.959.89%696.03BRIIAT68.459.83%
50.23%East Asia7.9513.21%65.29%East Asia66.339.53%
NAFTA5.368.90% NAFTA127.6518.34%
ROW34.4257.21% ROW334.7048.09%
Fixed Capital Euro7.1313.29%Fixed Capital Euro42.8511.93%
Non-Euro1.212.25% Non-Euro14.704.09%
53.66BRIIAT1.502.79%359.26BRIIAT40.7911.35%
44.79%East Asia22.1741.32%33.70%East Asia63.4317.65%
NAFTA5.7710.74% NAFTA91.4825.46%
ROW15.7029.27% ROW103.7028.86%
Inventories Euro0.416.94%Inventories Euro2.2620.88%
Non-Euro0.081.39% Non-Euro0.857.85%
5.97BRIIAT0.437.21%10.84BRIIAT3.1328.87%
4.98%East Asia2.0133.63%1.02%East Asia0.797.28%
NAFTA0.498.29% NAFTA3.4832.11%
ROW2.5342.34% ROW0.000.01%
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Chen, Z.; Tan, Y. The Imbalance of Embodied CO2 in China’s Imports, Exports and Its Causes. Sustainability 2022, 14, 6460. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14116460

AMA Style

Chen Z, Tan Y. The Imbalance of Embodied CO2 in China’s Imports, Exports and Its Causes. Sustainability. 2022; 14(11):6460. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14116460

Chicago/Turabian Style

Chen, Zhiheng, and Yaru Tan. 2022. "The Imbalance of Embodied CO2 in China’s Imports, Exports and Its Causes" Sustainability 14, no. 11: 6460. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14116460

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop