Next Article in Journal
Electric Field Induced Changes of a Diffusion Flame and Heat Transfer near an Impinging Surface
Previous Article in Journal
Real-Time Transient Thermal Rating and the Calculation of Risk Level of Transmission Lines
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

An Exploratory Study on Coopetitive Behavior in Oil and Gas Distribution

by
Sebastian Ion Ceptureanu
1,*,
Eduard Gabriel Ceptureanu
1,
Marieta Olaru
2 and
Liviu Bogdan Vlad
3
1
Department of Management, The Bucharest University of Economic Studies, 010374 Bucharest, Romania
2
Department of Business, Consumer Sciences and Quality Management, The Bucharest University of Economic Studies, 010374 Bucharest, Romania
3
Department of Tourism and Geography, The Bucharest University of Economic Studies, 010374 Bucharest, Romania
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2018, 11(5), 1234; https://doi.org/10.3390/en11051234
Submission received: 21 April 2018 / Revised: 8 May 2018 / Accepted: 9 May 2018 / Published: 12 May 2018

Abstract

:
The purpose of this article is to analyze coopetitive behavior of companies operating in oil and gas distribution networks, enhancing both conceptual clarity of the concept and understanding of its specifics in oil and gas industry. We developed a model based on six factors: intensity, functionality, formalism, benefits, tension and stability to investigate 10 research hypothesis on a sample consisting of 154 subjects from 39 companies. By its conceptualization and results, our study is one of the first focusing on coopetitive behavior in oil and gas distribution and contributes to shape coopetition as a distinct subject for research.

1. Introduction

Discussion of coopetition, representing the simultaneous pursuit of cooperation and competition by organizations, has been on the rise in the academic literature recently [1,2,3,4,5]. Without any doubt, coopetition is a reality across many industries. Our paper seeks to contribute to the understanding of coopetition dynamics in oil and gas products distribution supply chains by empirically testing several factors specific to the coopetition process. By using a model which integrates various approaches of the concept, we analyze and discuss specific interactions and the resulting dynamics.
Scholars argue that coopetition between organizations create a paradox which have the potential to aggravate tensions among them and break existing partnerships [6,7]. Large failure rates of alliances between competitors [8,9] indicate that companies lack, in many cases, the ability to manage tensions occurring during coopetitive relations [10,11], negatively impacting the expected outcomes [12,13]. However, this does not mean that managing the coopetition paradox [14] is needless, requiring a balanced approach of emerging tensions [15,16,17] to fully grasp the benefits of cooperation.
Our research is based on a model relying on the literature dedicated to coopetition, covering the most important dimensions of any coopetitive relation: intensity, functionality, formalism, benefits, tension and stability. The outcome is coopetitive performance measured by subjects’ perception about overall benefits of getting involved in the coopetition. Our study is conducted in oil and gas distribution networks, a fertile ground in terms of coopetition considering the multitude of companies involved and the nature of their relationships. Romanian market is dominated by several large providers, while smaller companies distributing their products have to compete with other companies established by large oil companies themselves.
This paper aims to develop coopetition literature by clarifying the landscape of coopetitive relations in oil and gas distribution, enabling scholars and practitioners to better understand this process.

2. Literature Review

The engagement of organizations in coopetition materializes a paradox in the relationship [12,18]. Scholars argue that such a paradox engenders coopetitive tensions that in turn have the potential to aggravate the relationship and break partnerships [6,7], with large failure rates of alliances between competitors [8,9]. Unfortunately, the definition of coopetition still remains fuzzy [19]. Various definitions are used, with significant differences in terms of scope and nature. Usually, coopetition is defined as cooperation between directly competing organizations [5,20,21]. Moreover, coopetition has also been defined as an occurrence between different supply chains [22], and networks [23].
In strategic management literature, cooperation and competition were traditionally seen as antagonistic drivers within cooperative arrangements [24], with competitive side of a cooperative relationship usually regarded as potentially harmful [25,26]. By contrast, coopetition perspective tries to integrate the two paradoxical approaches into a common construct [14,27]. The emerging perspective is to depict cooperation and competition as two separate continua allowing to distinguish between different forms of coopetition with varying levels of intensity for cooperation and competition respectively [12,28,29].
According to Brandenburger and Nalebuff’s (1996) [30], this cooperative-competitive approach has to be defined relationally, as relations between customers, suppliers, and competitors, which jointly create value for themselves and the other partners involved. So, coopetition is perceived as the sum of various relations, with cooperative and competitive relations divided between various actors. This conceptualization is used by networking and industrial coopetition literature [4,31,32]. At an inter-organizational level, Bengtsson and Kock [33] emphasized the tension and complexity occurring when two or more organizations cooperate and compete simultaneously. They restrict coopetition at direct competitors, focusing on the horizontal coopetition and argue that relations are divided between activities. Hence, according to this approach, coopetition appears as consisting of two simultaneous interactions: cooperation for a distinct set of activities and competition for a different set of activities [1,3,5,11].
In the literature there are several approaches used by scholars when studying coopetition phenomena. One approach uses game theory, considering cooperative-competitive relations as mutual profitable relationships and discussing the balance between value creation and value appropriation [1,30,34]. A second approach uses a resource-based view and focuses on the benefits of mutually developing and using technologies and resources [35,36]. Finally, a third approach, based on networks, emphasize the importance of cooperative ties between competing firms in terms of learning and knowledge sharing through networks [37] or joint development of competitive advantages [20].
Other scholars develop the coopetition literature based on the level where cooperative-competitive relations occurs:
(a) On an individual level, coopetition relates to how individual motivations stimulate various individuals to compete, even if they trust each other [38]. The most frequently outcomes are knowledge sharing and team performance [39,40].
(b) On an organizational level, coopetition emphasize processes between units or teams, and primarily highlight how they affect knowledge sharing. Tsai [41] argues that formal hierarchy negatively affect knowledge sharing while informal lateral relations have positive effects on the process. For Luo [21] different infrastructural systems enable units to collaborate, while simultaneously competing with each other. Ghobadi and D’Ambra [2] analyzed cross-functional project teams and argue that the organization of projects is critical for positive outcomes in terms of knowledge sharing.
(c) The most common level of coopetition research is inter-organizational. Sometimes called simple coopetition, it occurs between organizations placed on the same level of value chain. This type of relational structure emphasize continuous and intensive transfer of products and information between supply chain participants, discouraging opportunistic behavior. According to Bengtsson et al. [19], partners seek increased competitiveness and securing competitive advantages, mutual development of technological innovations, exploration of international opportunities, and access to resources. Various studies explored how coopetition affects R&D activities [42], knowledge creation [43], knowledge acquisition [44], and knowledge transfer [45]. Commitment to long-term cooperation does not involve abandoning competition, the reason behind cooperation lies in the willingness to work with a vendor to solve technical and economic problems, instead of changing provider.
(d) Network-based coopetition, sometimes called complex coopetition, occurs in industrial clusters, where concentration of small and medium sized organizations in aggregated structures enable a dynamic network of closely interconnected structures, with varying levels of cooperation intensity. At the same time, network-based coopetition covers the entire value chain, from production to distribution. Scholars argue that organizational structures and processes serve as the backbone to balance coopetition, both at the organizational and inter-organizational levels; however, the latter level also demands the consideration of relation-specific and contextual factors as critical. Peng and Bourne [23] studied coopetition between healthcare networks and concluded that coopetition between networks with compatible but different structures is easier to balance. Song and Lee [22] studied how both cooperation and competition between value chains facilitate knowledge acquisition and the created logistics value. Studies on the network level coopetition are scarce, and more studies are needed in the future.
Distribution of oil and gas products is characterized by a highly complex network of companies that are involved in both cooperation and competition [46]. Hence, the oil and gas industry is a strong case to analyze coopetition because its products are widely used in economic and social activities [47] and the nature of interactions between various actors is dynamic, under continuous changes.
Coopetition assumes that companies involved facilitate strategic and transparent integration of key business processes and cooperation among supply chain members [48,49,50]. As such, coopetition entails that companies move beyond their immediate economic concerns and take proactive steps towards accepting and multiplying aggregated effects of cooperation while retaining their ability to compete on other markets or new clients. Srivastava [51] suggests that companies employ new strategies to achieve their goals. As such, propensity of companies from oil and gas distribution toward coopetition should help overcome negative effects of intense competition, a distinct feature in oil and gas distribution, while allowing them to sustain itself economically. Another study [52] argue that oil and gas companies could be exposed to legal, financial and reputational risks if they fail to align their objectives with the suppliers.
To address these risks, various scholars [53,54] have suggested actions that companies may take in order to improve supply chain performance. Improve cooperation with suppliers to improve the overall performance of logistics operations, for instance, may be useful in reducing costs and effective coordination of supply chain activities [55].
Involvement in coopetition in supply chains may have an internal and an external driver. Internal driver can be demonstrated through top management leadership [56,57,58,59,60], development of a more open organizational culture [48,49,57,61] or willingness to adhere to coopetitive business behavior. Management support is also crucial to enable mutual learning processes and to facilitate knowledge transfer [62,63]. A more open organizational culture determine companies to actively engage with suppliers and clients to improve supply chain performance, leading to vertical integration across supply chain and horizontal integration across networks [48,49].
Coopetition may lead to better risk management related to brand image and quality, enhancing the involved companies’ reputation [64], mitigating economic risks of supply chain activities [62]. Close cooperation with supply chain partners could facilitate more effective risk assessment practices [65,66]. As such, coopetition may enable collaboration between supply chain partners in developing supply chain solutions that can collectively improve their capabilities and competitiveness [67]. The lack of coordination and communication in companies and across supply chains could lead to ineffective cooperation [50,65]. Strategic collaboration with suppliers enables companies to develop supply chain capabilities and knowledge that can be used to reduce costs [59].
Oil and gas companies may find reasons to get involved in cooperation due to potential increase in perceived or expected benefits, surpassing benefits of acting alone or with traditional partners, and reduce threats, usually from external factors. Other benefits include better use of resources [2,68], better use of capabilities and skills to fulfill specific objectives as well as saving costs, both for current operations and for specific projects or increased organizational effectiveness. Others [69] argue that collaboration improve effectiveness because it enables companies to direct resources to increase their credibility, while for others [68] collaboration lead to a common framework to solve problems [70]. Other scholars highlight synergy achieved when two or more organizations combine their strengths [68] or improved delivery of services [70].
Concerning threats as a factor leading to cooperation, the literature includes elements like environmental turbulence [71] or political and economic circumstances [68]. According to this rationale, collaboration is a natural response to environmental factors. Increased competition for resources is such a factor [69]. Instead of competing for scarce resources, companies can team together, using less resources to get more value.
Regarding competitive dimension, namely barriers in active cooperation between companies, lack of motivation is perhaps the most common cited. It includes a wide array of factors, such as reluctance of many companies to consciously sacrifice something (knowledge, resources, etc.) in order to collaborate with others [72], or lack of organizational congruence between organizations, encompassing divergent goals or objectives [68], unwillingness to compromise their specific goals for the sake of common objectives [72], difficulties in managing obligations deriving from cooperation [70] or operational differences, relating to either day-to-day running of the business or a perceived incompatibility of leadership or management styles of the companies [72].

3. Materials and Methods

There is a significant lack of empirical research in the field, with most studies focusing on setting up models and frameworks. Hence, we investigated the coopetition phenomenon among companies operating in oil and gas distribution based on a quantitative research. Data collection was performed by using a standardized, closed questionnaire. The questionnaires were sent by email, with a small number filled directly during a workshop. In the end, we collected 154 valid questionnaires (Table 1). The respondents were explicitly encouraged to note any clarifications they see fit to explain their answers. For the validity of our study, only respondents from top management tier were considered, like president, manager or board member were considered. This limitation was considered essential for acquiring data on coopetition is terms of trust or performance, for instance.
Capitalizing on literature on this topic [73] we defined a model composed of six factors (Table 2):
(1) Intensity factor reflects the number of traditional partners and collaborative competitors. A higher number of partners is considered to positively contribute to cooperation [74]. In terms of access to resources, a higher number of partners offers the chance to find additional resources and gain access to relevant know-how [68] while simultaneously signals better experience, superior skills in managing connections with other organizations and superior learning skills or knowledge retention capabilities. Hereby, we argue that H1.
Hypothesis 1 (H1).
Companies with a high number of partners achieve better results in coopetition.
(2) Functionality factor reflects how the coopetitive relation is working. Variables of interest are type of relation, highlighting to what level of the value chain occurs value creation, who was the initiator of the relation, what are the objectives pursued and if a separate structure for managing the relation was established [75]. Therefore, we argue that H2.
Hypothesis 2 (H2).
Value creation level influences benefits distribution.
(3) Formalism factor address the trust vs contract side of the coopetitive relationship, the existence of any agreements or contracts between partners, the mutual trust and how it has evolved during their relation. Two hypothesis were assumed, namely:
Hypothesis 3 (H3).
Distinct formal structures are required to manage successfully manage coopetitive relations.
Hypothesis 4 (H4).
Coopetitive relations based on trust are more beneficial than those based on formal agreements.
(4) Benefits factor considers company own benefits, competitors’ benefits and their distribution. Creating value and making use of it is critical for coopetition [1]. Companies can create shared value by collaborating with competitors, by accessing their resources or develop common sales, for instance. This value will be shared jointly by all the partners according to each one’s contribution and bargaining power. The problem of mutual vs private benefits has been addressed first by Khana et al. [72] and later developed by Kumar [76]:
Hypothesis 5 (H5).
Benefits are maximized when cooperation and competition are balanced.
Hypothesis 6 (H6).
Benefits of company are directly related to partners’ benefits.
(5) Tension factor was necessary to be included due to the paradoxical nature of coopetition, the necessity of balancing cooperation and competition, and the need to manage tension within the relation [77] to achieve a dynamic resource balance [78]. Scholars propose different strategies to manage this tension. Oliver [79] suggests that competition and cooperation should be separated for each process and in time, while Chin [80] emphasize the importance of trust. Tension is considered to have a beneficial effect on performance, but high levels are considered unproductive [81]:
Hypothesis 7 (H7).
Coopetitive tension is inversely proportional to coopetitive performance.
Hypothesis 8 (H8).
Trust is inversely proportional to coopetitive tension.
Hypothesis 9 (H9).
Increased opportunism corresponds to increased coopetitive tension.
(6) Stability factor reflects the impact of definite/indefinite character of relation or the stability and performance of coopetitive relations [82]:
Hypothesis 10 (H10).
Increased stability leads to low coopetitive tension and higher performance.
Hypothesis were correlated with factors of the model. Interactions between factors were further analyzed in a regression model to determine the variation in the level of benefits associated with the concurrent action of considered factors.
Special attention was payed to measurement of coopetitive relations Performance. There is no generally accepted method up to date. The selected method of measuring performance is subjective, perceived performance by top executives of surveyed companies. However, taking a look at the fact that decision-makers are engaged in a coopetitive relation for specific objectives, their individual perception of the effectiveness of the relation is relevant (possibly the most relevant) and other studies confirm the accuracy of the method [83].
The tools used in the analysis were non-parametric correlations (Kendall and Spearman), cross-tabs, analysis of variance and linear regression.
Before analyzing the actual data we tested their reliability with the common variation method (Table 3). Using analysis of variance to analyze the effect of one factor only we extracted four factors explaining 39% of the total variance. The first is responsible for 14.259% of the variation, the second for 9.086% and the sum of the following two, 15.3%. Considering the results we concluded that the problem of common variation is not confirmed and we proceed further.

4. Results

(1) Intensity factor was analyzed to test Hypothesis H1.
(a) Number of coopetitive relations measured total number of interactions of the surveyed companies, regardless if it is with an organization perceived as competitor or not (Table 4). In our study, the median for the number of partners was 2.6, while for the number of competitors it was 2.
According to Park and Russo [74], a large number of relations/partners contribute to achieving good results. Gong et al. [68] argues that a high number of partners means better access to resources and know-how. A similar study conducted by Yamakawa [84] testing the impact of business alliances (they assumed that a large number of alliances indicates a high number of partners) achieved a weak and insignificant negative correlation (−0.04, n.a). It is possible that engaging in relations with a large number of organizations (partners and competitors) weaken companies’ relational capabilities or make them to pay less attention to each relation and, as such, relations are not optimized.
(b) Behavior describes who initiated the coopetitive relation and as such it may be proactive (initiated by surveyed companies) or reactive (initiated by a competitor). In the study, 70% of surveyed companies were found to be proactive, 9% reactive while 21% manifests both a proactive and reactive behavior according to circumstances.
(c) Competitors variable measured number of perceived direct and indirect competitors for surveyed companies. Direct or indirect competitor status is given by the type of the cooperative relations (horizontal or vertical). In our sample, half of surveyed companies use horizontally coopetitive relations, 16% use vertical relations while 34% were engaged in mixed relations, a balanced result considering the 2 main approaches in coopetition field: coopetition in a large sense [30,85], which includes mixed and vertical relations, and the narrow approach of coopetition [11], which considers only horizontal coopetition, relations with direct competitors.
We tested Hypothesis H1 which was not confirmed, the link was weak and statically insignificant (0.154, n.s.) (Table 5).
(2) Functionality factor details how the coopetitive relation is working and seek to test Hypotheses H2 and H3. Again, four variables were constructed:
(a) Value creation variable pinpointed where coopetitive interaction generated value creation for the company. Reviewing literature, we opted out for Know-how, Resource sharing, Operations, Procurement and Sales.
(b) Initiator variable identified who initiated the relation. An interesting fact was that 16 of surveyed companies provided mixed answers, they were simultaneously initiators and partners. We consider that is normal taking into account the very nature of coopetition relation, a succession of coopetitive contingent games. This situation was theorized by Padula and Dagnino [5], by referring to the theory of positive sum game.
(c) Objectives variable measured what goals have to be achieved or what were the reasons to engage in a coopetitive relation. In our study they includes New products/services, New markets, Access additional resources and Access new knowledge, in this succession.
(d) Structure variable measured existence of any formal, distinct organizational arrangement, created exclusively for coordination of coopetitive relation. Theoretical models [75] argue that the existence of the separated structures have a positive impact on how effective is the coopetitive relation. In our study, we discovered a clear lack of formal structures, just 9% of respondents admitted using it. It seems that a majority of surveyed companies’ executives prefer to personally and informally handle relations with other organizations.
To test H2 hypothesis we used a matrix and calculated the Benefits median (Table 6).
Important differences exists, the highest level being registered by those relations seeking shared Procurement (2) followed by Know-how (1.863) and Sales (1.619). Hypothesis H2 is hence confirmed. The importance of knowledge transfer in the coopetitive relations in various studies is confirmed in our study by the high level of associated perceived Benefits.
Hypothesis H3 is partially confirmed. Correlation between Structure and Performance was not confirmed (−0.1, n.s), while Structure clearly correlated with Number of coopetitive relations (0.215, p < 0.05) (Table 7).
(3) Formalism factor describes the level of trust in the coopetitive relation and its evolution. Three variables were constructed:
(a) Contract measured the existence of a formal contract/arrangement between oil and gas distribution companies during coopetitive relation. In our study, the majority of companies (82%) has formal agreements for the ongoing of coopetitive relations. The main reasons were the clear definition of the mutual obligations and the guarantees in case of any litigations. The results are comparable with those of Schmoltzi and Wallenburg [73].
(b) Trust measured opinion of the respondents on the contract versus trust balance during coopetitive relation. 63% of respondents consider that contractual agreements are more important, 32% rely on trust while 5% consider them equally important. Less trust means more contract.
(c) Trust evolution measured evolution of trust between the partners after the start of the relation. In more than 50% of the cases it increased, while for less than 20% it decreased. We concluded that more oil and gas distribution companies begin to trust more their partners, regardless if they were competitors or not, during their cooperation.
To test H4 hypothesis we compared mean values for Contract and Trust variables related to Benefits.
We concluded that H4 hypothesis is confirmed, the relation based on trust having a mean (1.862) higher than those based on contract (1.596). The difference between the numbers of cases is given by the fact that some of the respondents gave an equal importance for the two of the possibilities (Table 8).
(4) Benefits factor describes performance of coopetitive relation based on own-benefits vs mutual benefits. Kale et al. [83] have investigated different ways of measuring the performance in partnerships and consider that the executives’ opinion about the results is relevant and precise, they are the most suitable to assess if the relation fulfill organizational objectives. This factor was used to test Hypotheses 5 and 6.
(a) Benefits measured respondents’ perception about how lucrative is the coopetitive relation. According to our study, 75.3% of respondents consider that coopetitive relation results are positive, 14.3% without impact (the benefits are compensated by company contribution) and 10.3% consider that the result is negative. The results are very similar to those achieved by Duysters and de Mann [86], in their analysis on the partnerships’ effects on the performance.
(b) Competitor benefits measured the perception of the respondents about the competitor company benefits achieved by coopetitive relation. According to our study, more than 80% of respondents consider that coopetitive relations bring benefits to their competitors, also.
We concluded that both variables (Benefits and Competitor benefits) have a similar distribution, correlation is positive and significant (0.447; p < 0.001) according to the mutual benefits theory (Table 9). Hence, H5 was confirmed.
(c) Benefits distribution measured the perception of the respondents about the distribution of mutual benefits. A majority of the respondents, 75%, have considered it as fair and mutual. Corroborating the result with the coopetition typology (Gnyawali and Park [11]), we concluded that a balance between the competitive and collaborative sides of coopetition was reached. In the 25% other cases we encountered a dominant competitive dimension, with benefits appropriated by one partner or the other. In our study, the majority of the relations involved operational contingencies in procurement, resources and operations. Hence, coopetition gave the chance of accessing only some marginal opportunities which negatively affect the outcome. This way the H6 hypothesis was confirmed, similar to the Luo [28] and Gnyawali and Park [11] studies according to which performance is maximized when both cooperative and competitive sides of coopetition are balanced.
(5) Tension is a factor who recursively emerge in many studies about coopetition (Gnyawali and Park [87]). The paradoxical nature of coopetition determines a perceived tension for decision makers, the so called coopetitive tension. Achieving a high level of performance means keeping under control the coopetitive tension.
(a) Coopetitive tension measured the perceived tension during coopetitive relation. In our sample, the level of perceived tension (2.74 based on the Likert scale) was between low and medium.
(b) Opportunism variable measured the perceived risk of the opportunistic behavior from the other partner. The concept is derived from game theory. The opportunism is expressed by the risk that one of the two players involved in coopetition stop cooperating after it gets its desired resources or outcomes from the other player. In our study it has a distribution almost equal, 48% of respondents stating they have experienced opportunistic behavior risks from their partners.
Regarding Hypothesis H7, a majority of theoretical models considers that a high level of coopetitive tension harms the relation’s performance [81]. This is confirmed in our research, correlation between the two of the variables, Benefits and Coopetitive tension is negative (−0.435; p < 0.001) (Table 10).
We further tested the H8 hypothesis by using Kendall and Spearman test for Coopetitive tension with Trust evolution (Table 11).
H8 hypothesis was confirmed (−0.261; p < 0.01). Fang et al. [7] analyzed the relation between trust and tension and they achieved comparable results (−0.35, p < 0.001).
Finally, H9 hypothesis was tested by using Coopetitive tension and Opportunism variables (Table 12).
This hypothesis was also confirmed (0.266; p < 0.01). Fang et al. [7] have analyzed the tension-engagement relation and achieved a significant negative correlation (−0.29; p < 0.01). Assuming Engagement and Opportunism are opposite constructs, there seem to be a reversed correlation between them. Starting from this premise, our results are comparable with Fang (especially Spearman rho test).
(6) Stability factor, defined by two variables, reflects the impact of definite/ indefinite character of coopetitive relations on their stability and performance. Theoretical models argue that determined term relations will have higher levels of coopetitive tension, opportunism and a lower level of implication which will translate in inferior performance. This factor was used to test H10 hypothesis.
(a) Stability measured if the coopetitive relation is stable (established on a determined or undetermined period). According to our research, 24.61% of the respondents are involved in determined term relations while 39% in undetermined term relations.
(b) Performance measured overall perception of the respondents about coopetitive relations. In our study, Performance is highly correlated with Benefits (0.697, p < 0.001) (Table 13). Duysters and Man [86] achieved similar results in their empiric study about the strategic alliances.
In this case, we tested H10 hypothesis and used a linear regressive model (Table 14). Results indicates that Hypothesis H10 was confirmed (R² = 0.299, p < 0.05).
Stability related coefficient is negative because the variable is encoded 0 for undetermined and 1 for determined. Hence, if the value decreased, Performance related coefficient increased accordingly. Coopetitive tension is inversely proportional with Performance, as we demonstrated earlier and is positive correlated with Stability (0.241, p < 0.05) (Table 15 and Table 16). Fang et al. [7] have tested the correlation between cooperation and financial performance and also achieved a positive relation.

5. Conclusions

This study makes important contributions in terms of coopetition between companies in oil and gas distribution. In our opinion, coopetition as a new paradigm of organizational cooperation has reached a critical level necessary for shaping it as a distinct subject of research for scholars and practitioners from various industries, and oil and gas is no different. Even though the conceptualization of coopetition is still underway, empirical studies has to be done to better understand coopetition specifics.
Considering our study results, rejection of H1 hypothesis means that a company may engage in a limited number of coopetitive relations without fear of being less effective and, as such, cooperation with a high number of partners does not constitute a prerequisite to achieve better results or improved performance. A balanced approach in choosing partners and areas for cooperation, is desirable [88].
Confirmation of H2 hypothesis brings forward the reasons behind decision to engage in a coopetitive relation. Surveyed companies seek Procurement and Know-how instead of Resource sharing or Operations, a sign of a more strategic than operational approach. This concur the findings of other studies addressing knowledge and resource in energy sector [89], and may concur to innovation [90] or open innovation [91], particularly in networks.
Partial confirmation of H3 hypothesis means that companies have to be prepared to make use of coopetitive relations by creating distinct, formal structures to manage them, especially when dealing with a large number of partners. However, we do not find evidence an impact of the structure of overall coopetitive relations on performance.
Confirmation of H4 hypothesis means that most surveyed companies do not value formalism, choosing to trust their partners. As such, they neglect contractual agreements for loosely, informal cooperation based on mutual trust.
Confirmation of H5 and HG hypotheses links benefits with competition and cooperation. When companies are competing each other, the eventual cooperation for specific objectives seems less desirable, perhaps due to a concurrent lack of trust. Even though they cooperate, decision makers carefully assess their own-benefits and compare them to competitor’s results. This led to an equilibrium between cooperation and competitive dimensions, enabling performance to be maximized.
Confirmation of Hypotheses H7, H8 and H9 brings forward the understanding of coopetitive tension and opportunism on coopetitive on performance. In terms of coopetitive tension, this study provide similar results with other studies [7,87]. Hence, coopetitive tension is inversely proportional to performance, while trust is inversely proportional to coopetitive tension. Similarly, high levels of opportunism corresponds to a high coopetitive tension. Coupled with previous results, it show that benefits are maximized when cooperation and competition are balanced doubled by low levels of tension and opportunism.
Finally, confirmation of Hypothesis H10, stability (long terms vs short term relations) is very important for overall coopetitive relations performance, with determined term relations having higher levels of coopetitive tension and lower level of performance than undetermined ones.
In conclusion, our results confirmed other studies for most of the factor analyzed. This represents a proof of increasingly cooperative behaviors among companies in oil and gas distribution as a practical way to maximize performance and benefits not necessary from interactions with traditional partners, but also with competitors.
In terms of limitations, our study does consider the traditional benefits, like economic and organizational [92], while neglecting sustainable benefits, determined by ecological responsibility [93] or use of new IT&C technologies in fostering cooperation [94].

Author Contributions

S.I.C., E.G.C. and L.B.V. designed the study. S.I.C., E.G.C., M.O. and L.B.V. conducted the literature review. S.I.C., E.G.C. and L.B.V. developed the questionnaire and analyzed the data. S.I.C., E.G.C., M.O. and L.B.V. interpreted the results. S.I.C., E.G.C. and L.B.V. wrote the paper, with M.O. providing critical assessment. All authors revised the manuscript for intellectual content. All authors have read and approved the final manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Gnyawali, D.R.; He, J.; Madhavan, R. Co-Opetition: Promises and Challenges. In Encyclopedia of 21st Century Management; Wenkel, C., Ed.; SAGE Publications: Thousands Oaks, CA, USA, 2008; Chapter 38; pp. 386–398. [Google Scholar]
  2. Ghobadi, S.; D’Ambra, J. Coopetitive relationships in cross-functional software development teams: How to model and measure? J. Syst. Softw. 2012, 85, 1096–1104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bengtsson, M.; Kock, S. “Coopetition” in business networks-To cooperate and compete simultaneously. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2000, 29, 411–426. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Lado, A.A.; Boyd, N.G.; Hanlon, S.C. Competition, cooperation, and the search for economic rents: A syncretic model. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1997, 22, 110–141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Padula, G.; Dagnino, G.B. Untangling the rise of coopetition: The intrusion of competition in a cooperative game structure. Int. Stud. Manag. Organ. 2007, 37, 32–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Das, T.K.; Teng, B.S. Instabilities of strategic alliances: An internal tensions perspective. Organ. Sci. 2000, 11, 77–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Fang, S.R.; Chang, Y.S.; Peng, Y.C. Dark side of relationships: A tensions-based view. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2011, 40, 774–784. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Lunnan, R.; Haugland, S. Predicting and measuring alliance performance: A multidimensional analysis. Strateg. Manag. J. 2008, 29, 545–556. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Park, S.H.; Ungson, G.R. Interfirm rivalry and managerial complexity: A conceptual framework of alliance failure. Organ. Sci. 2001, 12, 37–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Gnyawali, D.R.; Madhavan, R.M.; He, J.; Bengtsson, M. Contradictions, Dualities and Tensions in Cooperation and Competition: A Capability Based Framework. In Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the Academy of Management, Boston, MA, USA, 5 August 2012. [Google Scholar]
  11. Gnyawali, D.R.; Park, B.J.R. Co-opetition between giants: Collaboration with competitors for technological innovation. Res. Policy 2011, 40, 650–663. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Raza-Ullah, T.; Bengtsson, M.; Kock, S. The coopetition paradox and tension in coopetition at multiple levels. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2014, 43, 189–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Park, B.J.R.; Srivastava, M.K.; Gnyawali, D.R. Walking the tight rope of coopetition: Impact of competition and cooperation intensities and balance on firm innovation performance. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2014, 43, 210–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Bengtsson, M.; Eriksson, J.; Wincent, J. Co-opetition dynamics—An outline for further inquiry. Compet. Rev. 2010, 20, 194–214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Garud, R.; Kumaraswamy, A. Technological and organizational designs for realizing economies of substitution. Strateg. Manag. J. 1995, 16, 93–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Mariani, M.M. Coopetition as an emergent strategy: Empirical evidence from an Italian consortium of opera houses. Int. Stud. Manag. Organ. 2007, 37, 97–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Wu, Z.; Choi, T.Y.; Rungtusanatham, M.J. Supplier–supplier relationships in buyer–supplier–supplier triads: Implications for supplier performance. J. Oper. Manag. 2010, 28, 115–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Fernandez, A.S.; Le Roy, F.; Gnyawali, D.R. Sources and management of tension in co-opetition case evidence from telecommunications satellites manufacturing in Europe. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2014, 43, 222–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Bengtsson, M.; Johansson, M.; Näsholm, M.; Raza-Ullah, T. A systematic review of coopetition: Levels and effects on different levels. In Proceedings of the 13th EURAM Conference, Istanbul, Turkey, 26–29 June 2013. [Google Scholar]
  20. Gnyawali, D.R.; Madhavan, R. Cooperative Networks and Competitive Dynamics: A Structural Embeddedness Perspective. Acad. Manag. Rev. 2001, 26, 431–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Luo, Y. Toward coopetition within a multinational enterprise: A perspective from foreign subsidiaries. J. World Bus. 2005, 40, 71–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Song, D.; Lee, E.-S. Coopetitive networks, knowledge acquisition and maritime logistics value. Int. J. Logist. Res. Appl. 2012, 15, 15–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Peng, T.-J.A.; Bourne, M. The coexistence of competition and cooperation between networks: Implications from two Taiwanese healthcare networks. Br. J. Manag. 2009, 20, 377–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Das, T.K.; Teng, B.S. A resource-based theory of strategic alliances. J. Manag. 2000, 26, 31–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Dyer, J.H.; Singh, H. The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1998, 23, 660–679. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Child, J.; Faulkner, D.; Tallman, S. Cooperative Strategy: Managing Alliances, Networks, and Joint Ventures; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  27. Chen, M.J. Reconceptualizing the Competition-Cooperation Relationship: A Transparadox Perspective. J. Manag. Inquiry 2008, 17, 288–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Luo, Y. A Coopetition Perspective of Global Competition. J. World Bus. 2007, 42, 129–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Park, B.J.; Srivastava, M.K.; Gnyawali, D.R. Impact of coopetition in the alliance portfolio and coopetition experience on firm innovation. Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag. 2014, 26, 893–907. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Brandenburger, A.M.; Nalebuff, B.J. Co-Opetition; Doubleday: New York, NY, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  31. Levy, M.; Loebbecke, C.; Powell, P. SMEs, Co-opetition and Knowledge Sharing: The Role of Information. Eur. J. Inf. Syst. 2003, 12, 3–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Ritala, P.; Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, P. What’s in it for me? Creating and appropriating value in innovation-related coopetition. Technovation 2009, 29, 819–828. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Bengtsson, M.; Kock, S. Cooperation and competition in relationships between competitors in business networks. J. Bus. Ind. Mark. 1999, 14, 178–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Clarke-Hill, C.; Li, H.; Davies, B. The paradox of co-operation and competition in strategic alliances: Towards a multi-paradigm approach. Manag. Res. News 2003, 26, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Chen, M.J. Competitor analysis and interfirm rivalry: Toward a theoretical integration. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1996, 21, 100–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Emden, Z.; Calantone, R.J.; Droge, C. Collaborating for new product development: Selecting the partner with maximum potential to create value. J. Prod. Innov. Manag. 2006, 23, 330–341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Powell, W.W.; Koput, K.W.; Smith-Doerr, L. Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation: Networks of learning in biotechnology. Adm. Sci. Q. 1996, 41, 116–141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Poulsen, M.-B.J. Competition and cooperation: What roles in scientific dynamics? Int. J. Technol. Manag. 2001, 22, 782–793. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Baruch, Y.; Lin, C.-P. All for one, one for all: Coopetition and virtual team performance. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2012, 79, 1155–1168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Enberg, C. Enabling knowledge integration in coopetitive R&D projects-The management of conflicting logics. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2012, 30, 771–780. [Google Scholar]
  41. Tsai, W. Social structure of “coopetition” within a multiunit organization: Coordination, competition, and intraorganizational knowledge sharing. Organ. Sci. 2002, 13, 179–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Huang, K.F.; Yu, C.M.J. The effect of competitive and non-competitive R&D collaboration on firm innovation. J. Technol. Transf. 2011, 36, 383–403. [Google Scholar]
  43. Zhang, H.S.; Shu, C.L.; Jiang, X.; Malter, A.J. Managing knowledge for innovation: The role of cooperation, competition, and alliance nationality. J. Int. Mark. 2010, 18, 74–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Li, Y.A.; Liu, Y.; Liu, H. Co-opetition, distributor’s entrepreneurial orientation and manufacturer’s knowledge acquisition: Evidence from China. J. Oper. Manag. 2011, 29, 128–142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Solitander, M. When Sharing Becomes a Liability: An Intellectual Capital Approach to Describing the Dichotomy of Knowledge Protection versus Sharing in Intra—And Interorganizational Relationships; Economics and Society, Hanken School of Economics: Helsinki, Finland, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  46. Wan Ahmad, W.N.K.; Rezaei, J.; Tavasszy, L.A.; de Brito, M.P. Commitment to and preparedness for sustainable supply chain management in the oil and gas industry. J. Environ. Manag. 2016, 180, 202–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  47. White, M.A. Sustainability: I know it when I see it. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 86, 213–217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Carter, C.R.; Rogers, D.S. A framework of sustainable supply chain management: Moving toward new theory. Int. J. Phys. Distrib. Logist. Manag. 2008, 38, 360–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Pagell, M.; Wu, Z. Building a more complete theory of sustainable supply chain management using case studies of 10 exemplars. J. Supply Chain Manag. 2009, 45, 37–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Seuring, S.; Müller, M. From a literature review to a conceptual framework for sustainable supply chain management. J. Clean. Prod. 2008, 16, 1699–1710. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Srivastava, S.K. Green supply chain management: A state of the art literature review. Int. J. Manag. Rev. 2007, 9, 53–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Midttun, A.; Dirdal, T.; Gautesen, K.; Omland, T.; Wenstøp, S. Integrating corporate social responsibility and other strategic foci in a distributed production system: A transaction cost perspective on the North Sea offshore petroleum industry. Corp. Gov. 2007, 7, 194–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Wagner, J.; Armstrong, K. Managing environmental and social risks in international oil and gas projects: Perspectives on compliance. J. World Energy Law Bus. 2010, 3, 140–165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Thurner, T.; Proskuryakova, L.N. Out of the cold—The rising importance of environmental management in the corporate governance of Russian oil and gas producers. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2014, 23, 318–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Tesfay, Y.Y. Environmentally friendly cost efficient and effective sea transport outsourcing strategy: The case of Statoil. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2014, 31, 135–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Harms, D.; Hansen, E.G.; Schaltegger, S. Strategies in sustainable supply chain management: An empirical investigation of large German companies. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2013, 20, 205–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Walker, H.; Jones, N. Sustainable supply chain management across the UK private sector. Supply Chain Manag. Int. J. 2012, 17, 15–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Zhu, Q.; Sarkis, J.; Geng, Y. Green supply chain management in China: Pressures, practices and performance. Int. J. Oper. Prod. Manag. 2005, 25, 449–468. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Paulraj, A. Understanding the relationships between internal resources and capabilities, sustainable supply management and organizational sustainability. J. Supply Chain Manag. 2011, 47, 19–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Seuring, S.; Müller, M. Core issues in sustainable supply chain management—A Delphi study. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2008, 17, 455–466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Frankel, R.; Mollenkopf, D.A. Cross-functional integration revisited: Exploring the conceptual elephant. J. Bus. Logist. 2015, 36, 18–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Wittstruck, D.; Teuteberg, F. Understanding the success factors of sustainable supply chain management: Empirical evidence from the electrics and electronics industry. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2012, 19, 141–158. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Wu, Z.; Pagell, M. Balancing priorities: Decision-making in sustainable supply chain management. J. Oper. Manag. 2011, 29, 577–590. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Campbell, J.L. Why would corporations behave in socially responsible ways? An institutional theory of corporate social responsibility. Acad. Manag. Rev. 2007, 32, 946–967. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Beske, P.; Seuring, S. Putting sustainability into supply chain management. Supply Chain Manag. Int. J. 2014, 19, 322–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Chang, B.Y.; Kenzhekhanuly, Y.; Park, B. A study on determinants of green supply chain management practice. Int. J. Control Autom. 2013, 6, 199–208. [Google Scholar]
  67. Gold, S.; Seuring, S.; Beske, P. Sustainable supply chain management and inter-organizational resources: A literature review. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2010, 17, 230–245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Gong, Y.; Shenkar, O.; Luo, Y.; Nyaw, M.-K. Do multiple parents help or hinder international joint venture performance? The mediating roles of contract completeness and partner cooperation. Strateg. Manag. J. 2007, 28, 1021–1034. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Dowling, M.J.; Roering, W.D.; Carlin, B.A.; Wisnieski, J. Multifaceted relationships under coopetition. J. Manag. Inq. 1996, 5, 155–167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Ritala, P.; Hallikas, J.; Sissonen, H. The effect of strategic alliances between key competitors on firm performance. Manag. Res. 2008, 6, 179–187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Gray, B. Conditions Facilitating Interorganizational Collaboration. Hum. Relat. 1985, 38, 911–936. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Khanna, T.; Gulati, R.; Nohria, N. The dynamics of learning alliances: Competition, cooperation, and relative scope. Strateg. Manag. J. 1998, 19, 193–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Schmoltzi, C.; Wallenburg, C.M. Horizontal cooperations between logistics service providers: Motives, structure, performance. Int. J. Phys. Distrib. Logist. Manag. 2011, 41, 552–575. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Park, S.H.; Russo, M.V. When competition eclipses cooperation: An event history analysis of joint venture failure. Manag. Sci. 1996, 42, 875–890. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Anand, B.N.; Khanna, T. Do firms learn to create value? The case of alliances. Strateg. Manag. J. 2000, 21, 295–316. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Kumar, M.V.S. Are joint ventures positive sum games? The relative effects of cooperative and noncooperative behavior. Strateg. Manag. J. 2010, 32, 32–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Näsholm, H.M.; Bengtsson, M. A conceptual model of individual identifications in the context of coopetition. Int. J. Bus. Environ. 2013, 6, 11–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Perks, H. Marketing information exchange mechanisms in collaborative new product development—The influence of resource balance and competitiveness. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2000, 29, 179–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Oliver, A.L. On the duality of competition and collaboration: Network-based knowledge relations in the biotechnology industry. Scand. J. Manag. 2004, 20, 151–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Chin, K.S.; Chan, B.L.; Lam, P.K. Identifying and prioritizing critical success factors for coopetition strategy. Ind. Manag. Data Syst. 2008, 108, 437–454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Bengtsson, M.; Eriksson, J.; Wincent, J. Co-opetition: New ideas for a new paradigm. In Coopetition Winning Strategies for the 21st Century; Yami, S., Castaldo, S., Le Roy, F., Eds.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2010; pp. 19–39. [Google Scholar]
  82. Tidström, A.; Hagberg-Andersson, A. Critical events in time and space when cooperation turns into competition in business relationships. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2012, 41, 333–343. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Kale, P.; Dyer, J.H.; Singh, H. Alliance capability, stock market response, and long-term alliance success: The role of the alliance function. Strateg. Manag. J. 2002, 23, 747–767. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Yamakawa, Y.; Yang, H.; Lin, Z. Exploration versus exploitation in alliance portfolio: Performance implications of organizational, strategic and environmental fit. J. Res. Policy 2011, 40, 287–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Lado, A.A.; Boyd, N.G.; Wright, P.; Kroll, M. Paradox and theorizing within the resource-based view. Acad. Manag. Rev. 2006, 31, 115–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. de Man, A.-P.; Duysters, G. Collaboration and innovation: A review of the effects of mergers, acquisitions and alliances on innovation. Technovation 2005, 25, 1377–1387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Gnyawali, D.R.; Park, B.J.R. Co-opetition and Technological Innovation in Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises: A Multilevel Conceptual Model. J. Small Busi. Manag. 2009, 47, 308–330. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Cerqueti, R.; Fanelli, V.; Rotundo, G. Long Run Analysis of Crude Oil Portfolios. Energy Econ. 2018, in press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Ceptureanu, E.G.; Ceptureanu, S.I.; Popescu, D.I.; Vlad, L.B. Two Stage Analysis of Successful Change Implementation of Knowledge Management Strategies in Energy Companies from Romania. Energies 2017, 10, 1965. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Ausloos, M.; Bartolacci, F.; Castellano, N.G.; Cerqueti, R. Exploring how innovation strategies at time of crisis influence performance: A cluster analysis perspective. Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag. 2018, 30, 484–497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Olaru, M.; Dinu, V.; Keppler, T.; Mocan, B.; Mateiu, A. Study on the Open Innovation Practices in Romanian SMEs. Amfiteatru Econ. 2015, 17, 1129–1141. [Google Scholar]
  92. Dragan, I.-M.; Isaic-Maniu, A. An Alternative for Indicators that Characterize the Structure of Economic Systems. Entropy 2017, 19, 346. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Radulescu, D.M.; Radulescu, V. Ecological responsibility—Part of sustainable development. Int. J. Acad. Res. Econ. Manag. Sci. 2012, 1, 89–96. [Google Scholar]
  94. Martin, F.M.; Ciovica, L.; Cristescu, M.P. Implication of Human Capital in the Development of SMEs through the ICT Adoption. Procedia Econ. Financ. 2013, 6, 748–753. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Sample structure.
Table 1. Sample structure.
Surveyed CompaniesShare in the SampleSurveyed RespondentsShare in the Sample
Company sizeMicro (<10)5.19%Respondent position in the companyPresident5.19%
Small (10–49)38.31%Executive74.03%
Medium (50–249)56.49%Board member20.78%
Company age<10 years4.55%Respondent educationISCED 4 or less0.00%
ISCED 5 and 669.48%
10–15 years41.56%ISCED 7 or more30.52%
>15 years old53.90%Respondent age<35 years old7.14%
Development RegionSouth-East and South33.12%35–50 years old63.64%
South-West and West20.78%>50 years old29.22%
Bucharest–Ilfov30.52%
North-East and North-West11.03%
Table 2. Conceptual model.
Table 2. Conceptual model.
VariableDescriptionMeasurement Scale
Intensity factors
Number of partnersNumber of companies with whom the company has established relations, regardless if cooperative or competitive.Four intervals were defined: 1–3 partners, 3–10, 10–25 and more than 25 partners.
BehaviorThe behavior of the surveyed company in the relation with others (both partners and competitors)Two variables were defined: Proactive and Reactive. Binary type (0-No, 1-Yes)
CompetitorsNumber of companies which were considered direct or indirect competitors.Two variables were defined: Direct competitors and Indirect competitors. Binary type (0-No, 1-Yes)
Number of competitorsNumber of companies which were considered direct or indirect competitors.Four intervals were defined: 1–3, 3–5, 5–10 and above 10 organizations.
Functionality factors
Value creationDescribes where coopetitive interaction is taking place in terms of value creation (value chain)Possible values are: know-how transfer, resource sharing, operations, procurement, sales. Binary type (0-No, 1-Yes)
InitiatorDescribes the initiator of the coopetitive relationTwo variables were defined: surveyed company or competitor. Binary type (0-No, 1-Yes)
ObjectivesDescribes the expected objectives to be achieved in the coopetitive relationPossible values are: New services (provide new services), New markets (access new markets), Knowledge (access new knowledge from partners), Resources (access additional resources), Other (other objectives). Binary type (0-No, 1-Yes)
StructureMeasures the existence or not of a formal structure, responsible for coordination of coopetitive relationBinary type variable (0-No, 1-Yes)
Formalism factors
ContractAnalyses the relation from a formal point of view, if there was any written contract/ arrangement between companiesBinary type variable (0-No, 1-Yes)
TrustSeek to identify the opinion of the respondents about the relative importance of the contract in comparison with the trust in partnerBinary type variable (0-No, 1-Yes)
Trust evolutionDescribes the evolution of trust between the partners after the start of the coopetitive relationThere were three possible answers: 1- Decreased, 2- Similar and 3- Increased
Benefits factors
BenefitsDescribes the respondents’ perception about surveyed company benefits from coopetitive relationPossible values: 1-Negative impact, 2-No impact, 3-Positive impact
Competitor benefitsMeasures the perception of the respondents about the competitor’s benefits achieved by coopetitive relationPossible values: 1-Negative impact, 2-No impact, 3-Positive impact
Benefits distributionMeasures the perception of the respondents about the distribution of mutual benefits.Possible values: 1- More favorable for competitor, 2- Even distributed, 3- More favorable for surveyed company
Tension factors
Coopetitive tensionMeasures level of tension during coopetitive relationLikert scale from 1-Non-existent to 5-Very high
OpportunismDescribes the perceived risk of the opportunistic behavior from the partnerBinary Variable (0-No, 1-Yes)
Stability factors
StabilityMeasures if the coopetitive relation is established on a determined or undetermined periodBinary variable (0-Undetermined; 1-Determined)
PerformanceDescribes overall perception of the respondents about the coopetitive relationPossible values: 1-Negative impact, 2-No impact, 3-Positive impact
Future cooperationDescribes the willingness of the respondents to be engaged in similar relations in the future.Three binary variables were considered: Yes, No, Undecided.
Table 3. Common variation analysis.
Table 3. Common variation analysis.
Initial EigenvaluesExtraction Sums of Squared Loadings
ComponentTotal% of VarianceCumulative %Total% of VarianceCumulative %
16.70214.25914.2596.70214.25914.259
24.2719.08623.3454.2719.08623.345
34.0788.67632.0214.0788.67632.021
43.1376.67438.6953.1376.67438.695
52.3875.07943.774---
62.2144.71148.485---
72.0454.35152.837---
81.9514.15056.987---
91.7073.63260.619---
101.6703.55264.171---
111.5483.29367.464---
121.5373.27170.735---
131.3822.94073.675---
141.2202.59676.271---
151.0482.23078.501---
160.9762.07680.577---
170.8911.89782.474---
180.8371.78084.254---
190.7401.57585.829---
200.6701.42587.254---
Extraction method: Principal Component Analysis.
Table 4. Competitors and partners.
Table 4. Competitors and partners.
Number of PartnersNumber of Competitors Cross Tabulation
Number of CompetitorsTotal
1–33–1010–25>25
Number of partners1–32420026
3–1026164248
10–25101210436
>2561082044
Total66402226154
Table 5. Correlation between Number of coopetitive relations and Benefits.
Table 5. Correlation between Number of coopetitive relations and Benefits.
Number of Coopetitive RelationsBenefits
Kendall’s tau_bNumber of coopetitive relationsCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.154
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.131
N154154
BenefitsCorrelation Coefficient0.1541.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.131-
N154154
Spearman’s rhoNumber of coopetitive relationsCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.175
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.128
N154154
BenefitsCorrelation Coefficient0.1751.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.128-
N154154
Table 6. Benefits median.
Table 6. Benefits median.
Level of Value CreationMeanNStd. Deviation
Know-how1.863440.710
Resources1.565460.506
Operations1.400100.547
Procurement2.000120.632
Sales1.619420.669
Total1.6881540.633
Table 7. Correlation between Structure and Number of coopetitive relations.
Table 7. Correlation between Structure and Number of coopetitive relations.
StructureNumber of Coopetitive Relations
Kendall’s tau_bStructureCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.215 *
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.040
N154154
Number of coopetitive relationsCorrelation Coefficient0.215 *1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.040-
N154154
Spearman’s rhoStructureCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.235 *
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.040
N154154
Number of coopetitive relationsCorrelation Coefficient0.235 *1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.040-
N154154
* Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).
Table 8. Benefits (Contract vs. Trust).
Table 8. Benefits (Contract vs. Trust).
ContractTrust
MeanNStd. DeviationMeanNStd. Deviation
No1.880500.6001.583960.646
Yes1.5961040.6341.862580.580
Total1.6881540.6331.6881540.633
Table 9. Benefits-Competitor benefits correlations.
Table 9. Benefits-Competitor benefits correlations.
BenefitsCompetitor Benefits
Kendall’s tau_bBenefitsCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.447 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.000
N154154
Competitor benefitsCorrelation Coefficient0.447 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.000-
N154154
Spearman’s rhoBenefitsCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.422 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.000
N154154
Competitor benefitsCorrelation Coefficient0.422 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.000-
N154154
** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Table 10. Benefits—Coopetitive tension correlations.
Table 10. Benefits—Coopetitive tension correlations.
BenefitsCoopetitive Tension
Kendall’s tau_bBenefitsCorrelation Coefficient1.000−0.435 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.000
N154154
Coopetitive tensionCorrelation Coefficient−0.435 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.000-
N154154
Spearman’s rhoBenefitsCorrelation Coefficient1.000−0.490 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.000
N154154
Coopetitive tensionCorrelation Coefficient−0.490 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.000-
N154154
** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Table 11. Coopetitive tension-Trust evolution correlations
Table 11. Coopetitive tension-Trust evolution correlations
Coopetitive TensionTrust Evolution
Kendall’s tau_bCoopetitive tensionCorrelation Coefficient1.000−0.261 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.008
N154154
Trust evolutionCorrelation Coefficient−0.261 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.008-
N154154
Spearman’s rhoCoopetitive tensionCorrelation Coefficient1.000−0.306 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.007
N15477
Trust evolutionCorrelation Coefficient−0.306 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.007-
N154154
** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Table 12. Coopetitive tension–Opportunism correlations.
Table 12. Coopetitive tension–Opportunism correlations.
Coopetitive TensionOpportunism
Kendall’s tau_bCoopetitive tensionCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.266 *
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.010
N154154
OpportunismCorrelation Coefficient0.266 *1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.010-
N154154
Spearman’s rhoCoopetitive tensionCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.294 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.009
N154154
OpportunismCorrelation Coefficient0.294 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.009-
N154154
* Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed). ** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Table 13. Correlation between Benefits and Performance.
Table 13. Correlation between Benefits and Performance.
PerformanceBenefits
Kendall’s tau_bPerformanceCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.697 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.000
N154154
BenefitsCorrelation Coefficient0.697 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0-
N154154
Spearman’s rhoPerformanceCorrelation Coefficient1.0000.718 **
Sig. (2-tailed)-0.000
N154154
BenefitsCorrelation Coefficient0.718 **1.000
Sig. (2-tailed)0.000-
N154154
** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).
Table 14. The influence of Stability and Coopetitive tension on Performance.
Table 14. The influence of Stability and Coopetitive tension on Performance.
Model Summary
ModelRR SquareAdjusted R SquareStd. Error
10.547 a0.2990.2800.5636
a Predictors: (Constant), Coopetitive tension, Stability.
Table 15. ANOVA test results.
Table 15. ANOVA test results.
ANOVA a
ModelSum of SquaresdfMean SquareFSig.
1Regression10.02625.01315.7810.000 b
Residual23.507740.318--
Total33.35276---
a Dependent Variable: Benefits. b Predictors: (Constant), Coopetitive tension, Stability.
Table 16. Final results.
Table 16. Final results.
Coefficients a
ModelUnstandardized CoefficientsStandardized Coefficients1Sig.
BStd. ErrorBeta
1 (Constant)3.5330.172-20.5940.000
Stability−0.3260.136−0.241−2.4050.019
Coopetitive tension−0.2500.057−0.437−4.3690.000
a Dependent Variable: Benefits.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Ceptureanu, S.I.; Ceptureanu, E.G.; Olaru, M.; Vlad, L.B. An Exploratory Study on Coopetitive Behavior in Oil and Gas Distribution. Energies 2018, 11, 1234. https://doi.org/10.3390/en11051234

AMA Style

Ceptureanu SI, Ceptureanu EG, Olaru M, Vlad LB. An Exploratory Study on Coopetitive Behavior in Oil and Gas Distribution. Energies. 2018; 11(5):1234. https://doi.org/10.3390/en11051234

Chicago/Turabian Style

Ceptureanu, Sebastian Ion, Eduard Gabriel Ceptureanu, Marieta Olaru, and Liviu Bogdan Vlad. 2018. "An Exploratory Study on Coopetitive Behavior in Oil and Gas Distribution" Energies 11, no. 5: 1234. https://doi.org/10.3390/en11051234

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop