Next Article in Journal
The COVID-19 Health Crisis and Its Impact on China’s International Relations
Previous Article in Journal
Housing Real Estate Economics and Finance
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Do Post-Corona European Economic Policies Lift Growth Prospects? Exploring an ML-Methodology

1
Economics Department, ESB Business School, Reutlingen University, 72762 Reutlingen, Germany
2
Reutlingen Research Institute (RRI), 72762 Reutlingen, Germany
3
Institute of Finance and Economics (IFE), Reutlingen University, 72762 Reutlingen, Germany
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2022, 15(3), 120; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15030120
Submission received: 26 January 2022 / Revised: 15 February 2022 / Accepted: 1 March 2022 / Published: 4 March 2022
(This article belongs to the Section Applied Economics and Finance)

Abstract

:
This article explores the determinants of people’s growth prospects in survey data as well as the impact of the European recovery fund to future growth. The focus is on the aftermath of the Corona pandemic, which is a natural limit to the sample size. We use Eurobarometer survey data and macroeconomic variables, such as GDP, unemployment, public deficit, inflation, bond yields, and fiscal spending data. We estimate a variety of panel regression models and develop a new simulation-regression methodology due to limitation of the sample size. We find the major determinant of people’s growth prospect is domestic GDP per capita, while European fiscal aid does not significantly matter. In addition, we exhibit with the simulation-regression method novel scientific insights, significant outcomes, and a policy conclusion alike.
JEL Classification:
F43; F45; F47; O47

1. Introduction

The father of growth theory, Nobel laureate Robert Solow, concluded in a paper in year 2000: “Most of today’s more heated macroeconomic controversies relate to the shorter time scale relevant for business cycle fluctuations” (Solow 2000). Indeed, short-term output fluctuations are mainly driven by monetary and fiscal policy (Sato 1963). Yet, in the long-term, monetary and fiscal policy are neutral to output. There is magical evidence that growth determinants matter in the long-term alone (Acemoglu et al. 2018; Barro 1990; Mankiw et al. 1992; Solow 2003).
In this paper, we explore the impact of the Corona pandemic to output and the people’s prospects to economic growth. On the one hand, the output dynamic is determined by short-term policies, such as the domestic fiscal stimulus packages, particularly the EU recovery fund of 750bn Euro implemented by the European Union (EU) in 2020. On the other hand, the long-term growth trend is determined by slowly moving macroeconomic variables, such as R&D, investment in infrastructure and education as well as structural reforms (Twionburyo and Odhiambo 2018). In contrast to fiscal and monetary data, the data of long-term growth determinants is not available within a short time period. We intend to resolve this data mismatch by utilizing large household survey data across all EU Member States together with a simulation-regression methodology.
In the work mentioned above (Solow 2000, pp. 152f., 157f.), the authors argue that expectations in medium-run macro theory are key even if we do not understand it sufficiently well. We utilize Eurobarometer survey data where people are frequently asked about their expectations of the national and European economy today and in 12 months. We conjuncture that, by responding to those survey questions, people implicitly relate short- and long-term economic policies in order to obtain a medium-term growth outlook. Indeed, the heterogeneity of survey data reveal how agents adjust their post-Corona expectations on the economic growth prospects in the EU.
Our research question is: How do growth prospects in survey data change and what is the role of short-term stimulus policies to people’s growth outlook in the EU. The Corona pandemic is an excellent study object, given the policy response in the aftermath of the Corona pandemic and the political willingness to enhance EU growth (Valaskova et al. 2021). We explore how the large-scale European fiscal stimulus, particularly the 750bn Euro recovery fund financed by EU debt, affect growth prospects. In addition, we explore how the growth prospects in the survey data vary across countries, particularly between beneficiary countries, which get more money out of the EU budget than paid-up.
We design a novel econometric approach and utilize the new computing software Julia. Indeed, Julia is faster than conventional alternatives, such as R, STATA, MATLAB or Python. We find that matching survey and macroeconomic data, the simulation regression methodology provides a new opportunity to resolve the issue of small samples. The regression reveals that the major positive determinant of people’s growth prospects are the level of GDP per capita. The major negative determinants of people’s growth assessment are the unemployment rate and the shock absorption capacities at home. Finally, we show that the role of EU institutions (e.g., stimulus policies), such as the new recovery fund have no significant impact to people’s perception in regard to growth. On the contrary, we obtain the policy conclusion that national growth policies matter, while European growth policies do not matter as much in people’s economic assessment.
The paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we review the literature. The data and methodology is explained in Section 3. In Section 4, we discuss the stylized facts of the data and illustrate the major variable from the Eurobarometer survey. Thereafter, in Section 5 we estimate different models. In addition, we develop and discuss the simulation-regression methodology in Section 5.1. This method enables a robust econometric estimation of our empirical models. Section 6 discusses the policy implications and concludes.

2. Literature Review

Research in social sciences relies heavily on data. We distinguish two different data sources in our study. On the one hand, we utilize survey data and on the other, we work with macroeconomic data.
Firstly, there exits a long literature on survey research (Check and Schutt 2012). The goal of surveys are to describe and explore human behavior (Singleton and Straits 2009). This methodology is applied in almost all social and economic fields, even in political science (Coppock and McClellan 2019).
Recently Börsch-Supan (2020a)’s study in longitudinal health surveyed the role of aging and retirement in Europe (Börsch-Supan 2020b). Even experimental studies are combined with surveys in order to find certain behaviors and the rules of decision-making (Fitzimons and Moore 2008; Spangenberg et al. 2016; Wilding et al. 2016). In addition, surveys are combined with macro data by Crossely et al. (2017). They studied saving behavior from tax records and found that respondents actually save somewhat less under the monetary regime of interest rates at the zero-lower-bound.
Secondly, the macroeconomic growth literature is particularly broad. We focus on standard macroeconomic data and follow the literature (Durlauf et al. 2008; Sala-i-Martin 1997). Recent literature by the EU-Commission (2021) estimates the growth development in the aftermath of the Corona pandemic. They claim a significant positive impact of the EU stimulus on future growth, despite not having any long-run economic data.
The combination of survey data and macroeconomic data have various benefits and challenges. The benefit is resolving new puzzles that focus on medium- to long-term economic issues. The challenges are: First, microeconomic survey’s have a large sample yet frequently a low frequency. Second, there is an ongoing debate about the accuracy of surveys of a large population (Cornesse et al. 2020). Third, the the data frequency of survey and time-series macroeconomic data do not match in general (Gelman et al. 2017). Fourth, aggregation of survey data at the country level reduces the dimensionality advantage of large surveys.
In order to tackle the challenges above, we develop a unique methodology, defined as simulation-regression. This technique does solve the frequency, aggregation and dimensionality challenge when working with both survey and macroeconomic data in a single sample. We demonstrate this novel approach by utilizing Eurobarometer data. We study a research question, which requires survey and macroeconomic data: Do macroeconomic data determine people’s growth outlook in survey data?

3. Data and Methodology

On the one hand, we utilize survey data conducted on behalf of the European Commission, the European Parliament and other EU institutions denoted as Eurobarometer. The Standard Eurobarometer is conducted twice a year and monitors the state of public opinions. It collects micro data via random face-to-face or telephone interviews across all EU countries since the 1970s. The sample consists of at least 1000 persons from large and 500 from small EU Member States. In total the sample size is at least N = 20,000 observations.
On the other hand, we utilize macroeconomic data of 27 EU Member States from Eurostat. We integrate variables, such as GDP per capita, public deficit per GDP, unemployment and inflation rate. Moreover, we design a variable ‘Recovery Fund’, which represents country specific monetary aid in billion Euro provided by the EU in the aftermath of the SARS-CoV2 pandemic. The total envelope of the Next Generation EU Fund is 750bn Euro. Finally, we create a dummy variable of the beneficiary countries, defined by obtaining more money than paid-up in the general EU budget.
In order to match survey and macro data in our econometric modelling, we utilize aggregated data on the country level. In the end, we obtain a panel of 27 EU countries across time. The regression models are as follows
Y i , t = α + β 1 G D P i , t + β 2 D e f i c i t i , t + β 3 U n e m p l o y m e n t i , t + β 4 C o n t r o l s i , t + ϵ i , t ,
where i represents the country and t time. The dependent variable Y i , t denote two metrics about the economic situation measured by Eurobarometer survey data. Furthermore, we estimate a difference-in-difference model exploring the growth rates of each variable, such as
Δ Y i , t = β 1 Δ G D P i , t + β 2 Δ D e f i c i t i , t + β 3 Δ U n e m p l o y m e n t i , t + β 4 Δ C o n t r o l s i , t + ϵ i , t .
Given the research question, we particularly compare the economic situation before the pandemic in year 2019 to the year 2020.1 In order to increase validity and significance, we need to enhance the sample size of 27 countries and the two benchmark years. Thus, we develop a novel econometric methodology defined as ‘simulation regression’.
In step I, we estimate the models above. In step II, we use the standard errors and descriptive statistics of the respective variables to simulate data with the same characteristics. We generate an enlarged sample of N = 10 6 , which is featuring our sample. The following simulation algorithm does the job:
x i , t s i m = [ x i , t + σ x randn ( n , 1 ) for n in 10 6 ] y i , t s i m = [ y i , t + σ y randn ( n , 1 ) for n in 10 6 ] ,
where σ x and σ y is computed from our data in step I. Finally, in step III, we estimate the generalized model:
Y i , t s i m = α + β X i , t s i m + ϵ i , t ,
where X i , t s i m is a matrix with all independent variables, including the controls. The β denotes the vector of all coefficients. The Julia code is available in Appendix A. This simulation regression methodology exhibit robust and significant outcomes.

4. Preliminary Insights

First, we compute the descriptive statistics of all variables in order to describe our sample (Table 1). The survey questions are summarized from Q 1 to Q 9 in Table 1. The numbers range between zero and one, where one denotes a 100 percent positive response of all agents. Thus, the mean of 0.688 demonstrates that almost 69 percent assess that the economic situation in 12 months is the same or better than today.
The macroeconomic variables are GDP, deficit ratio, inflation, unemployment, bond yields, Covid-deaths per cases, recovery aid and the EU-budget dummy, which measures countries benefiting from the annual EU budget. Note, growth determinants, such as patents or R&D are slowly moving variables and do not significantly vary over two years, which makes those data unusable at the current edge. According to the descriptive statistics in Table 1, average inflation is 2.18 percent, with a standard deviation of 1.15 and a range of [ 0.30 , 4.96 ] . The range shows that inflation rates are significantly different across countries, despite average inflation is almost following the European Central Banks (ECB) inflation target of 2.0 percent over the medium-term.
In Figure 1, we illustrate our two dependent variables in our models. Indeed, we show Y i , t across all i EU countries for Question 1 and Question 4. Some facts stand-out: (i) in the left- and right-panel of Figure 1 the economic assessment in 2020 is lower than in 2019 in general. Of course this is caused by the Corona pandemic in 2020. (ii) the median drops from m = 0.55 to m = 0.44 in the left-panel, which is more than in the right-panel. This implies that people downgrade the current economic situation far more than the economic expectations in 12 months. (iii) the range in the left panel between [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] is greater than in the right-panel of [ 0.50 , 0.85 ] . That pattern is somewhat surprising. Yet, there exists psychological and evolutionary biological evidence that human beings form more optimistic and homogenous beliefs about the future (see literature review (Hecht 2013)). Consequently, the range of the future economic prospect is narrow and more positive than the current economic evaluation.
Finally, we illustrate the histograms and kernel density estimates of our macroeconomic data in Figure A1 in Appendix B. In line with Reis (2021), we find that the kernel density of inflation in 2021 is shifting to the right and this implies the onset of a new inflationary regime. Indeed, a t-test of the ECB’s inflation target of 2.0 percent fails to reject the H0-hypothesis in 2019, while the same t-test rejects the H0-hypothesis in 2020/2021. This indicates that mean inflation of EU Member States is significantly above the ECB’s inflation target for the Eurozone of 2.0 percent—evaluated at a 5% significance level.2

5. Results

We estimate a variety of regression models with macroeconomic variables in order to determine the factors of people’s economic assessment in Eurobarometer data. Table 2 represents three models on the basis of 2019 and four models on the basis of 2020 data.
Firstly, there is robust evidence that the people’s economic assessment of Q4 is significant positively correlated with GDP per capita. The significance level is above 1% in all models. Secondly except of unemployment the other macroeconomic variables are insignificant. Surprisingly, the significant negative relation between unemployment and Q4 is weaker in the pandemic year of 2020. This indicates a relative robust labor market during the Corona pandemic; likely due to labor market programmes, such as short-time allowance. Hence, despite slightly higher unemployment in 2020, the people’s confidence in the economic situation was still good in 2020.
All F-tests of models 1 to 7 are statistically significant above 0.1%. Yet, somewhat unexpected to us is the insignificance of the Recovery Fund and Covid-Ratio variables as well as the EU-Budget dummy. This might imply that people’s economic assessment is weakly determined by EU institutions and European fiscal policies. What matters most when assessing the economic situation are GDP per capita and unemployment in the domestic economy.
Focusing on the major determinant, we re-estimate a bi-variate regression between GDP per capita and people’s economic assessment measured by Q4 in the Eurobarometer survey. Figure 2 represents a scatter and regression outcome of 2019 and 2020, including the 95% confidence intervals. Yet, the overlapping confidence intervals do not give a conclusive answer about the difference before and after the pandemic.
We exhibit that the Corona pandemic has shifted the people’s assessment of the economic situation downward (red) in general. Yet, the slope of the regression line might be the same in 2019 and 2020. Of course, a major limitation of the regression model is the sample size due to aggregation of survey and macroeconomic data. However, studying the impact on growth in the aftermath of the Corona pandemic together with the EU recovery fund, which for the first time is financed by EU debt, is automatically limiting the sample size. In order to fix this flaw, we develop a new method of a simulation-regression next.
Before exploring our simulation-regression methodology, we represent the regression results of the difference-in-difference and panel regression (Table 3). We check heteroscedasticity by the Breusch-Pagan and White-Test. Both tests do reject heteroscedasticity at 1%. Furthermore, the Hausman test does indicate fixed effects in our panel data.
The models of the difference-in-difference regression do not obtain significant results. Hence, explaining the change of the economic assessment within a survey is independent to the changes in the macroeconomic variables. Thus, people’s growth prospects in survey’s are mainly determined by stock and not by flow data. Somewhat unexpected is the EU-Budget dummy. This coefficient is significant negatively correlated to growth expectations, which means that people in beneficiary EU Member States expect weaker growth in the next 12 months. This supports our finding above that EU institutions do not affect people’s growth prospects positively, yet the impact of (democratic) institutions to growth is significant (Acemoglu et al. 2005, 2018, 2019; Evans and Ferguson 2013; Nyasha and Odhiambo 2019). What matters for people in survey’s is the domestic economic situation.
The panel regression confirms the findings of the annual regression models. In all models the following three variables are significant: GDP per capita is robustly positive, the unemployment rate and the Covid death per cases are negatively correlated to the people’s economic assessment in Question 4. All three macroeconomic variables follow the economic intuition. Of course, a higher Covid death count and unemployment rate reduce the economic outlook of the respondence. In general, the panel models are supported by high adjusted R-squared and significant F-tests.

5.1. Simulation Regression

Next, we explain the robust simulation regression methodology. We scientifically study the growth prospects of people’s in the aftermath of the Corona pandemic and the impact of the EU recovery fund financed by EU debt (Herzog 2020). This question requires an urgent assessment, yet we are in the second year of the pandemic and thus the sample size is limited.
Estimating the model with a small sample gives us basic data characteristics at first. We are going to utilize this information in the simulation regression in order to enlarge the sample. According to Equation (3) we simulate the sample and re-estimate the models by using Equation (4) (cf. Appendix A).
Let us explain the benefits by studying the bi-variate regression in Figure 2. First, we simulate the data with a new sample size of now N = 27,000. Second, we re-estimate the regression models of the annual relationship between Question4 and GDP per capita in 2019 and 2020. The results are illustrated in Figure 3.
The scatter plots represent the large sample of N = 27,000 for each year. This sample represents a situation where we have annual survey and macroeconomic data of the same size. The regression lines display the same shape as in Figure 2, yet the regressions are now strongly significant, particularly the difference across time. The 99% confidence bands are narrow and demonstrate the overwhelming regression output. We find that the people’s assessment of the growth prospects declined significantly in 2020 in comparison to 2019. Indeed, the regression line of 2020 shifted parallel downward in Figure 3. The slope of 0.002 remains significant positive at a 0.1%-level (Table 4). Yet, the intercept declined from 0.307 in 2019 to 0.214 in 2020 (Table 4). This implies that people’s prospects declined by almost 1 / 10 or 70 percent, while the economic situation measured by growth did not decline with the same degree. Thus, the people’s survey assessment of the economy is highly volatile in relation to the macroeconomic variables. Nonetheless, the macroeconomic variables, particularly GDP per capita, determine the survey outcome.
Citizens of Member States with greater GDP per capita have a higher positive response in regard to the economic prospects in general (Table 4). This is robust in all regressions and highly significant at 0.1 %. Moreover, the relationship to unemployment of 0.008 and the Covid death per cases ratio of 0.001 are strongly significant with the people’s growth assessment. We find that neither the recovery fund nor the EU-budget aid to beneficiary EU Member States affect the people’s assessment of the future economy. What matters most for people are the state of the national economy, the national unemployment rate and the national Covid performance. Consequently, people’s happiness which is highly correlated to the growth prospects would be better enhanced by structural (growth) policies at home. European growth policies are nice to have, yet do not resolve weak national growth policies in Member States.
Finally, we re-simulate the model with a sample size of N = 100,000. Figure 4 show all possible bi-variate regression models consisting of Question 4 and GDP per capita. Indeed, Figure 4 exhibits the histograms of the intercepts in the left-panel and the slopes in the right-panel. The median values reflect the estimation outcomes of Panel 1 in Table 4.
Based on this simulation, we find the standard deviation of the intercept of σ I n t e r c e p t = 0.248 . Thus, a one σ I n t e r c e p t -variation keeps the intercept positive. Similarly the standard deviation of the slope is of σ S l o p e = 0.002 . Hence, a one σ S l o p e -variation keeps the slope positive too. The likelihood that the estimated positive relationship reverses is low, given that volatility of macroeconomic variables are significantly lower than the variation in survey data.
Of course, one can argue that the simulation regression has no counterfactual analysis. Indeed, this might be a limitation. Yet, we tested the approach for a two-year window 2008 and 2009 of the global financial crisis and compared the simulation regression output with the existing long time-series of 1990 to 2020. Indeed, the simulation regression is reflecting the same properties than the long time-series pattern. In future research, we plan to validate the simulation regression methodology at different events across countries and time.

6. Conclusions

Our paper exhibits several conclusions. First, in order to match survey and macroeconomic data, the simulation regression methodology provides a novel opportunity. Indeed, this approach allows a real-time assessment of economic questions. Second, the major positive determinant of growth prospects are the level of GDP per capita, while the major negative aspects are the unemployment rate and the shock absorption capacities at home (here measured by the Covid death per cases ratio). Third, the role of EU institutions and EU policies, such as the recovery fund or the EU-budget has no significant impact on the people’s perceptions in regard to growth. Thus, we obtain the policy conclusion that domestic growth policies matter, while European growth policies do not as much. Consequently, we suggest that Member States within a monetary union without a fiscal union, have to both implement and finance economic policies primarily at home (Herzog 2018; Herzog and Hengstermann 2013; Herzog and Choi 2017). The idea of a European-state or European growth policy is misguided economically and degrades the people’s perceptions still living in democratic Member States. European growth policies would be effective if policy-makers establish a political union (Herzog 2021). Yet, this is neither realistic nor feasible in the near future.

Funding

I am grateful that the publication fee were financed by Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg, Universitätsbibliothek, Geschäftsstelle des Konsortiums Baden-Württemberg and Reutlingen University, Bibliothek, Reutlingen. I have not received further external funding for the research project.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

I thank all IRM-seminar participants for valuable comments and a thorough discussion of my paper. Moreover, I thank the university Reutlingen for giving me the opportunity of a research leave in 2021. Most of this work was conducted during the research semester in winter 2021.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Julia Code

Listing A1. Simulation Regression Code.
Listing A1. Simulation Regression Code.
// Create a variable of GDP data:
x2019 = real.(data2019.GDP)
// Simulate the data for i new sample size:
xSim19 = [x2019 .+ σ ^ G D P * randn(size(x2019)[1]) for i = 1:100,000]
// Convert simulation data to DataFrame and Matrix:
dfx19 = DataFrame(xSim19,:auto);
Ax19 = Matrix(dfx19);
// Transform matrix to single-vector:
begin
vect19 = Float64[]
      for j in 1:size(Ax19,2)
           vect19 = vcat(vect19, Ax19[:,j])
      end
end
xSim19f = vect19
// Make Dataframe for regression:
dataSimReg19 = DataFrame([ x S i m 19 f y S i m 19 1 y S i m 19 2 y S i m 19 3 ] , :auto);
// Compute the Simulation regression:
SimReg19 = reg(dataSimReg19, @formula( x 1 x 2 + x 3 + x 4 ))

Appendix B. Histogram and Kernel Density

Figure A1. Histogram and Kernel densities: Left-hand panels represent the data of 2019 for each macroeconomic variable. Right-hand panels represent the data of 2020 for each macroeconomic variable. Source: Eurostat 2021.
Figure A1. Histogram and Kernel densities: Left-hand panels represent the data of 2019 for each macroeconomic variable. Right-hand panels represent the data of 2020 for each macroeconomic variable. Source: Eurostat 2021.
Jrfm 15 00120 g0a1

Notes

1
Note: the macroeconomic data for 2021 are not available-only forecasts.
2
The evaluation of mean inflation of Eurozone countries alone is slightly above 2.0 percent.

References

  1. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005. Handbook of Economic Growth. Volume 1A, Chapter Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 385–472. [Google Scholar]
  2. Acemoglu, Daron, Suresh Naidu, Pascual Restrepo, and James A. Robinson. 2019. Democarcy does cause growth. Journal of Political Economy 127: 47–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Acemoglu, Daron, Ufuk Akcigit, Harun Alp, Nicholas Bloom, and Wiliam Kerr. 2018. Innovation, Reallocation and Growth. American Economic Review 108: 3450–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Barro, Robert J. 1990. Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. Journal of Political Economy 98: 103–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Börsch-Supan, Axel. 2020a. Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe-Wave 1. Mannheim: MEA, Version 7.1.0. [Google Scholar]
  6. Börsch-Supan, Axel. 2020b. Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe-Wave 2. Mannheim: MEA, Version 7.1.0. [Google Scholar]
  7. Check, Joseph, and Russell K. Schutt. 2012. Research Methods in Education. Chapter Survey Research. Southern Oaks: Sage Publications, pp. 159–85. [Google Scholar]
  8. Coppock, Alexander, and Oliver A. McClellan. 2019. Validating the demographic, political, pschological, and experimental results obtained from a new source of online survey respondents. Research & Politics 6: 1–14. [Google Scholar]
  9. Cornesse, Carina, Annelies G. Blom, David Dutwin, Jon A Krosnick, Edith D. De Leeuw, Stéphane Legleye, Josh Pasek, Darren Pennay, Benjamin Phillips, Joseph W Sakshaug, and et al. 2020. A review of conceptual approaches and empirical evidence on probabiltiy and nonprobability sample survey research. Journal of Survey Statistics and Methodology 8: 4–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Crossley, Thomas F., Jochem de Bresser, Liam Delaney, and Joachim Winter. 2017. Can survey participation alter household saving behaviour? Economic Journal 127: 2332–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Durlauf, Steven, Andros Kourtellos, and Chih Tan. 2008. Are any growth theories robust? Economic Journal 1118: 329–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. EU-Commission. 2021. European Economic Forecast-Winter 2021. February. Interim 144. Brussels: EU Commission. [Google Scholar]
  13. Evans, William, and Clare Ferguson. 2013. Governance, Instituions, Growth and Poverty Reduction: A Literature Review. Report. London: UK Government. [Google Scholar]
  14. Fitzimons, Gavan J., and Sarah G. Moore. 2008. Should we ask our children about sex, drugs and rock & roll? Potentially harmful effects of asking questions about risky behaviors. Journal of Consumer Psychology 18: 82–95. [Google Scholar]
  15. Gelman, Andrew, Sharad Goel, David Rothschild, and Wei Wang. 2017. Routledge Studies in Global Information, Politics and Society. Chapter High-Frequency Polling with Non-Representative Data. London: Routledge, vol. 12, pp. 89–105. [Google Scholar]
  16. Hecht, David. 2013. The neural basis of optimism and pessimism. Experimetnal Neurobiology 22: 173–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Herzog, Bodo. 2018. Monetary Unions: Background, Advantages and Disadvantages. Chapter A Monetary Union Without a Fiscal Union. Hauppauge: Nova Science Press, vol. I, pp. 99–118. [Google Scholar]
  18. Herzog, Bodo. 2020. Whither corona-bonds? The past and future of the EMU in the corona-pandemic. Intereconomics 55: 3–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Herzog, Bodo. 2021. Optimal sequencing to reform the European economic and monetary union: A roadmap. Quantitative Finance and Economics 5: 311–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Herzog, Bodo, and Katja Hengstermann. 2013. Restoring Credible Govnernance to the Eurozone. Journal of Economic Affairs 33: 2–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Herzog, Bodo, and Minjae Choi. 2017. Policy Rules in the Economic and Monetary Union. Intereconomics 52: 51–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil. 1992. A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 407–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Nyasha, Sheilla, and Nicholas M. Odhiambo. 2019. Government size and economic growth: A review of international literature. SAGE Open, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Reis, Ricardo. 2021. Losing the Inflation Anchor (October 2021). CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP16664. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3960248 (accessed on 16 January 2022).
  25. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 1997. I just run two million regressions. American Economic Review 87: 178–83. [Google Scholar]
  26. Sato, Ryuzo. 1963. Fiscal policy in a neo-classical growth model: An analysis of time required for equilibrium adjustment. Review of Economic Studies 30: 16–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Singleton, Royce A., and Bruce C. Straits. 2009. Approaches to Social Research. New York: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  28. Solow, Robert. 2000. Toward a macroeconomics of the medium run. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 151–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Solow, Robert. 2003. Reflections on growth and development. Annals of Economics and Finance 4: 219–29. [Google Scholar]
  30. Spangenberg, Eric R., Ioannis Kareklas, Berna Devezer, and David E. Sprott. 2016. A meta-analysis synthesis of the question-behavior effect. Jounral of Consumer Psychology 26: 441–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Twionburyo, Enock N., and Nicholas M. Odhiambo. 2018. Monetary policy and economic growth: A review of international literature. Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice 2: 123–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  32. Valaskova, Katarina, Pavol Durana, and Peter Adamko. 2021. Changes in consumers’ purchase patterns as a consequence of the COVID-19 pandemic. Mathematics 9: 1788. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Wilding, Sarah, Mark Conner, Tracy Sandberg, Andrew Prestwich, Rebecca Lawton, Chantelle Wood, Eleanor Miles, Gaston Godin, and Paschal Sheeran. 2016. The question-behaviour effect: A theoretical and methodological review and meta-analysis. European Review of Social Psychology 27: 196–230. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Figure 1. Peoples assessment of the economy in 2019 and 2020: In the left-hand panel, how would you judge the current economic situation. In the right-hand panel, what are your expectations for the economy in 12 months. Both panels list always the positive responses, i.e., all people responding with good, better or the same. Source: Eurobarometer-Standard 2021.
Figure 1. Peoples assessment of the economy in 2019 and 2020: In the left-hand panel, how would you judge the current economic situation. In the right-hand panel, what are your expectations for the economy in 12 months. Both panels list always the positive responses, i.e., all people responding with good, better or the same. Source: Eurobarometer-Standard 2021.
Jrfm 15 00120 g001
Figure 2. Regression Outcome. Source: author.
Figure 2. Regression Outcome. Source: author.
Jrfm 15 00120 g002
Figure 3. Simulation Regression: The blue color represents the simulation of the scatter and regression line with 99% confidence interval of the 2019 data. The red color represents the simulation of the scatter and regression line with 99% confidence interval of the 2020 data. Source: author.
Figure 3. Simulation Regression: The blue color represents the simulation of the scatter and regression line with 99% confidence interval of the 2019 data. The red color represents the simulation of the scatter and regression line with 99% confidence interval of the 2020 data. Source: author.
Jrfm 15 00120 g003
Figure 4. Simulation Regression: Left panel denotes the histogram of the intercept. Right panel denotes the histogram of the slope. Source: author.
Figure 4. Simulation Regression: Left panel denotes the histogram of the intercept. Right panel denotes the histogram of the slope. Source: author.
Jrfm 15 00120 g004
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics 2019 and 2020.
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics 2019 and 2020.
Variable NamesMeanstdminmaxq25q75
Q10.6880.0810.4800.8500.6400.745
Q20.7240.0680.6000.8890.6690.780
Q30.6850.0790.4300.8400.6400.737
Q40.4940.2530.0800.9300.2920.690
Q50.5650.1240.2900.8000.4920.650
Q60.4470.4540.0001.0000.0000.910
Q70.6480.1150.3500.8600.5720.750
Q80.6860.2040.2300.9200.5700.830
Q90.6510.0830.4200.8500.6020.707
GDP per capita101.99267.70428.200340.40054.725138.050
Deficit per GDP−3.2813.943−11.0004.100−5.7750.300
Inflation (in percent)2.1891.1570.3004.9661.3252.817
Unemployment (in percent)6.4203.2272.00017.3004.4007.400
Bond Yield (in percent)0.6251.052−0.5104.540−0.0551.022
Covid-Death/cases0.7870.9970.0004.1300.0001.431
Recovery Fund (in bn.)6.27514.6000.00069.5000.0005.975
EU-Budget (Dummy)0.6660.4750.0001.0000.0001.000
Q1: What are your expectations for the next twelve months: will the next twelve months be better, worse or the same, when it comes to economic situation in your country? Responses: Same+Better; Q2: What are your expectations for the next twelve months: will the next twelve months be better, worse or the same, when it comes to situation in general? Responses: Good; Q3: What are your expectations for the next twelve months: will the next twelve months be better, worse or the same, when it comes to economic situation in EU? Responses: Good; Q4: How would you judge the current situation in each of the following? The situation of the (NATIONALITY) economy. Responses: Good; Q5: How would you judge the current situation in each of the following? The situation of the European economy. Responses: Good; Q6: Thinking about the consequences of the coronavirus pandemic, to what extent do you agree or disagree with the following statements? The coronavirus pandemic has serious economic consequences for (OUR COUNTRY). Responses: totally agree; Q7: Could you please tell whether the term Globalization brings to mind something very positive, fairly positive, fairly negative or very negative? Responses: very+fairly positive; Q8: Please tell me whether you are for it or against it. A European economic and monetary union with one single currency, the euro. Response: for it; Q9: Would you say that you are very optimistic, fairly optimistic, fairly pessimistic or very pessimistic about the future of the EU? Responses: very+fairly optimistic. The EU-Budget dummy is 1 if the country gets more money out than paid-up.
Table 2. Regression Table of Basic Models with 2019 and 2020 data.
Table 2. Regression Table of Basic Models with 2019 and 2020 data.
Dep. Question 420192020
ModelsModel 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5Model 6Model 7
(Intercept)0.609 ***0.652 ***0.613 ***0.496 **0.669 ***0.609 **0.679 ***
(0.068)(0.095)(0.070)(0.134)(0.154)(0.173)(0.168)
GDP0.002 ***0.002 **0.002 ***0.002 ***0.002 **0.002 **0.002 *
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Deficit0.0260.0270.0250.0110.0060.0020.006
(0.015)(0.015)(0.016)(0.015)(0.015)(0.016)(0.015)
Unemployment−0.044 ***−0.044 ***−0.044 ***−0.028 *−0.031 **−0.027 *−0.031 *
(0.008)(0.008)(0.008)(0.011)(0.011)(0.012)(0.011)
EU−Budget D. −0.040 −0.013
(0.062) (0.077)
Deficit−square −0.002
(0.005)
Covid−Ratio −0.085−0.073−0.084
(0.043)(0.046)(0.044)
Recovery Fund −0.002
(0.002)
EstimatorOLSOLSOLSOLSOLSOLSOLS
N27272727272727
R 2 0.7690.7730.7700.6060.6650.6750.665
a d j . R 2 0.7390.7320.7280.5540.6040.5970.586
p ( F s i g . ) 0.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.00
Note: significance of 5% = *, 1% = **, and 0.1% = ***. Source: author.
Table 3. Regression Table of Difference-In-Difference Regression and Fixed-Effect Panel Regression.
Table 3. Regression Table of Difference-In-Difference Regression and Fixed-Effect Panel Regression.
Difference-Regression Q1Panel Regression Q4
Model 8Model 9Model 10Model 11Model 12Model 13Model 14
(Intercept)0.0830.0270.0270.552 ***
(0.089)(0.094)(0.096)(0.058)
GDP−0.0050.0000.0000.002 ***0.002 ***0.002 ***0.002 ***
(0.004)(0.005)(0.005)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Deficit0.0050.0140.0130.0110.0110.0110.011 ***
(0.011)(0.013)(0.014)(0.005)(0.010)(0.010)(0.000)
Covid-Ratio0.024 −0.073 *−0.073 *−0.073 ***
(0.023) (0.036)(0.032)(0.014)
EU-Budget D.−0.165 ***
(0.042)
Recovery 0.0020.003
(0.001)(0.002)
Interaction −0.001
(0.002)
Unemployment −0.037 ***−0.038 ***−0.038 ***−0.038 **
(0.007)(0.007)(0.005)(0.011)
Year-fixed effect---NoYesYesYes
Estimator Model-TypeOLSOLSOLSOLSFEFE+robustFE+Cluster
N27272754545454
R 2 0.4250.1470.1500.6790.7050.7050.705
a d j . R 2 0.3200.0360.0040.6590.6740.6740.681
p ( F s i g . ) ---0.0000.0000.0000.000
Note: significance of 5% = *, 1% = **, and 0.1% = ***. With robust and clusterd Variance-Covariance matrix. Source: author.
Table 4. Simulation Regression Models.
Table 4. Simulation Regression Models.
Bi-VariateMulti-Variate
Model 2019Model 2020Panel 1Panel 2
(Intercept)0.307 ***0.214 ***0.260 ***0.319 ***
(0.002)(0.002)(0.002)(0.002)
GDP0.002 ***0.002 ***0.002 ***0.002 ***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Unemployment −0.008 ***
(0.000)
Covid −0.001 ***
(0.000)
EstimatorOLSOLSOLSOLS
N27,00027,00054,00054,000
R 2 0.3210.3880.3450.392
a d j . R 2 0.3210.3880.3450.392
p ( F s i g . ) 0.0000.0000.0000.000
Note: significance of 0.1% = ***. Source: author.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Herzog, B. Do Post-Corona European Economic Policies Lift Growth Prospects? Exploring an ML-Methodology. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2022, 15, 120. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15030120

AMA Style

Herzog B. Do Post-Corona European Economic Policies Lift Growth Prospects? Exploring an ML-Methodology. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2022; 15(3):120. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15030120

Chicago/Turabian Style

Herzog, Bodo. 2022. "Do Post-Corona European Economic Policies Lift Growth Prospects? Exploring an ML-Methodology" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 15, no. 3: 120. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15030120

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop