Next Article in Journal
State Space Modeling of Event Count Time Series
Next Article in Special Issue
A Framework for Enhancing Stock Investment Performance by Predicting Important Trading Points with Return-Adaptive Piecewise Linear Representation and Batch Attention Multi-Scale Convolutional Recurrent Neural Network
Previous Article in Journal
The Information Bottleneck’s Ordinary Differential Equation: First-Order Root Tracking for the Information Bottleneck
Previous Article in Special Issue
Heterogeneous Retirement Savings Strategy Selection with Reinforcement Learning
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Perspective

An Introduction to Complex Networks in Climate Finance

by
Alexander P. Kartun-Giles
* and
Nadia Ameli
Institute for Sustainable Resources, The Bartlett School of Environment, Energy and Resources, University College London, London WC1H 0NN, UK
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Entropy 2023, 25(10), 1371; https://doi.org/10.3390/e25101371
Submission received: 10 April 2023 / Revised: 31 August 2023 / Accepted: 7 September 2023 / Published: 22 September 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Complexity in Economics and Finance: New Directions and Challenges)

Abstract

:
In this perspective, we introduce recent research into the structure and function of complex investor networks supporting sustainability efforts. Using the case of solar, wind and hydro energy technologies, this perspective explores the complexity in low-carbon finance markets, defined as markets that direct capital flows towards low-carbon technologies, using network approaches to study their structure and dynamics. Investors are modeled as nodes which form a network or higher-order network connected by edges representing projects in which joint funding or security-related insurance was provided or other investment-related interaction occurred. We review the literature on investor networks generally, particularly in the case of complex networks, and address areas where these ideas were applied in this emerging field. The complex investor dynamics which emerge from the extant funding scenarios are not well understood. These dynamics have the potential to result in interesting non-linear behaviour, growth, and decline, which can be studied, explained and controlled using the tools of network science.

1. Introduction

Financial markets are complex systems [1,2]. When it comes to the study of the financial system for climate action, meaning capital flows directed towards low-carbon interventions with direct greenhouse gas mitigation benefits, complexity is a paradigm shift. The financial system, as any other complex system, reflects the interactions and dynamics of its heterogeneous actors across the globe who have diverse investment preferences and operate in different market conditions, which collectively shape the actual flows and investments in low carbon [3,4]. Complexity is in both its composition (heterogeneous agents interacting simultaneously with each other on multiple levels, e.g., national and international) and in the diversity of emergent behaviour [5,6]. Analyses incorporating such aspects are vital for policy design to monitor and influence the way financial markets could pool long-term financial assets to boost the low-carbon transition.
Research focuses on how techniques from theoretical physics can be used to study economic systems of this type [7,8,9,10,11]. As a system of interacting human agents, economic actors form a much more sophisticated complex system than that of the interacting spins in a disordered magnetic state such as a spin glass, but the principles are the same, such as what Galton called The Law of Frequency of Error: “The huger the mob, and the greater the apparent anarchy, the more perfect is its sway” [12]. As with flocks of starlings forming a murmuration, we also have the collective behaviour of banking syndicates funding low-carbon projects, see Figure 1, and despite acting independently based on strict financial self-interest, significant emergent behaviour arises that can be understood both mathematically and economically, and for societal benefit.
Moreover, this behaviour can be universal, in that large classes of systems all with varying microscopic differences can have the same behaviour in a certain respect [10]. A famous example is in theoretical ecology, where Robert May shows how (models of) food-webs are stable (in terms of population numbers) below a universal critical interaction strength, independent of the probability distribution from which interaction strengths are drawn [13]. In recent years, however, we turn to the grandest scale, and look at how these ideas apply in real systems such as political groups, social networks, city formations, and beyond. It is the aspect of randomness emerging from deterministic laws in these systems that unites them under the theme of complexity, and it can be remarkable to see case studies of probabilistic analogies between systems usually seen in physics, and these economic systems suggest a vast amount of untapped potential in describing their behaviour.
In particular, in this article, focuses on financial flows channeled into sustainability. Actors usually form a bipartite graph of investors and projects, and the underlying dependency structure takes the form of influences between investors, and, in general, the economic agents involved. The dynamics influenced by this structure constitute syndicated investment in renewable energy. How is the structure of the economic interactions related to the investment dynamics? Is the behaviour universal across different energy markets (such as wind, solar, or hydro)? Is there any observable connection between the complexity of these economic interactions, and the rate of renewable energy investment at all? All these questions are important in climate finance, and therefore scholars turn to the theory of complex networks to help answer them.
This article is structured as follows. In Section 2, we discuss the relevant background to complex networks in climate finance, and investor networks more generally. In Section 3, we discuss empirical evidence in different climate finance scenarios and markets. Finally, in Section 4, we conclude with some take-away messages, and discuss the potential for future research development in this area.

2. Background

2.1. Econophysics and Investor Networks

Econophysics is a “revolutionary reaction” to standard economic theory that threatens to enforce a paradigm shift in thinking [14]. Usually, complex networks appear in economics within this general area. An early and highly cited example is Mantenga’s use of the graph theory to study the influence between stock prices [2]. A weighted complete graph is obtained from the matrix of correlation coefficients between stocks of a portfolio by considering the synchronous time evolution of (the difference of the logarithm of) daily stock prices. For a review of milestones and challenges in econophysics, see [15].
Within this field, complex networks are commonplace. Remco van der Hofstad writes in his recent book on complex networks that
The advent of the computer age has incited an increasing interest in the fundamental properties of real networks. Due to the increased computational power, large data sets can now easily be stored and investigated, and this has had a profound impact in the empirical studies on large networks. A striking conclusion from this empirical work is that many real networks share fascinating features.
The two primary and first-studied examples of this are the scale-free degree distribution and the small world property, known informally as six degrees of separation. This universal behaviour observed in real networks has lead to the new subject of network science [16]. As a subdiscipline of theoretical physics, network science uses techniques and ideas from statistical physics such as random graphs, stochastic processes, combinatorics, and wider mathematical ideas involving probability (as distinct from statistics), analysis (i.e., calculus) and dynamics (dynamical processes, particularly on networks [17]) to reveal the structure and function of complex systems.
A growing trend in corporate finance is to apply centrality measures to investor networks derived from various datasets. In Bajo et al. [18], the value of a firm is shown to be strongly correlated with the degree of centrality of its investors in the wider US investor network (as well as with other centrality measures, in an attempt to show the results are robust to a variety of measures). Investors are nodes, and links form between pairs of investors when they co-invest in an equity as listed in a public US equity holding database. They write:
In our sample, the information on the equity holdings by US institutional investors allows to construct a network of relations. Stemming from the simple observation that often institutional blockholders share co-ownership relationships with other institutional investors, we interpret the blockholder as actor and the co-ownership link as a tie.
The network is then the set of actors and their ties. Fracassi et al. [19] also consider centrality, showing how managers are influenced by their social peers when making corporate policy decisions, while Crane et al. [20] show how investors acting together in cliques can amplify their voice concerning how the company is run, which strengthens governance, while weakening governance via threat of exit.
In Dordi et al. [21], ten actors are identified that can accelerate the transition away from fossil fuels using a centrality analysis of shareholder data from Bloomberg, and the Carbon Underground 200 list of companies (200 companies that own 98% of global oil, gas and coal reserves). The study finds that the top ten owners of CU200 fossil fuel reserve holders are Blackrock, Vanguard, the Government of India, State Street, the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia, Dimensional Fund Advisors, Life insurance Corporation, Norges Bank, Fidelity Investments and Capital Group. Similarly, Galaz et al. [22] identify a limited set of financial actors mediating flows of capital that affect biomes of the earth.
In Dimson et al. [23], the authors study coordinated engagements by a network of shareholders cooperating to influence firms on environmental and social issues. They write in the conclusion that
Our evidence indicates that, for maximum effect, coordinated engagements on (ESG) issues should preferably have a credible lead investor who is well suited geographically, linguistically, culturally and socially to influencing target companies.
Shareholder activist networks are studied by Yang et al. [24]. Pension funds, special interest groups and religious organizations interact in a network of networks to influence corporate behaviour through the joint control of shares for what they perceive to be societal benefit. They show a correlation between both eigenvector and degree centrality, and the “efficiency of results” obtained by the activists.

2.2. Nonequilibrium Statistical Physics Meets Climate Finance

Network evolution—see, for example Figure 2—concerns a topic within network science where growing network models, known as models of “nonequilibrium statistical physics”, are used as null models of network growth. They attempt to explain, via simple combinatorial rules, the large-scale universal behaviour of real networks, including their degree distribution, clustering, homology, and anything else concerning their structure.
An early and fundamental observation in network science is the power-law degree distribution observed in many real networks (such as citation networks, social networks, the internet, world airline connection, etc). How does this appear? Even more important is observing it in the first place, by comparing real networks with a null statistical model, which in the case of Barabasi and Albert is the Erdos–Renyi random graph. The degree distribution has been known since the 1950s to follow a Poisson distribution (in the so-called thermodynamic limit where the number of nodes continues to infinity, but keeping the expected degree constrained such that it converges to a positive constant). The fact that random networks do not have power law degrees (also called a scale-free degree distribution) suggests there exist global organizing principles at play that “fatten the tail” or, more formally, skew the degree distribution.
The question in finance which has only been recently explored is how this happens in financial systems such as green bond syndication networks, or investor networks as discussed above. A simple observation is that the degree distribution, see, e.g., Figure 3, which is a the discrete probability mass function for the node degree (or, in layman’s terms, the proportion of nodes with a certain degree, plotted against the degree), has an exponent γ < 2 . An example hypergraph evolution model where banking syndicates of more than two parties can form is shown in Figure 2.
Chung et al. points out that preferential attachment models of network evolution cannot explain such a large skew [25]. Alternative suggested models involve node duplication presented by Chung et al. in their work on biological networks. The Pittman–Yor process is also a candidate which involves preferential attachment and can explain degree distributions whose exponent can be lower even than unity [25,26]. A major research question is to explain the skew we observe in the green bond syndication network of Section 3.4. This develops early research of Rickman et al. in [9] and Ameli et al. in [7] who also consider the effect of the fitness model of Bianconi–Barabasi [27] using the work of Pham et al. on attachment functions [28].

2.3. Investor Hubs Dominate the Market

The network analysis in [9] provides the first quantitative evidence of a right-skewed degree distribution. With hubs defined in this context to be vertices of G with more pairwise connections than average by one standard deviation, it is observed that “The domination of energy markets by a few organizations can be driven by large incumbents achieving cost reductions through, e.g., economies of scale, better access to finance, or vertical integration of services bringing in multiple revenue streams” ([9], Section 3.1). The authors also write that “we observe a strong positive correlation between growth of wind markets and the level of debt hub activity” ([9], Section 3.2), and discuss this in depth.

2.4. Fit Get Richer, and Rich Get Richer

In Ameli et al., the preferential attachment model is compared with the fitness model [7,27]. Instead of the standard method of considering attachment of new nodes based on the existing degree, nodes may attach to the existing lenders or sponsors based on the intrinsic fitness of nodes, as was proposed by Bianconi and Barabasi in the Bianconi–Barabasi model introduced in 2001 to develop the theory of competition and multiscaling in evolving networks [27]. Ameli et al. address this in the context of climate finance networks of energy efficiency investors.

2.5. Community Detection

Community detection is one of the largest areas of complex networks [29]. The goal is to define community in such a way that groups of financial actors are identified in a way that reveal a non-trivial structure to the larger system. Larosa et al. identify a significant home bias [30], writing “The investor community analysis reveals geographical investment patterns. In far-east Asian countries (Korea and Vietnam) the interactions between domestic investors (i.e., community density) are more frequent compared to the rest of the world. In India, the financial landscape is dominated by domestic state-owned banks, while Japan has a strong presence over the continent through the investment made by its second biggest bank, namely Sumitomo Mitsui Banking Corporation and a private utility (Kansai Electric Power Co., Inc.)... Investors mainly cluster together at national and regional level confirming the existence of a “home bias” in investments” ([8], Section 3.1).
Home bias, in layman’s terms, occurs when investors are more likely to invest in projects in their native country or region. For obvious reasons, knowledge of the local economy and the ability to predict the long-term prospects of a venture are a major advantage. The community detection of Larosa et al. is the first quantitative evidence of this effect.
Larosa et al. detail their methodology in [8], Section 2 using the Jaccard coefficient [31]. The effect is, in fact, every important for the corresponding network science. Home bias leads to local clustering and the potential emergence of network geometry, as nearby links are favored over long range links, on the whole. Longer range links exist, but they connect large hubs in a way similar to the World Airlines Network [10]. As such, it is important to askteh following question: To what extent does home bias lead to the emergent network structure in climate finance networks of this type?

2.6. Centrality Measures

Centrality is a measure of the importance of a node in a network. Important examples include betweenness centrality, where the extent to which nodes lie on multiple shortest paths in the network is considered important. PageRank, used by Google, is an example of providing centrality scores to websites containing a searchable keyword based on the extent to which random walks around the interconnected websites spend time on a particular webpage.
How do we measure centrality in climate finance networks? What makes a lender node i I or a project sponsor node s S important to the network? Larosa et al. introduce a new measure based on the number of communities an investor node takes part in. They introduce the community-based centrality score (CC), writing the following: “The CC is strongly anchored to the link community structure. In fact, well-connected investors are not just the ones with many active co-investments, but rather those who operate in communities with high connecting power. Investors with high CC score will belong to communities capable of reaching distant groups of actors, hence spreading the available financial resources to different players. We express CC as the weighted sum of communities a node belongs to over the X communities weighted by the average similarity between pairs of communities”. The authors discuss this in further detail in [8], Section 2. Further work identifying the centrality measures important in climate finance markets is of great interest.

3. Empirical Evidence

3.1. Wind Markets

Wind makes up a significant part of renewable energy consumption around the world. For example, in the UK, wind makes up about a quarter of the energy contribution of the country [32], with 11 thousand wind turbines (14 GW onshore and 14 GW offshore) active by 2023. In a recent journal article, The internal dynamics of fast-growing wind finance markets [9], Rickman et al. investigate, inter alia, the claim that preferential attachment (PA) drives the evolution of the hypergraph G introduced in Section 2.2. PA was initially introduced in a paper by Barabasi and Albert in 1999 in order to explain the emergence of the scale-free property in complex networks [33]. The arrival of new lenders is a discrete process of unknown temporal distribution, but it is hypothesized in [9] that they form new links to existing equity investors with probability proportional to the attachment kernel
A l ( w l ) = w l β l ,
and sponsors, on arrival, form new links to lenders with a probability proportional to the attachment kernel
A s ( w s ) = w s β s .
With multiple lenders involved in a single project, this constitutes a hyperedge of G. When a project has recieved multiple funding sources in the form of equity or debt loans, this also constitutes a hyperedge.
These authors do not attempt to recreate the BNEF data for the wind finance market via a random model [11] involving preferential attachment. This aspect remains an open avenue of further research. Instead, assuming this hypothesis, the exponents β l and β s are estimated via likelihood-based statistical methods. The lender exponent β l of Equation (1) and the sponsor exponent β s of Equation (2) are obtained via partial maximum likelihood estimation [34]. The accuracy of the validity of the PA model is itself assessed via the likelihood ratio test of Clegg [35]; see [9], Section 2.5.
The authors found that the preferential attachment theory described 11 out of the 16 countries analyzed in the study. They write that debt investors (lenders) face competition for projects and past lending experience is a major determinant of who will be selected as a project partner [9], Section 3.3. The authors claim that preferential attachment in this market is based on financial learning. Egli et al. write that “On the level of the renewable energy finance industry, investors benefitted from growing renewable energy technology (RET) markets and subsequent learning-by-doing (e.g., better risk assessment). Larger markets allowed banks to form in-house project finance teams specialized in RETs. The knowledge and data that these teams accumulated allowed for a more accurate technology assessment. Consequently, project risks declined. For example, as the market had accumulated experience on historical wind speeds, investors shifted from calculating project returns on wind resource estimations with 90% certainty” ([36], Drivers of Change).

3.2. Hydro Markets

Hydroelectric power (hydropower) is the largest international contributor to renewable energy production, producing more than half of the total output. Hydropower is particularly popular in developing countries, and thus plays an important role in the UN sustainability goals [32]. Larosa et al. write that “financing hydropower projects requires investors to pay large upfront capital and lock in their capital for decades (hydro projects can last for 100 years), while also bearing high investment risks”. With this in mind, the hydroelectric project financing landscape is addressed by Larosa et al. in “Finding the right partners? Examining inequalities in the global investment landscape of hydropower” [8]. Given the unique aspect of intercontinental development at work, internationally diverse financial actors need to be assembled. The focus is therefore on centrality and community detection rather than network evolution; see Figure 3 in [8].
Financing hydropower projects necessitates substantial upfront capital investment, with funds tied up for extended periods, often spanning a century due to the long lifespan of such projects. Indeed, the construction of a large hydropower dam typically exceeds a billion dollars, demanding patient capital and enduring the natural investment cycle. Thus, an intricate network of diverse investors, and effective capital distribution becomes essential for hydropower assets. The focus is therefore on centrality and community detection rather than network evolution.

3.3. Energy Efficiency Markets

Energy Efficiency Technologies are interventions that reduces energy consumption, such as using light-emitting diodes (LED) in place of conventional filament bulbs. This technology has a major place in modern science due primarily to its efficiency. The Nobel Prize in 2014 was awarded for the blue LED as it enables white light and a more universal employment of energy efficiency with the climate in mind [37]. Ameli et al. write that “investments in energy efficiency (EE) are particularly crucial to reduce the energy demand for a growing world economy and are listed as core measures for sustainable recovery plans” [7].
As with the research in wind markets, Ameli et al. focus on the theme of preferential attachment in a bipartite graph of investors and energy efficiency projects. Applying ideas from Pham et al. in their recent work concerning the joint estimation of preferential attachment and node fitness in growing complex networks, the authors look at how influential the intrinsic fitness of a node to acquire links is compared with its degree-based link acquisition (i.e., simple preferential attachment compared with a fitness-based network evolution model [27]).
They “empirically estimate the preferential attachment (PA) function and node fitnesses from observed network data” [7]. The authors suggest that there is a balance between preferential attachment and node fitness determining the evolution of their network, writing the following: “Following Pham et al. approach, we measure the respective influences of the preferential attachment and the fitness models” [7,28]. The PAFit method is discussed by Pham: “Our main contributions are twofold. The first contribution is a statistical method called PAFit to simultaneously estimate the PA and node fitness functions without imposing any assumptions on their functional forms. To the best of our knowledge, PAFit is the first ever method in the literature that can do so”.
Given this approach to the theory of network evolution, the authors draw the conclusion that “...this suggests that the ‘rich get richer’ mechanism becomes weaker when the ‘fit get richer’ effect is considered, showing that to some extent technology’s ability to attract new investment is explained by its fitness”. They also discuss the snapshot overtime of the network (see Figure 4), observing the total number of investments that different types of investors (e.g., from the utilities sector) have made ([7]: evolution, dynamics and growth of the energy efficiency network).

3.4. Green Bonds, Loans, and Networks of Underwriter Syndicates

Green bonds, loans and debt securities are designated to finance environmentally friendly projects. This may take the form of renewable energy infrastructure, such as a wind farm, or refurbishment of real estate to make it more sustainable. Whatever project requires funding, the project managers approach a bank looking for funding. They attempt to acquire investment by selling green bonds to investors [9]. These are underwriting, i.e., insured by a banking syndicate who buys all the bonds and resells them to investors for profit, therefore taking on the risk in case the project collapses. This guarantees returns for the holders of the bonds (these may be private customers, such as pension funds, or individuals purchasing online using their own funds) [38].
One can build a complex network—see Figure 5—from transaction data in the following way. The modeling consists of
  • A hypergraph G ( V , E ) where V is the vertex set and E is the edge set, with | V | = n | and | E | = m , and each edge e is simply a subset of V; see [39], Introduction.
  • The vertices, which represent banks.
  • The hyperedges (i.e., higher-order edges representing groups of investors and an investment rather than simply pairs of investors). which represent project financing by the corresponding banking syndicate. The amount of money invested is large enough in many cases to require large syndicates of banks to underwrite the risk.
See also Berge [40] and Beckenbach [41] for a discussion of bipartite hypergraphs. Note that there is also a potential to view this as a simplicial complex [42]. Higher-order network models of a banking network is an interesting area of further research in this area.

4. Final Words and Open Avenues of Research

The area is still developing, but has immense potential. Understanding the interesting aspects of complex networks which present particular application in banking networks funding climate initiatives allows policy makers intervention and influence on climate funding in a postive way for society.
The ways in which different market places, different sectors such as finance, technology or utilities, or different geographic regions lead to different network structure, or the ways in which it is universal, is still not well understood. Community detection needs further work, for example, by developing network embedding techniques that incorporate financial metrics (e.g., weighted edges representing money mobilized in a deal). As we disucssed, higher-order network models of a banking network is an interesting area of further research.
Two recent articles have addressed preferential attachment as the main driver of network evolution. It remains an open question as to whether random models of climate finance hypergraphs which evolve based on ”rich get richer” or ”fit get richer” models are able to reproduce the data of BNEF in a sophisticated way. This would present an important connection between statistical physics and climate finance, and allow further insights into how these networks evolve and develop. How to then encourage the transition to green energy based on this detailed understanding is a difficult and multi-disciplinary task, but well founded on the excellent descriptive analysis that can be provided by these early works in complex networks Further work on network evolution is critical to understand the mechanisms that generate the highly skewed degree distributions observed in banking syndicate networks. We look forward to a future review concerning research developing these ideas, and to the corresponding new insights into climate finance as we track the critically important goals of the Paris agreement.
We hope that in the future, the link between policy and network structure can be addressed, as well as the ways in which this structure leads to better and more sustainable green growth. This is a major challenge which we hope the networks community can begin to address to provide a remarkable example of physics in society.

Author Contributions

Writing—original draft, A.P.K.-G. and N.A. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

Both authors acknowledge support from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (grant agreement No 802891).

Data Availability Statement

Bloomberg data used for any banking syndicate informaton (not published elsewhere) is proprietary and shareable on request with the corresponding author.

Acknowledgments

We thank Denitsa Angelova, Ginestra Bianconi, Claudia Brown, Max Falkenberg, Michael Grubb, Ben Hinder, Francessca Larosa, Figo Lau, Sumit Kothari, and Jamie Rickman, for many helpful discussion.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Ladyman, J.; Lambert, J.; Wiesner, K. What is a complex system? Eur. J. Philos. Sci. 2012, 3, 33–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Mantegna, R. Hierarchical structure in financial markets. Eur. Phys. J. B 1999, 11, 193–197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Hall, S.; Foxon, T.J.; Bolton, R. Investing in low-carbon transitions: Energy finance as an adaptive market. Clim. Policy 2015, 17, 280–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Schweitzer, F.; Fagiolo, G.; Sornette, D.; Vega-Redondo, F.; Vespignani, A.; White, D.R. Economic Networks: The New Challenges. Science 2009, 325, 422–425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  5. Foster, J. From simplistic to complex systems in economics. Camb. J. Econ. 2005, 29, 873–892. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Gross, T.; Sayama, H. (Eds.) Adaptive Networks; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2009. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Ameli, N.; Kothari, S.; Livan, G.; Caldarelli, G. The Hidden Structure of Energy Efficiency Finance. SSRN Electron. J. 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Larosa, F.; Rickman, J.; Ameli, N. Finding the right partners? Examining inequalities in the global investment landscape of hydropower. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2022, 74, 102518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Rickman, J.; Larosa, F.; Ameli, N. The internal dynamics of fast-growing wind finance markets. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 375, 134129. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Barthelemy, M. Spatial networks. Phys. Rep. 2011, 499, 1–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Grimmett, G. Probability on Graphs; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  12. Pearson, K. The Life, Letters and Labours of Francis Galton; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. May, R.M. Will a Large Complex System be Stable? Nature 1972, 238, 413–414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Rickles, D. Econophysics and the Complexity of Financial Markets. In Philosophy of Complex Systems; Handbook of the Philosophy of Science; Hooker, C., Ed.; North-Holland: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2011; Volume 10, pp. 531–565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Kutner, R.; Ausloos, M.; Grech, D.; Matteo, T.D.; Schinckus, C.; Stanley, H.E. Econophysics and sociophysics: Their milestones and challenges. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Its Appl. 2019, 516, 240–253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Van der Hofstad, R. Random Graphs and Complex Networks; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Aguiar, M.; Bick, C.; Dias, A. Network Dynamics with Higher-Order Interactions: Coupled Cell Hypernetworks for Identical Cells and Synchrony. arXiv 2022, arXiv:2201.09379. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Bajo, E.; Croci, E.; Marinelli, N. Institutional investor networks and firm value. J. Bus. Res. 2020, 112, 65–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Fracassi, C. Corporate Finance Policies and Social Networks. Manag. Sci. 2012, 63, 2397–2419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Crane, A.D.; Koch, A.; Michenaud, S. Institutional investor cliques and governance. J. Financ. Econ. 2019, 133, 175–197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Dordi, T.; Gehricke, S.A.; Naef, A.; Weber, O. Ten financial actors can accelerate a transition away from fossil fuels. Environ. Innov. Soc. Transitions 2022, 44, 60–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Galaz, V.; Crona, B.; Dauriach, A.; Scholtens, B.; Steffen, W. Finance and the Earth system – Exploring the links between financial actors and non-linear changes in the climate system. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2018, 53, 296–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Dimson, E.; Karakaş, O.; Li, X. Coordinated Engagements. SSRN Electron. J. 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Yang, A.; Uysal, N.; Taylor, M. Unleashing the Power of Networks: Shareholder Activism, Sustainable Development and Corporate Environmental Policy. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2017, 27, 712–727. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Chung, F.; Lu, L.; Dewey, T.G.; Galas, D.J. Duplication Models for Biological Networks. J. Comput. Biol. 2003, 10, 677–687. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Seyed-allaei, H.; Bianconi, G.; Marsili, M. Scale-free networks with an exponent less than two. Phys. Rev. E 2006, 73, 046113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Bianconi, G.; Barabási, A.L. Competition and multiscaling in evolving networks. Europhys. Lett. (EPL) 2001, 54, 436–442. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Pham, T.; Sheridan, P.; Shimodaira, H. Joint estimation of preferential attachment and node fitness in growing complex networks. Sci. Rep. 2016, 6, 32558. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Newman, M.E.J.; Girvan, M. Finding and evaluating community structure in networks. Phys. Rev. E 2004, 69, 026113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  30. Lindblom, T.; Mavruk, T.; Sjögren, S. East or west, home is best: The birthplace bias of individual investors. J. Bank. Financ. 2018, 92, 323–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Murphy, A.H. The Finley Affair: A Signal Event in the History of Forecast Verification. Weather Forecast. 1996, 11, 3–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. IEA. World Energy Outlook; IEA: Paris, France, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  33. Barabasi, L.; Albert, R. Emergence of Scaling in Random Networks. Science 1999, 286, 509–512. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  34. Inoue, M.; Pham, T.; Shimodaira, H. Joint estimation of non-parametric transitivity and preferential attachment functions in scientific co-authorship networks. J. Inf. 2020, 14, 101042. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Clegg, R.G.; Parker, B.; Rio, M. Likelihood-based assessment of dynamic networks. J. Complex Netw. 2016, 4, 517–533. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Egli, F.; Steffen, B.; Schmidt, T.S. A dynamic analysis of financing conditions for renewable energy technologies. Nat. Energy 2018, 3, 1084–1092. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. nobelprize.org. Press Release. Nobel Prize Outreach AB 2023. Available online: https://www.nobelprize.org/prizes/physics/2014/press-release/ (accessed on 31 March 2023).
  38. Wikipedia. Project Finance. 2023. Available online: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Project_finance (accessed on 9 April 2023).
  39. Chen, H.; Frieze, A. Coloring bipartite hypergraphs. In Integer Programming and Combinatorial Optimization; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1996; pp. 345–358. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Berge, C. Hypergraphs: Combinatorics of Finite Sets; North-Holland: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1989; Volume 43. [Google Scholar]
  41. Beckenbach, I.L. Matchings and Flows in Hypergraphs. Ph.D. Dissertation, Freien Universität Berlin, Berlin, Germany, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  42. Kartun-Giles, A.P.; Bianconi, G. Beyond the clustering coefficient: A topological analysis of node neighbourhoods in complex networks. Chaos Solitons Fractals X 2019, 1, 100004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Green debt issued in the Balkans to date. Nodes are banks, and links exist between banks when they insure a bond issuance together (i.e., investors provide financing for a loan to support a green energy project, and the loan is insured by the larger financial system by buying the debt and reselling to investors as a security). A multilayer network is formed, since banks work together on deals that are domiciled in a specific country. Whenever two banks work together to underwrite a loan for a project whose country of domicile is listed in Kosovo, they are connected with a blue link, with a red link when in Bosnia, and with a purple link in Montenegro. The node degree is reflected in its relative size. The Austrian financial service provider Erste Group Bank has activity 2, since it takes part in two layers, and degree 11, since it has interacted with that many banks.
Figure 1. Green debt issued in the Balkans to date. Nodes are banks, and links exist between banks when they insure a bond issuance together (i.e., investors provide financing for a loan to support a green energy project, and the loan is insured by the larger financial system by buying the debt and reselling to investors as a security). A multilayer network is formed, since banks work together on deals that are domiciled in a specific country. Whenever two banks work together to underwrite a loan for a project whose country of domicile is listed in Kosovo, they are connected with a blue link, with a red link when in Bosnia, and with a purple link in Montenegro. The node degree is reflected in its relative size. The Austrian financial service provider Erste Group Bank has activity 2, since it takes part in two layers, and degree 11, since it has interacted with that many banks.
Entropy 25 01371 g001
Figure 2. Hypergraph evolution. Nodes represent banks, and hyperedges (coloured edges) represent syndicates. New hyperedges attach to the current network nodes based on preferential attachment.
Figure 2. Hypergraph evolution. Nodes represent banks, and hyperedges (coloured edges) represent syndicates. New hyperedges attach to the current network nodes based on preferential attachment.
Entropy 25 01371 g002
Figure 3. Degree distribution for the green bond and loan network. The red squares represent the probability a randomly selected bank in the international banking network supporting green loans and bonds is involved in k bond issuances. The non-linear model P ( k ) k 1.77 is the black line. This suggests a highly right-skewed degree distribution with exponent 1.77 , which occurs because the syndicates arrive in time faster than the banks, leaving a dense network where deals/banks > 1 , and grows in time.
Figure 3. Degree distribution for the green bond and loan network. The red squares represent the probability a randomly selected bank in the international banking network supporting green loans and bonds is involved in k bond issuances. The non-linear model P ( k ) k 1.77 is the black line. This suggests a highly right-skewed degree distribution with exponent 1.77 , which occurs because the syndicates arrive in time faster than the banks, leaving a dense network where deals/banks > 1 , and grows in time.
Entropy 25 01371 g003
Figure 4. Aggregated network of financial actors involved in energy efficiency financing (2000–2017) in different sectors, taken from [7]. Nodes are investors, and edges are financial interactions between them, with the following key: pink from state-owned utility, brown from investor-owned utilities, light blue from manufacturing and services, green from the governmental sector, dark purple from an energy cooperative, light-green research and the university sector, blue from institutional investors, orange construction and real estate, turquoise diversified, deep green chemicals and steel, green-brown food, bright red retail, light purple defence, and bright purple the remaining uncatagorised areas.
Figure 4. Aggregated network of financial actors involved in energy efficiency financing (2000–2017) in different sectors, taken from [7]. Nodes are investors, and edges are financial interactions between them, with the following key: pink from state-owned utility, brown from investor-owned utilities, light blue from manufacturing and services, green from the governmental sector, dark purple from an energy cooperative, light-green research and the university sector, blue from institutional investors, orange construction and real estate, turquoise diversified, deep green chemicals and steel, green-brown food, bright red retail, light purple defence, and bright purple the remaining uncatagorised areas.
Entropy 25 01371 g004
Figure 5. A sample of the multilayer network of banks (nodes) underwriting green bonds and loans in two countires, UK (blue links), and France (red links). Goldman Sachs, BNP Paribas, and HSBC connect the layers, serving as international actors which unite layers more often than local banks.
Figure 5. A sample of the multilayer network of banks (nodes) underwriting green bonds and loans in two countires, UK (blue links), and France (red links). Goldman Sachs, BNP Paribas, and HSBC connect the layers, serving as international actors which unite layers more often than local banks.
Entropy 25 01371 g005
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kartun-Giles, A.P.; Ameli, N. An Introduction to Complex Networks in Climate Finance. Entropy 2023, 25, 1371. https://doi.org/10.3390/e25101371

AMA Style

Kartun-Giles AP, Ameli N. An Introduction to Complex Networks in Climate Finance. Entropy. 2023; 25(10):1371. https://doi.org/10.3390/e25101371

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kartun-Giles, Alexander P., and Nadia Ameli. 2023. "An Introduction to Complex Networks in Climate Finance" Entropy 25, no. 10: 1371. https://doi.org/10.3390/e25101371

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop