Next Article in Journal
Application of Unconventional Tillage Systems to Maize Cultivation and Measures for Rational Use of Agricultural Lands
Previous Article in Journal
The Foundational Components of Self-Regulating (Sustainable) Economies and Ecosystems: Implications for Green Infrastructure and Economic Restoration
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Effects of Transfer of Land Development Rights on Urban–Rural Integration: Theoretical Framework and Evidence from Chongqing, China

1
Department of Urban Planning, School of Architecture, Tsinghua University, Beijing 100084, China
2
School of Architecture and Urban Planning, Nanjing University, Nanjing 210093, China
3
School of Landscape Architecture, Beijing Forestry University, Beijing 100083, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Land 2023, 12(11), 2045; https://doi.org/10.3390/land12112045
Submission received: 5 September 2023 / Revised: 8 November 2023 / Accepted: 8 November 2023 / Published: 10 November 2023

Abstract

:
The transfer of land development rights (TDR) is a significant policy tool for advancing urban–rural integration. This study establishes an analytical framework to examine the influence mechanism of TDR on urban–rural integration, considering the flow of land, capital, and population factors. Furthermore, an indicator system is developed to evaluate urban–rural integration across economic, social, and population dimensions. Using panel data from Chongqing, China (2013 to 2019), this article adopts the global principal component analysis (GPCA) method and time-varying difference-in-difference (TV-DID) model to analyze the effects of the land quota trading project, known as the ‘Dipiao’ policy. The results show that TDR can effectively promote urban–rural integration, though with a four-year time lag. Heterogeneous effects of TDR on urban–rural integration are observed across different districts and counties, with the more pronounced promotion in areas characterized by low agricultural land value or high industrial land value. This study further analyzes the influence mechanism of TDR on urban–rural integration. It concludes with policy implications on improving TDR to promote urban–rural integration.

1. Introduction

The escalating disparities between urban and rural areas have been witnessed worldwide, and the urban–rural divide has emerged as a preeminent concern in the contemporary context [1,2,3]. Whereas urban areas occupy a rapidly increasing share of land, rural areas tend to have fewer residents and lower GDP per capita compared to their urban counterparts [4,5]. Given that land constitutes the material foundation and spatial carrier for urban–rural development, the inequitable allocation of land resources between urban and rural areas has become a significant factor of imbalances in urban–rural development [6,7]. The unimpeded and unrestricted flow of land1, capital, and other essential elements between urban and rural areas is of pivotal importance in facilitating the integration of urban and rural development [8,9,10,11]. The facilitation by removing barriers to the flow of land is considered a vital policy tool in advancing urban–rural integration within the context of contemporary urbanization in China [12], and the transfer of land development rights (TDR) has been implemented in pilot cities. Nevertheless, it remains to be examined whether the exploration of TDR genuinely contributes to urban–rural integration given the existing land institutions. Clarifying the mechanism and effect of TDR on urban–rural integration and leveraging the role of TDR in achieving integrated urban–rural development and rural revitalization have become critical scientific and social propositions and imperatives for China.
Article 10 of the Chinese Constitution states the distinction of land ownership between urban and rural land—state-owned land in urban areas and collective-owned land in rural areas. Rural–urban land conversion can be legally achieved only through a state requisition process, while the legal authorization for the private transfer of rural land-use rights for non-rural use has never been promulgated by the Chinese government [13]. Characterized by a strict boundary between urban and rural land, the current dual land management system in China inevitably leads to a considerable urban–rural divide in economic well-being and imposes significant constraints on rural land development rights [14,15,16]2. With the rapid and massive urbanization in China, numerous farmers have migrated from rural areas, resulting in a considerable amount of vacant rural construction land and land resources. In an effort to address the issue of urban–rural land division and alleviate the contradiction in urban–rural land supply, the Chinese government has implemented the “Increase-decrease Linkage” policy (Zengjian Guagou). Since 2004, it has allowed local governments to convert certain amounts of agricultural land to urban construction land if they create an equal amount or more agricultural land from rural construction land. Building upon this policy, Chongqing has explored a market trading mechanism, namely, the Dipiao policy, to further facilitate the trading of urban and rural land development rights, which has become a prominent approach to promoting urban–rural integration [17].
In the realm of land policy-making, there has been extensive discussion in the existing literature regarding the effect of TDR on equitable development and social justice. Aiming to compensate landowners for losses caused by strictly regulated zoning procedures and other spatial planning regulations, TDR was introduced to counter the unequal allocation of initial development rights across diverse regions [18,19]. Proponents claim that TDR schemes were designed to fulfill the principle of social justice by correcting inequities [20,21]. An empirical evaluation of TDR programs in the United States demonstrated that TDR could be a viable supplementary policy for achieving a balance between growth and preservation [22]. In Turkey, the decent combination of market-led TDR and the command-control function of the traditional land-use plan helps to restore equity, balance, and fairness [23]. Drawing from the experiences in Hong Kong, TDR can be a potential tool to increase equity and mitigate the impact of rigid planning laws or actions on private property [24]. However, some scholars argue that a general application of TDR cannot guarantee the equity and fairness of the planning system. Italian urban planning techniques are evolving into a more open system characterized by the free movement and the marketability of land development rights. This allows certain parcels to be developed at higher densities compared to those in their vicinity, resulting in an unequal distribution and new forms of speculative activity [25].
In the context of the Chinese land system, diverse perspectives exist concerning the positive role of TDR on urban–rural integration. Proponents believe TDR is a potential tool to promote urban–rural integration. They examine how TDR optimizes the allocation of urban and rural land and supports rural revitalization by enabling the possibility of farmers to participate in the appreciation of urban land value [26,27,28,29,30,31,32,33,34,35]. Furthermore, urban–rural integration is undeniably a complex geographical process that requires a meticulous examination of potential unintended consequences. Critics argue that farmers are placed in a disadvantaged position in this process, experiencing dispossession and exploitation, which ultimately leads to ineffective protection of their rights and inadequate compensation [36,37,38]. Also, it is pointed out that the rent-seeking behavior and policy deficiencies resulted in failures to effectively promote coordinated urban–rural development and even exacerbated the urban–rural divide [39,40,41,42]. Thus, it is crucial to emphasize the significance of adopting a wise stance to gain a comprehensive understanding of the intricate nature of urban–rural integration [43]. This involves the establishment of collective wisdom through practices such as community building to empower individuals in mitigating adverse effects related to the transformation of urban–rural relationships [44,45]. Additionally, the dependent variables of primary interest in the relevant quantitative research encompass the urban–rural income gap [46,47], the growth of income among urban and rural residents [48], and the urban–rural industrial structure [49]. Additionally, from the perspective of a spatial scale, existing studies predominantly focus on macro-level units such as provinces and cities as the primary units, while little research has been conducted on the district/county scale [50].
However, despite the wealth of literature on the effects of TDR that has provided useful insights, the effect mechanism of TDR on the flow and interaction of various factors in the process of urban–rural integration remains incomplete. The burgeoning quantitative research rests on a relatively simplistic image of urban–rural integration, mainly focusing on economic performance, which may miss many of its important dimensions. On the whole, further research is necessary to investigate the intricate mechanism underlying the effect of TDR on urban–rural integration, and it is essential to employ quantitative measurement to conduct a comprehensive evaluation of urban–rural integration encompassing diverse dimensions.
This article aims to examine the relationship between TDR and urban–rural development and explore the mechanisms through which TDR affects urban–rural integration to provide a comprehensive framework and a perspective of TDR for the optimal allocation of urban–rural land resources and advancement of urban–rural coordinated development. In the sections that follow, we develop an analytical framework that illustrates how TDR drives urban–rural integration and construct evaluation indicators for urban–rural integration based on three key dimensions. Empirically, we then quantitatively analyze the spatial patterns of urban–rural integration across 37 districts and counties in Chongqing using the global principal component analysis (GPCA) method. Furthermore, the relationship between TDR and urban–rural integration will be examined through the time-varying difference-in-difference (TV-DID) model based on Chongqing’s panel data between 2013 and 2019.

2. TDR and Urban–Rural Integration: A Theoretical Framework

2.1. Connotations of TDR and Urban–Rural Integration

2.1.1. TDR and Dipiao Policy

TDR is the process of transferring the development rights from one parcel of land to another, which allows more development on the second parcel (land-receiving area), while the originating parcel (land-sending area) experiences a reduction or restriction in development opportunities [51]. This market-based mechanism plays a key role in offsetting the restrictions imposed on development rights caused by regulatory institutions such as land management systems [52,53].
This article explores the transfer of land development rights between urban and rural areas, where cities serve as the land-receiving areas, obtaining more construction land quotas, while rural areas are land-sending areas facing constraints on development [54]. According to the land administration system in China, it is notable that while the Linkage Policy was initiated by the central government, the local governments are the actual land suppliers for urban construction [55]. Consequently, diverse operational approaches have emerged across different regions, with the Dipiao policy proposed by the Chongqing government representing one of the most typical programs [56,57]. In 2009, the State Council approved the establishment of the Chongqing Rural Land Exchange (CRLE) to carry out experiments on land quota transactions within the whole city region of Chongqing [38]. The local government introduced a credit system known as Dipiao, which could be literally translated as land ticket or land certificate, enabling the securitization of land development rights [37].
The Dipiao policy has been adopted as a means of TDR within the context of the dual land property rights arrangements in China [58]. According to the Dipiao Transaction Rules of Chongqing Rural Land Exchange (Revised in 2019), Dipiao mainly involves rural homestead land and other rural collective construction lands [59]. Before the land quotas are securitized as Dipiao, the rural construction land should be reclaimed back to qualified agricultural land and undergo strict approval by the local bureau of land resources. Once the high-quality reclaimed land is accepted, Dipiao is officially issued. Figure 1 illustrates the Dipiao transaction process. Firstly, the construction land quotas would be gathered in CRLE and be traded to developers through auction or tender. Secondly, CRLE will pay a substantial monetary reward as compensation for their land at the prevailing market price, which is much higher than the normal land compensatory fee [60]. A notable aspect is that 85% of the net revenue from the sale of the land quotas is allocated to rural villagers (the relocated peasants who previously lived on the land), with the remaining 15% going to the rural collective.

2.1.2. Urban–Rural Integration

Urban–rural integration is a comprehensive and multi-dimensional dynamic concept, which entails the establishment of effective links between urban and rural populations, land, and industries through the two-way free flow and equal exchange of resources and factors [61,62]. This concept perceives cities and villages as an organic whole, emphasizing the process of promoting the mobility of production factors and balancing the allocation of public resources. Urban–rural linkages can be promoted through the circulation of commodities, population mobility, infrastructure connectivity, provision of public services, and cooperation in environmental governance. These efforts facilitate economic, social, ecological, and other forms of collaboration between urban and rural areas [63].
The urban–rural integration analyzed in this article primarily focuses on economic integration, social integration, and population integration. In the economic dimension, urban–rural integration is manifested by the gradual narrowing of the urban–rural income and productivity gaps, the transformation of the rural economy toward non-agricultural sectors, and the convergence of urban–rural industrial structure [64]. In terms of population, urban–rural integration is characterized by a high urbanization rate, with the majority of the population concentrated in urban areas [65]. In the social dimension, urban–rural integration entails equitable living conditions, social welfare, and quality of life for both urban and rural residents, which manifests in the development and broader coverage of comprehensive public service facilities, as well as an improvement in the living standards of urban–rural residents.

2.2. Influence Mechanism of TDR on Urban–Rural Integration

From the above connotations, it becomes evident that the flow of land factors between urban and rural areas is an essential requirement and a significant prerequisite for achieving urban–rural integration [63]. The TDR policy, based on the flow of land factors, can exert further influence on urban–rural relations and development by facilitating the flow of population and capital factors. These three primary factors play a crucial role in shaping the dynamics of urban–rural coordinated development. It is expected that the spatial transfer and exchange in the flow of three key factors—land, capital, and population—resulting from the process of TDR will have an impact on the three dimensions of urban–rural integration. The theoretical framework is shown in Figure 2.
Regarding the land factors, the TDR policy breaks the government’s monopoly on rural–urban construction land transfers, enabling rural land resources to have more access to convert to urban uses. In response to the increasing urban population, urban areas face an expanding demand for construction land to support residential and industrial development. Therefore, obtaining more construction land quotas can address land resource constraints and promote urban development [66]. In contrast to this, in rural areas, there are a considerable number of unused houses and extensive undeveloped rural construction land [67]. The TDR policy can contribute to enhancing overall land-use efficiency by reasonably facilitating land-use conversion. Additionally, the practice of TDR in China involves reclaiming rural construction land and converting it into cultivated land, providing an opportunity for concentrated and contiguous rural land assembly, which may change the scale of agricultural land management and impact agricultural production efficiency [68,69]. In general, the TDR policy has the potential to accelerate land transfers from less productive producers to more productive ones or to more profitable uses.
From the perspective of capital factors, the funds obtained from the TDR process should be given back to the farmers and rural collectives, allowing rural land owners to share the benefits generated by urban land development, thus leading to capital flows between urban and rural areas. Land plots located in undeveloped rural areas or away from urban areas are the subjects of the land-sending area in TDR projects, and their rural owners are expected to significantly benefit from the compensation of land transfers. The introduction of tradable land-use rights quotas enables rural households to increase their property income [70]. Furthermore, some farmers who lose their rural homesteads may migrate to cities and engage in non-agricultural employment, thereby earning wage income [35,71]. Additionally, the compensation payment allocated to the rural collectives provides additional funds to support the infrastructure and improve living conditions in rural areas [59].
From a population perspective, the incomes generated from land quota transactions provide the initial financial support for rural laborers and their dependents, who tend to migrate to urban areas [38]. In some cases, the farmers in land-sending areas will be granted the chance to move into a high-rise apartment at a subsidized price, coupled with the provision of urban household registration (hukou) benefits [72,73]. The TDR policy, as well as its supporting policies, such as encouraging farmers’ relocation to newly constructed rural communities, offers a more equitable pathway for all farmers to participate in rapid urbanization, accelerating the transition of some farmers into wage workers. Simultaneously, the agglomeration of rural residents significantly reduces the cost of providing public services and effectively harnesses the positive externality and spillover effects of public services. The liberation of the rural population from the constraints of land ownership promotes urbanization and further facilitates the transition of migrant workers into registered urban residents [74].
On the whole, the TDR policy has strong effects on land use, income and employment structure, and agricultural production in rural areas, ultimately changing the economic, social, and population urban–rural integration through the reallocation of land resources, human resources, and capital factors [75]. It is expected that the TDR policy will promote integrated urban–rural development through the income effect, resource effect, and urbanization effect.

3. Materials and Method

Initially, evaluation indicators for urban–rural integration were constructed based on three key dimensions: economic integration, social integration, and population integration. The global principal component analysis (GPCA) method was employed to assess the urban–rural integration index, followed by the TV-DID model to measure the effect of TDR on urban–rural integration within the context of Chongqing (Figure 3).

3.1. Study Area and Data

3.1.1. Study Area

Chongqing is a typical mountainous city located in southwestern inland China (Figure 4). The urban–rural income gap in Chongqing peaked in 2006, making it one of the cities with the largest urban–rural divide in China (Figure 5). The challenges of limited construction land resources and the imbalance between urban and rural development have become pressing issues. In 2007, Chongqing was chosen as a National Pilot Area for Comprehensive Reforms in Coordinating Urban and Rural Development. This initiative aimed to achieve coordinated rural and urban development through comprehensive reforms in all sectors [76]. By 2019, the amount of rural construction land transferred to urban construction land in Chongqing had reached about 24,000 hectares, with a total land value of nearly 50 billion Chinese yuan (CNY). Considering the extensive scale of land development rights trading in Chongqing and the well-established market platform, it is of immense value and significance to conduct an empirical study in Chongqing.

3.1.2. Variables and Data Source

(1)
Dependent variables
The urban–rural integration index is considered a dependent variable. Based on the connotation of urban–rural integration discussed above and previous studies analyzing the influencing mechanism of urban–rural integration [76,77,78,79], an evaluation indicator system has been established following the principles of integrity, scientific nature, and feasibility. Fully considering data availability and validity, three indicators were selected to measure the urban–rural integration level in various counties and regions in Chongqing, namely economic integration, population integration, and social integration.
As shown in Table 1, the economic integration indicator includes six secondary indicators: the ratio of urban–rural residents’ per capita disposable income, the ratio of urban–rural residents’ per capita wage and salary income, the ratio of urban–rural residents’ per capita property income, the ratio of urban–rural residents’ per capita consumption expenditure, the ratio of urban–rural Engel coefficient, and proportion of the output value of the secondary and tertiary industries. Next, the population integration indicator includes four secondary indicators: urbanization rate, the proportion of the registered population within the permanent resident population, urban–rural disparity coefficient of employment proportion, and the ratio of urban–rural employed population. Finally, the social integration indicator includes six secondary indicators: population coverage rate of broadcast programs, the number of hospital beds per thousand people in health institutions, the number of medical technical personnel per thousand people in health institutions, the ratio of urban–rural per capita transport and communications expenditure, the ratio of urban–rural per capita education, cultural and recreation expenditure, and the ratio of urban–rural per capita healthcare and medical services expenditure.
(2)
Independent variable
This article investigates whether TDR policy has played a pivotal role in improving urban–rural integration. Therefore, the presence and timing of Dipiao transactions in different regions of Chongqing are represented as dummy variables in this research. In this model, ‘du’ represents the grouping dummy variable, du = 1 represents the areas where Dipiao transactions occurred during the observed period, and du = 0 represents the areas without Dipiao transactions occurring during the observed period; ‘dt’ is the timing dummy variable, dt = 0 represents the years before Dipiao transactions occurred, and dt = 1 represents the years after Dipiao transactions occurred. The product of these two terms, du × dt, is the independent variable.
(3)
Control variables
We seek to capture factors that are typically found to be significant in determining comprehensive urban–rural development. Specifically, we consider the economic development level, financial development level, social investment level, and external trade level. The economic development level is described by per capita GDP (d1) and total retail sales of consumer goods (d2); the financial development level is depicted by government general budgetary revenue, which reflects the government’s ability to balance the gap between urban–rural development (d3) and total deposit balance of RMB of financial institutions (d4); social investment level is quantified by analyzing the total investment in fixed assets (d5); the external trade level is characterized by total imports and exports (d6). These indicators have been widely acknowledged in the existing literature and hold relevance for understanding the multifaceted dynamics of urban–rural development.
A series of panel data from 2013 to 2019, covering 37 districts and counties in Chongqing, was selected for the model. The data on Dipiao transactions in various areas of Chongqing are collected from the official website of Chongqing Country Land Exchange, specifically from the announcements of Dipiao transaction results. The data on dependent variables and control variables are obtained from the Chongqing Statistical Yearbook (2014–2020) and Chongqing Survey Yearbook (2014–2020).

3.2. Method

3.2.1. Global Principal Component Analysis

Given the dynamic and comprehensive nature of the urban–rural relationship, the static principal component analysis (PCA), which is limited to cross-sectional data, is no longer suitable. To conduct an indicator assessment of urban–rural integration, the paper employs the global principal component analysis (GPCA), a dynamic multi-attribute decision-making model that builds upon the classical PCA methodology [80].
First, to analyze the 16 urban–rural integration indicators over a span of seven years, it is essential to establish a time-series stereo data table. Second, it is necessary to perform standardized processing to ensure that the indicators are transformed into a consistent scale. For positive indicators, the transforming equation is as follows:
y i j = x i j m i n ( x i j ) m a x x i j m i n ( x i j ) .
The transforming equation for negative indicators is as follows:
y i j = m a x x i j x i j m a x x i j m i n ( x i j ) .
where x i j denotes the initial value of the index, m i n ( x i j ) and m a x ( x i j ) are the minimum and maximum values of the index among the evaluation objectives, respectively, and y i j is the standardized value.
We used Stata16.0 software to perform the Bartlett test (BT) (Bartlett, 1950) and Kaiser–Meyer–Olkin (KMO) test (Kaiser and Rice, 1974). The approximate chi-square of Bartlett’s test is 2743.421, and the significance level is 0.000 (less than 0.01). The result of the KMO test is 0.767 (greater than 0.5), which indicates that there is a strong correlation among test indicators. Therefore, further analysis could be conducted. Next, the eigenvalues and contribution rate of the global principal components are calculated, and principal components are determined according to the criterion that the eigenvalues should be more than 1. Finally, the weight coefficients of the principal component matrix are calculated, and the comprehensive score of urban–rural integration is constructed. The formula for calculating the comprehensive score is as follows:
Z = k 1 F 1 + k 2 F 2 + + k n F n
where Z is the comprehensive score; k 1 , k 2 k n is the contribution rate of each principal component; F 1 , F 2 F n is the score of each principal component.

3.2.2. Time-Varying Difference-in-Difference Model

In the field of policy effect evaluation, the difference-in-difference (DID) model based on natural experiments is widely regarded as the most commonly used method [81]. In the DID model, samples are divided into treatment and control groups to comprehensively investigate the differences before and after the implementation of a certain policy [82]. We take the districts and counties that witnessed Dipiao transactions as the treatment group, while those without Dipiao transactions serve as the “control group”. Since the origin of Dipiao policy implementation varied across different districts or counties within the treatment group, the study employs the time-varying DID method (TV-DID). The model is formulated as follows:
Y i t = α + β d u × d t + γ X i t + y e a r t + a r e a i + ε i t
where i represents the area, t represents the year, the dependent variable Y i t represents the urban–rural integration index of the area i in the year t; d u is a dummy variable that equals 1 for the treatment group and 0 otherwise, d t represents the temporal dummy variable that equals 1 for the time period after policy implementation and 0 otherwise; X i t represents the control variable; y e a r t is the temporal fixed effect, a r e a i is the individual fixed effect, ε i t is the random disturbance term. This study focuses on the positive and negative direction of coefficient β and its significance. If β is significant and greater than 0, it means that the Dipiao policy plays a positive effect on the urban–rural integration of the objects.

4. Results

4.1. Measured Results of Urban–Rural Integration

Five principal components were extracted by the GPCA method, and the cumulative variance contribution rate was 74.52%. This can explain most of the information of the original variables. The results of the comprehensive score of the urban–rural integration index for districts and counties in Chongqing are shown in Table 2. From the perspective of the majority of districts and counties, the scores of the urban–rural integration index, which encompass the cumulative scores across all dimensions, have improved with slight fluctuations in overall urban–rural integration. Among the analyzed areas, only Wuxi County experienced a decrease in the urban–rural integration index from 2013 to 2019, yet it should be noted that there was a noticeable improvement in prior years.
Figure 6 further reveals the spatial characteristics of the urban–rural integration index, with the Jenks optimal natural fracture method in ArcGIS 10.4 adopted to divide them into five categories between the years 2013 and 2019. The urban–rural integration index generally exhibits a pattern of gradual decrease with increasing distance from the city center, i.e., from the southwest toward the southeast and northeast of Chongqing. From 2013 to 2019, the districts located in the city center, such as Shapingba District, Dadukou District, and Jiangbei District, emerged as the top-performing areas in terms of urban–rural integration. Nonetheless, when considering the changing trends, a more evident improvement in urban–rural integration is witnessed in economically underdeveloped districts and counties, exemplified by notable cases in Yunyang County, Wushan County, and Youyang County. Over a period of seven years, the urban–rural integration index experienced growth of more than two-fold in these three counties, with Wushan County even experiencing a three-fold increase.

4.2. Assessment of the TDR Effects on Urban–Rural Integration

4.2.1. Parallel Trend Test

In the context of the TV-DID method, it is crucial for the model to satisfy the ‘parallel trend assumption,’ which implies that trends in the outcomes between the treatment group and the control group are expected to be the same if the policy implementation does not have an effect on the treatment group. This assumption signifies that, in the pretreatment period without the policy intervention factors, there should be no inherent differences between the treatment group and the control group, and the diverging trends observed between the two groups in the post-treatment period can be attributed to the policy implementation. In order to fulfill this assumption, we introduced modifications to Equation (4) by incorporating insights from the study conducted by Beck et al. (2010) [83]. Since the Dipiao policies were implemented progressively across various areas, rather than selecting a specific year, we generated d u × d t k ( d u × d t + k ), which encompass the counterfactual year dummy variable dt and the treated group dummy variable du. Considering that the Dipiao policy was initiated in 2008, and with only a limited number of cities adopting the policy after 2012, d t 1 is employed to signify cities prior to the policy implementation. The modified equation is as follows:
Y i t = α + β d u × d t k + γ X i t + y e a r t + a r e a i + ε i t
The parallel trend test results provide evidence that satisfies the parallel trends assumption fundamental to the TV-DID model. Before the implementation of the Dipiao policy, the estimated coefficients were statistically insignificant, indicating no appreciable variation in the trend of the promoting effect on urban–rural integration between the treatment group and the control group. However, following the policy’s initiation, the promoting effect gradually appeared beginning in the fourth year. This indicates a slight time lag in the policy’s effect on promoting urban–rural integration. The primary factor contributing to this phenomenon could be that the time lag typically encountered between the sale of land quotas and the subsequent payment of capital compensation often spanned one or more years.

4.2.2. Baseline Regression Results

According to the two stages of the TDR process in Chongqing, which involve land quota trading and capital compensation payment, there was a time interval of between one and several years between these two stages. Consequently, both stages were considered the independent variables for regression analysis, with ‘du·dt_land’ representing land quota trading and ‘du·dt_capital’ representing capital compensation payment. In this section, the effect of TDR was estimated based on Equation (4), in which the du·dt_land and du·dt_capital were used for estimation purposes. The results of the four models are presented in Table 3, where models (1) and (2) illustrate the results with du·dt_land as the independent variable, while models (3) and (4) display the results with du·dt_capital as the independent variable. Moreover, models (1) and (3) are free from the effect of any control variables, while models (2) and (4) include all relevant control variables. All regression analyses were conducted with control for area and year fixed effects and area-level clustering standard errors. As suggested by models (1) and (2), estimated coefficients in β were 0.2915 and 0.2720, respectively, and were both statistically significant, passing the significance level test of 1%. Additionally, the coefficients shown in models (3) and (4) were also both positive, while only the coefficient of Model (3) was statistically significant. On the whole, the positive coefficients indicate that with the implementation of the land quotas transactions, the urban–rural integration in the treatment group witnessed a significant increase. Furthermore, the coefficients in models (1) and (2) were higher than those in models (3) and (4), suggesting that land quota trading seemed to play a more crucial role than capital compensation payments. Subsequently, the following sections will primarily focus on the implementation of land quota trading, with du·dt_land being utilized as the core independent variable.

4.2.3. Heterogeneity Analysis

The regression analysis above demonstrates the promotion effect of TDR policy on urban–rural integration. Given the vast territorial area of Chongqing, there are variations in land resources, geographical conditions, and economic development among the districts and counties, which may lead to different effects of TDR policy on urban–rural integration. Therefore, it is necessary to examine the heterogeneity in the study area. Under the government’s implementation of a minimum price protection system, the income from Dipiao transactions is relatively consistent across different areas, while the land values exhibit regional variations.
We primarily focus on the influence of agricultural output value generated by farmland and industrial output resulting from construction land. (1) Agricultural output value per land unit (CNY/hectare per year). The agricultural output value per unit area of farmland in each district and county was sorted in ascending order. The districts and counties with agricultural land values above the median were considered to have higher agricultural land values, while those below the median were categorized as having lower agricultural land values. It is observed that districts and counties with lower farmland values tend to face challenges such as abandoned farmland and population outflow [84]. Additionally, farmers participating in Dipiao transactions are more likely to benefit from TDR policies in such areas. (2) Overall industrial labor productivity (CNY/person per year). The overall industrial labor productivity in each district and county was sorted in ascending order. The districts and counties with higher industrial production above the median were considered to have higher industrial land value, while those below the median were categorized as having lower industrial land value. The districts and counties with higher industrial land value are more likely to attract population from rural areas to urban areas, and TDR policies seem to have a greater effect on the integration of urban and rural populations in these areas.
Table 4 reports the heterogeneity analysis results, where models (1) to (4) represent the groups divided based on agricultural land value, while models (5) to (8) represent the groups divided according to industrial land value. To be precise, the control variables were absent in models (1), (3), (5), and (7) and were included in models (2), (4), (6), and (8). Comparing the results of the higher agricultural land value group and the lower agricultural land value group in models (1) to (4), the coefficients were negative in models (1) and (2), while they were positive in models (3) and (4), clearly indicating that TDR policy had a positive effect specifically in the districts and counties with lower agricultural land values. In comparing the results of the higher and lower industrial land value groups, it is observed that while each coefficient was positive in models (5) to (8), only models (5) and (6) showed statistical significance, passing the significance level test of 1%. The coefficients in Models (7) and (8) were not statistically significant. The results showed that the TDR policy had a positive effect, specifically in the districts and counties with higher industrial land values.

4.2.4. Placebo Test

Having controlled for a series of major observable area characteristics, it was not possible to control the influence of all the characteristics, especially the influence of those that were non-observable. Although dual fixed effects have been employed in the baseline regression analysis, some characteristics may have different influences over time, thus affecting the identification of the hypothesis. To further examine whether the urban–rural integration index was influenced by TDR policies rather than other factors, we adopted the indirect placebo test, which has been widely used in relevant studies. Specifically, we constructed ‘pseudo-policy dummy variables’ by randomly generating a low-carbon city list (experimental group) as a replacement for the variable d u × d t . The process was repeated 500 times and 1000 times, respectively, and the variables were estimated using Model (2). Given that the variables were randomly generated, it was expected that β = 0. In other words, if β was not equal to 0, it indicated that there were other characteristics affecting the estimation results.
Figure 7 portrays the distribution of the obtained estimates for 500 and 1000 repetitions of the ‘pseudo-policy dummy variables’, respectively. The results indicate that the mean values of β were nearly zero and were not statistically significant. This indicates that the non-observable variables did not have a significant effect on urban–rural integration, thereby further validating the robustness and replicability of the initial baseline regression results in this article.

5. Discussion

5.1. Why Does TDR Improve Urban–Rural Integration?

5.1.1. The Realization of Rural Land Development Rights Value

Given the current land system framework in China, rural land development rights are not considered a separate and distinct form of rights. Only when the transfer of rural land development rights is allowed can they temporarily have an independent form from the broader concept of land property rights. According to the theory of TDR, the value of land assets obtained by farmers in land-sending areas should be equivalent to the value of urban construction land development; however, it still remains much lower. Although the standard of eminent domain in Chongqing has increased in recent years, as indicated in the notice issued by the Chongqing Municipal Government on the compensation and resettlement standards for land acquisition in 2021, the compensation price for acquired rural land is approximately CNY 40,000 to 60,000 per mu. Based on the minimum protection policy established by the Chongqing government, the current transaction price of Dipiao in Chongqing is at least CNY 178,000 per mu. Although the Dipiao policy still cannot fully reflect the property value of rural land, at least the lowest trading price with Dipiao is significantly higher than the government’s compensation standards for land acquisition, thereby playing a positive role in narrowing the income gap between urban and rural residents.

5.1.2. Urbanization and Income Structure Transition

The compensation payment received from TDR is a one-off property income for rural landowners in the land-sending area. However, TDR can have an indirect and more profound impact on the income structure of rural residents. As the transfer of construction land quotas from rural areas to urban areas escalates, the rural population increasingly migrates to cities, resulting in a higher urbanization rate. Some researchers also found through interviews that the Dipiao policy presents farmers with equal opportunities for being involved in urbanization [38]. The shift in identity from farmer to migrant worker also signifies a transition in income structure, with wage income becoming dominant over operational income. Figure 8 presents the average per capita income statistics of rural residents in various districts and counties of Chongqing from 2013 to 2019, indicating that the wage income of rural residents consistently surpassed the income from operations. Therefore, TDR not only boosts short-term property income but also has the potential to influence an increase in wage income, ultimately exerting a consistent and enduring impact on rural economic development.

5.1.3. Government Preferences and Transfer Payment Characteristics

According to the comparison of the spatial patterns of urban–rural integration in Chongqing between 2013 and 2019, it is evident that the overall level of urban–rural integration was increasing. The growth was particularly pronounced in underdeveloped areas and counties located far from the city center. This can be attributed to the government’s prioritization of the underdeveloped districts and counties while promoting the Dipiao policy, leading to evident characteristics of transfer payments associated with Dipiao. By the end of 2022, more than 263,000 acres of land quotas had been traded under the ‘Dipiao’ policy in Chongqing, with a total value of over CNY 70 billion. It is noticeable that around three-quarters of these trading projects took place in poverty-stricken districts and counties, involving nearly CNY 52 billion and effectively contributing to poverty alleviation efforts. Additionally, in Chengdu’s Dipiao policy practice, poverty alleviation of farmers was often a major consideration for the local governments for approving TDR project proposals from applicants. Part of the revenue generated from land quota transactions was used to finance various rural development and revitalization projects [67]. The farmers who have given up their rural land development rights would receive compensation and resettlement housing in return. According to the interviews with those farmers, the living conditions in rural areas have considerably improved through the TDR projects [40]. However, the effect of TDR was various across different districts and counties is different. The average Dipiao transaction prices per acre of construction land had remained consistent regardless of the various districts or counties, consistently approaching the minimum protection price established by the government. As a result, districts and counties with varying levels of economic development might experience different policy effects from a similar amount of property income, with potentially greater impact observed in areas characterized by lower per capita income.

5.2. How to Optimize TDR Policy to Further Improve Urban–Rural Integration?

5.2.1. Enhancing Rural Land Rights and Facilitating Marketization of Land Development Rights

The Dipiao policy introduces a new approach for converting rural land into urban construction land within the current land system in China, yet it falls short of fully overcoming the constraints of the urban–rural dual land system. Essentially, rural land development rights still need to be further improved, which constitutes the fundamental prerequisite for promoting rural prosperity and urban–rural equal development. The implementation of TDR policies in China still remains predominantly a government-led process of adjusting and transferring land quotas, making it challenging to achieve true marketization within the context of a top-down annual land-use plan and predetermined urban construction land quotas.
The planned nature of Dipiao is also evident in terms of the transaction quantity and usage. Initially, the central government imposed planned control over the Dipiao transactions in Chongqing. In principle, the construction land quotas generated by Dipiao should not exceed 10% of the annual planned land-use quota. Although the central government later lifted restrictions on the scale of Dipiao transactions, the Chongqing Municipal Government continued to set its own annual planned land-use quota and dynamically adjusted it according to the annual land-use plan. The current construction land quotas formed in Dipiao transactions still exhibit high asset specificity, with only two-thirds of the transaction volume truly available for use, primarily acquired by state-owned enterprises [85]. Additionally, the urban–rural system is a complex system composed of various factors, and the transformation of urban–rural relations cannot be achieved in a short period of time. Therefore, even with optimization of the process and rules of the TDR policies, the effectiveness of enhancing urban–rural integration cannot be immediately realized.

5.2.2. Optimizing the TDR Process and Zoning Management

The time lag of the effectiveness of the Dipiao policies may result from the lengthy process in the issuance of Dipiao and the complexity of the urban–rural factor flow. An important principle of the TDR system is “reclamation before trading”. While this approach prevents the loss of cultivated land and ensures the quantity and quality of cultivated land after reclamation, it adversely impacts the interests of farmers. According to the current regulations governing Dipiao transactions, the entire process typically takes a minimum of 307 days to complete. In contrast, farmers often receive their monetary compensation one or two years afterward, or even longer, instead of immediately after the Dipiao trading.
It was found that the reclamation of cultivated land in areas with high output value has resulted in a widening urban–rural gap. This could be attributed to the fact that farmers in these areas already had high agricultural incomes, and the benefits derived from Dipiao transactions did not significantly promote further economic development. On the other hand, the significant promotion of urban–rural integration in areas with low output value can be attributed to the stronger impact of large-scale production resulting from cultivated land reclamation and the improvement of agricultural output value. For regions with lower agricultural income, the same income from Dipiao transactions has a greater impact on their production and livelihood. Therefore, the government should adopt a differentiated regional TDR policy that takes into consideration the various agricultural and industrial development characteristics and development needs of each district and county. To conduct zoning management, when approving Dipiao applications from land-sending areas, priority can be given to districts and counties with low cultivated land output value as well as those experiencing significant population loss.

6. Conclusions

The urban–rural divide in China has been exacerbated by the significant challenges associated with the dual land institution, which has long constrained the realization of urban–rural integration and rural revitalization. The introduction of TDR in China has partially facilitated rural–urban land transfers. As evidenced by the case of 37 districts and counties in Chongqing, TDR policy plays a positive role in narrowing the gap between rural and urban sectors in China.
The insights obtained from our empirical study and the theoretical framework should have significant implications for understanding the relationship between TDR and urban–rural integration. Nevertheless, there are also some important issues left out of our framework. While our results indicate a positive impact in Chongqing, it is worth noting that the applicability of TDR in promoting urban–rural integration in other regions of China might vary. Future research should expand its scope, drawing evidence from a more diverse array of cities or regions. It is crucial to acknowledge the limitations associated with the data employed in this study. This requires more systematic and long-term analyses, including data tracking and the incorporation of surveys, to provide more scientifically grounded policy implications for enhancing both urban–rural integration and land allocation efficiency.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Y.W. and L.T.; methodology, Y.W. and Z.W.; validation, Y.W., Y.G. and L.T.; formal analysis, Y.W., Z.W. and C.W.; data curation, Y.W. and Y.G.; writing—original draft preparation, Y.W.; writing—review and editing, Y.W., L.T., C.W. and Y.G.; visualization, Y.W.; supervision, L.T.; funding acquisition, L.T. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the Beijing Outstanding Young Scientist Program (JJWZYJH01201910003010).

Data Availability Statement

Publicly available sources of the data used in this study are described in the article; for other data used, please contact the corresponding author on reasonable grounds. The data of the Dipiao transaction amount can be found on the following websites: http://nyncw.cq.gov.cn/ (accessed on 20 August 2023).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Notes

1
In this context, ‘flow of land’ refers to the transfer of development rights.
2
The concept of ‘land development rights’ has not been introduced within China’s legal framework. However, it is widely accepted that land development rights in China are typically categorized based on the differentiation between urban and rural land ownership.

References

  1. Liu, Y. Research on the urban-rural integration and rural revitalization in the new era in China. Acta Geogr. Sin. 2018, 73, 637–650. [Google Scholar]
  2. Ma, L.; Liu, S.; Fang, F.; Che, X.; Chen, M. Evaluation of urban-rural difference and integration based on quality of life. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2020, 54, 101877. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Mcfarland, C.K.; Grabowski, E.H. Local employment impacts of connectivity to regional economies: The role of industry clusters in bridging the urban-rural divide. Eco. Dev. Q. 2022, 36, 317–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Van Vliet, J.; Verburg, P.H.; Gradinaru, S.R.; Hersperger, A.M. Beyond the urban-rural dichotomy: Towards a more nuanced analysis of changes in built-up land. Comput. Environ. Urban Syst. 2019, 74, 41–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Kastrop, C.; Ponattu, D.; Schmidt, J.; Schmidt, S. The urban-rural divide and regionally inclusive growth in the digital age. In G20 Insights Policy Area: Inequality, Human Capital and Well-Being; Think20 (T20): Tokyo, Japan, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  6. Hersperger, A.M.; Grădinaru, S.R.; Siedentop, S. Towards a better understanding of land conversion at the urban-rural interface: Planning intentions and the effectiveness of growth management. J. Land Use Sci. 2020, 15, 644–651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Long, H.; Zhang, Y.; Tu, S. Rural vitalization in China: A perspective of land consolidation. J. Geog. Sci. 2019, 29, 517–530. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Xiuling, C.; Guizhen, C. Two way allocation of urban and rural factors in the process of Rural Revitalization and urbanization. Soc. Sci. Res. 2018, 51–58. [Google Scholar]
  9. Biliang, L. Clarify development ideas and implement Rural Revitalization Strategy. South China J. Econ. 2017, 8–11. [Google Scholar]
  10. Xiangyang, W.; Jing, T.; Xuefeng, S. The oretical framework and policy suggestions to the two-way flow of urban-rural elements. Issues Agric. Econ. 2020, 10, 61–67. [Google Scholar]
  11. Li, T. Dilemma of double-track land system in urban-rural coordinated planning lmplementation: An exploration of reform in land property rights. Urban Plann. Forum. 2013, 18–22. [Google Scholar]
  12. Cao, W.; Zhou, S.; Zhou, M. Operational pattern of urban-rural integration regulated by land use in metropolitan fringe of China. Land 2021, 10, 515. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Qiao, S.; Upham, F. Evolution of relational property rights: A case of chinese rural land reform. Iowa L. Rev. 2014, 100, 2479. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Tian, L.; Yan, Y.; Wu, Y.; Shao, L. Breaking the land monopoly: Can collective land reform alleviate the housing shortage in China’s mega-cities? Cities 2020, 106, 102878. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Tian, L.; Guo, X.; Yin, W. From urban sprawl to land consolidation in suburban shanghai under the backdrop of increasing versus decreasing balance policy: A perspective of property rights transfer. Urban Stud. 2017, 54, 878–896. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Lu, Q.; Yao, S. From urban-rural division to urban-rural integration: A systematic cost explanation and chengdu’s experience. China World Econ. 2018, 26, 86–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Jianwei, S. How to solve the “meta-problem” in urban-rural land exchange: An analysis based on the perspective of new rights. Explor. Free Views 2021, 160, 167–180. [Google Scholar]
  18. Micelli, E. Development rights markets to manage urban plans in italy. Urban Stud. 2002, 39, 141–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Renard, V. Property rights and the’transfer of development rights’: Questions of efficiency and equity. Town Plann. Rev. 2007, 78, 41–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Barrese, J.T. Efficiency and equity considerations in the operation of transfer of development rights plans. Land Econ. 1983, 59, 235–241. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Messer, K.D. Transferable development rights programs: An economic framework for success. J. Conserv. Plann. 2007, 3, 47–56. [Google Scholar]
  22. Kaplowitz, M.D.; Machemer, P.; Pruetz, R. Planners’ experiences in managing growth using transferable development rights (tdr) in the united states. Land Use Policy 2008, 25, 378–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Guzle, G.; Akpınar, F.; Duvarcı, Y. Transfer of development rights for the effectiveness of the conservation plans: A case from historic kemeraltı, izmir. Habitat Int. 2020, 103, 102207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Hou, J.; Chan, E.H.; Li, L. Transfer of development rights as an institutional innovation to address issues of property rights. J. Hous. Built Environ. 2018, 33, 465–479. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Colavitti, A.M.; Serra, S. The transfer of development rights as a tool for the urban growth containment: A comparison between the united states and italy. Pap. Reg. Sci. 2018, 97, 1247–1265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Jin, H.; Hongxia, C. Evaluation on the Linkage Policy of increase and decrease of urban and rural construction land: Based on literature review. Nat. Resour. Econ. China 2021, 34, 82–89. [Google Scholar]
  27. Huizhi, G.; Zijian, L.; Tianyu, Z.; Yilun, L.; Zhijie, X.; Wei, T. The impact of land factor marketization reform on urban and rural development under the dual-circulation system. J. Urban Stud. 2020, 41, 45–52. [Google Scholar]
  28. Fei, Z. Research on the mechanism and effect of “linkage between urban-land taking and rural-land giving”(LUTRG) on urban-rural integrated development. Acad. J. Zhongzhou 2016, 8, 35–40. [Google Scholar]
  29. Ye, Y. Systematic framework and practical approach for coordinated urban-rural development in China. Urban Plann. Forum. 2013, 79, 1–9. [Google Scholar]
  30. Peng, M.; Huang, H. A study on the extended application of increase and decrease link between urban and rural construction land in territorial planning: From the perspective of transfer of land development rights. City Plann. Rev. 2021, 45, 24–32. [Google Scholar]
  31. He, M. Land development rights as a public policy: Thoughts on establishing a unified construction land market in urban and rural areas. City Plann. Rev. 2022, 46, 14–20. [Google Scholar]
  32. Wei, C.; Shenglu, Z.; Shaohua, W.; Jun, W.; Yong, L.; Lifeng, C. Research progress on land use in urban-rural integration. Chin. J. Agric. Resour. Reg. Plann. 2013, 34, 8–15. [Google Scholar]
  33. Wangjun, L.; Changhe, L. Perspective on the policy of gain-loss balance of urban and rural construction land in China. Chin. J. Agric. Resour. Reg. Plann. 2013, 34, 16–21. [Google Scholar]
  34. Kong, X.; Liu, Y.; Jiang, P.; Tian, Y.; Zou, Y. A novel framework for rural homestead land transfer under collective ownership in China. Land Use Policy 2018, 78, 138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Chen, C.; Yu, L.; Choguill, C.L. “Dipiao”, chinese approach to transfer of land development rights: The experiences of chongqing. Land Use Policy 2020, 99, 104870. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Wilmsen, B. Expanding capitalism in rural China through land acquisition and land reforms. J. Contemp. China 2016, 25, 701–717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Zhang, Y. Grabbing land for equitable development? Reengineering land dispossession through securitising land development rights in chongqing. Antipode 2018, 50, 1120–1140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Hu, W. Evaluating the ‘dipiao’ policy from the perspectives of relocated peasants: An equitable and sustainable approach to urbanisation? Urban Res. Pract. 2022, 15, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Wang, H.; He, C.; Li, W.; Nie, X.; Zhong, H.; Wen, L. Will transferable development rights (tdr) increase regional economic imbalance?—A quota transaction case of cultivated land conversion and reclamation in Guangxi, China. Habitat Int. 2020, 104, 102254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Shi, C.; Tang, B.-S. Institutional change and diversity in the transfer of land development rights in China: The case of chengdu. Urban Stud. 2020, 57, 473–489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Xuefeng, H. The logic and fallacy of the policy of linking the increase and decrease of urban and rural construction land. Acad. Mon. 2019, 51, 96–104. [Google Scholar]
  42. Zhenxing, B.; Li, Q.; Hongbin, L.; Hongwu, J.; Limei, C. Research on land appreciation benefits in the link of urban and rural construction land increase and decrease: Based on the perspective of land development rights. Chin. J. Agric. Resour. Reg. Plann. 2016, 37, 55–61. [Google Scholar]
  43. Simandan, D. The wise stance in human geography. Trans. Inst. Br. Geogr. 2011, 36, 188–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Landemore, H.; Elster, J. Collective Wisdom: Principles and Mechanisms; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  45. Blackwell, A.; Colmenar, R. Transforming policy through local wisdom. Futures 1999, 31, 487–497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Zhanlu, Z.; Penghui, L. The impact and mechanism of land development rights trading on urban rural income gap: A case study of Chongqing land tickets practice. Chin. Rural Econ. 2022, 3, 36–49. [Google Scholar]
  47. Shaofu, Z.; Shunwei, X. The impact of market mechanism introduction on residents’ income under the coordination of urban and rural construction land use: An empirical test based on the Chongqing land ticket trading system. Urban Probl. 2021, 14, 22–60. [Google Scholar]
  48. Jing, Z.; Hongrui, Z. Evaluation and mechanism analysis of land ticket system based on composite control method. Sci. Technol. Manag. Land Resour. 2022, 39, 78–91. [Google Scholar]
  49. Xuming, M.; Dan, D. Rural collective construction land transfer and industrial structure adjustment: Evidence from the land coupon policy. Econ. Perspect. 2020, 3, 86–102. [Google Scholar]
  50. Zhou, D.; Qi, J.; Zhong, W. Review of urban-rural integration evaluation: Connotation identification, theoretical analysis, and system reconstruction. J. Nat. Resour. 2021, 36, 2634–2651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Johnston, R.A.; Madison, M.E. From land marks to landscapes: A review of current practices in the transfer of development rights. J. Am. Plann. Assoc. 1997, 63, 365–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Fulton, W.; Mazurek, J.; Pruetz, R.; Williamson, C. Tdrs and Other Market-Based Land Mechanisms: How They Work and Their Role In Shaping Metropolitan Growth; The Brookings Institution: Washington, DC, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  53. Tavares, A. Can the Market be Used to Preserve Land? The Case for Transfer of Development Rights. In Proceedings of the 43rd Congress of the European Regional Science Association: Peripheries, Centres, and Spatial Development in the New Europe, Jyväskylä, Finland, 27–30 August 2003. [Google Scholar]
  54. Linkous, E.R. Transfer of development rights in theory and practice: The restructuring of tdr to incentivize development. Land Use Policy 2016, 51, 162–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Shi, C.; Zhang, Z. Institutional diversity of transferring land development rights in China: Cases from zhejiang, hubei, and sichuan. Sustainability 2021, 13, 13402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Wang, H.; Tao, R.; Tong, J. Trading land development rights under a planned land use system: The “Zhejiang model”. China World Econ. 2009, 17, 66–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Wang, H.; Tao, R.; Wang, L.; Su, F. Farmland preservation and land development rights trading in Zhejiang, China. Habitat Int. 2010, 34, 454–463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Liu, Y.; Fan, P.; Yue, W.; Song, Y. Impacts of land finance on urban sprawl in China: The case of Chongqing. Land Use Policy 2018, 72, 420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Wang, J.; Li, Y.; Wang, Q.; Cheong, K.C. Urban–rural construction land replacement for more sustainable land use and regional development in China: Policies and practices. Land 2019, 8, 171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Lafarguette, R. Chongqing: Model for a new economic and social policy? China Perspect. 2011, 2011, 62–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Cui, S.; Zhou, G.; Dai, L.; Wu, G.; He, Y. Research progress and prospects of urban-rural integrated development based on geographical perspective. Econ. Geogr. 2022, 42, 104–113. [Google Scholar]
  62. Chen, K.; Long, H. Impacts of land market on urban-rural integrated development in China. J. Nat. Resour. 2019, 34, 221–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Yan, J.; Chen, H.; Xia, F. Toward improved land elements for urban-rural integration: A cell concept of an urban-rural mixed community. Habitat Int. 2018, 77, 110–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Shouying, L.; Tingyu, L. The theory of urban-rural integration: Stages, characteristics and enlightenment. Econ. Perspect. 2022, 3, 21–34. [Google Scholar]
  65. Hua, G. Urban and rural “third pole” and the risk response of county urbanization: From the perspective of the comparison between central-western and eastern regions. Acad. J. Zhongzhou 2022, 2, 61–69. [Google Scholar]
  66. Zhanlu, Z.; Yating, Z.; Yan, Y.; Qianyu, Z. Enlightenment of land development right allocation and transfer theory to the reform of homestead in China. Stud. Pract. 2019, 5, 33–41. [Google Scholar]
  67. Zhang, Q.F.; Wu, J. Political dynamics in land commodification: Commodifying rural land development rights in Chengdu, China. Geoforum 2017, 78, 98–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Peng, Z.; Chunxin, L. Exploration of urban and rural land ticket transaction based on the perspective of land development right and institutional change—Analysis of Chongqing model. Reform Econ. Syst. 2010, 5, 103–107. [Google Scholar]
  69. Wang, B.; Li, F.; Feng, S.; Shen, T. Transfer of development rights, farmland preservation, and economic growth: A case study of chongqing’s land quotas trading program. Land Use Policy 2020, 95, 104611. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Tan, R.; Wang, R.; Heerink, N. Liberalizing rural-to-urban construction land transfers in China: Distribution effects. China Econ. Rev. 2020, 60, 101147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Anlu, Z. The mechanism and institutional innovation of agricultural land and urban land transfer in the urban rural ecological economic interlaced zone. Rural Econ. 1999, 43–49. [Google Scholar]
  72. Yep, R.; Forrest, R. Elevating the peasants into high-rise apartments: The land bill system in chongqing as a solution for land conflicts in China? J. Rural. Stud. 2016, 47, 474–484. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Yep, R. Local alliances in rural urbanization: Land transfer in contemporary China. China Inf. 2020, 34, 168–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Bao, H.X.; Li, L.; Lizieri, C. City profile: Chongqing (1997–2017). Cities 2019, 94, 161–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Long, H.; Liu, Y. Rural restructuring in China. J. Rural Stud. 2016, 47, 387–391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Hanlong, G.; Shuyi, F.; Zhilin, Z.; Futian, Q. A comparative study between the hook of urban construction land increase and rural residential land decrease policy in China and transferable development rights policy in US. Econ. Geogr. 2015, 35, 143–148+183. [Google Scholar]
  77. Zhou, J.; Zou, W.; Qin, F. Review of urban-rural multi-dimensional integration and influencing factors in China based on the concept of equivalence. Geogr. Res. 2020, 39, 1836–1851. [Google Scholar]
  78. Zhou, J.; Qin, F.; Liu, J.; Zhu, G.; Zou, W. Measurement, spatial-temporal evolution and influencing mechanism of urban-rural integration level in China from a multidimensional perspective. China Popul. Res. Env. 2019, 29, 166–176. [Google Scholar]
  79. Xie, S.; Zhou, F.; Wu, T.; Fu, C. Evaluation and spatial pattern evolution of urban and rural integrated development in the yangtze river delta. Urban Stud. 2020, 27, 28–32. [Google Scholar]
  80. Hou, Y.; Zhang, K.; Zhu, Y.; Liu, W. Spatial and temporal differentiation and influencing factors of environmental governance performance in the yangtze river delta, China. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 801, 149699. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  81. Chen, K.; Long, H.; Liao, L.; Tu, S.; Li, T. Land use transitions and urban-rural integrated development: Theoretical framework and China’s evidence. Land Use Policy 2020, 92, 104465. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Liu, W.; Dunford, M.; Song, Z.; Chen, M. Urban–rural integration drives regional economic growth in chongqing, western China. Area Dev. Policy 2016, 1, 132–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Beck, T.; Levine, R.; Levkov, A. Big bad banks? The winners and losers from bank deregulation in the united states. J. Financ. 2010, 65, 1637–1667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Tianli, L. Farmers’ willingness to return residential land and the influence factors: Taking the survey made in Xunyang county of Shaanxi province as an example. J. Anhui Agric. Univ. 2016, 25, 1–5. [Google Scholar]
  85. Lanjiao, W.; Anlu, Z. Relationship among Institutional Innovation of Land Coupon, MarketMechanism of Land Development Right and Fulfillment of Rural Land Assets Value. China Land Sci. 2016, 115, 33–40. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. The Dipiao transaction process in Chongqing.
Figure 1. The Dipiao transaction process in Chongqing.
Land 12 02045 g001
Figure 2. The theoretical framework between TDR and urban–rural integration.
Figure 2. The theoretical framework between TDR and urban–rural integration.
Land 12 02045 g002
Figure 3. Research methodology diagram.
Figure 3. Research methodology diagram.
Land 12 02045 g003
Figure 4. The location and administrative division of the study area.
Figure 4. The location and administrative division of the study area.
Land 12 02045 g004
Figure 5. Income gap between urban and rural residents in Chongqing.
Figure 5. Income gap between urban and rural residents in Chongqing.
Land 12 02045 g005
Figure 6. The distribution characteristics of urban–rural integration index in Chongqing (2013–2019).
Figure 6. The distribution characteristics of urban–rural integration index in Chongqing (2013–2019).
Land 12 02045 g006
Figure 7. The results of the placebo test.
Figure 7. The results of the placebo test.
Land 12 02045 g007
Figure 8. The average income of rural residents in Chongqing (2013–2019).
Figure 8. The average income of rural residents in Chongqing (2013–2019).
Land 12 02045 g008
Table 1. Urban–rural integration evaluation index system.
Table 1. Urban–rural integration evaluation index system.
Primary IndicatorsIDSecondary IndicatorsCalculation MethodUnitIndicator Type
Economic integrationE1Ratio of urban–rural residents’ per capita disposable incomePer capita disposable income of urban households/per capita disposable income of rural households%Negative
E2Ratio of urban–rural residents’ per capita wage and salary incomePer capita wage and salary income of urban households/per capita wage and salary income of rural households%Negative
E3Ratio of urban–rural residents’ per capita property incomePer capita property income of urban households/per capita property income of rural households%Negative
E4Ratio of urban–rural residents’ per capita consumption expenditurePer capita consumption expenditure of urban households/per capita consumption expenditure of rural household%Negative
E5Ratio of urban–rural Engel coefficientThe ratio of food expenditure to total consumption expenditure of urban households/the ratio of food expenditure to total consumption expenditure of rural households%Positive
E6Proportion of the output value of the secondary and tertiary industryThe logarithm of the proportion of the sum of the output value of the secondary and tertiary sectors to the regional gross domestic product%Positive
Population integrationP1Urbanization rateUrban population/permanent resident population%Positive
P2Proportion of registered population in the permanent resident populationRegistered population/permanent resident population%Positive
P3Urban–rural disparity coefficient of employment proportionThe proportion of employed persons to resident population of urban households—the proportion of employed persons to resident population of rural households%Negative
P4Ratio of urban–rural employed populationThe number of employed people within urban households/the number of employed people within rural households%Negative
Social
integration
S1Population coverage rate of broadcast programs-%Positive
S2Number of hospital beds per thousand people in health institutionsThe logarithm of the number of hospital beds in health institutions/population at the year-end (1000 persons)Beds/
1000 persons
Positive
S3Number of medical technical personnel per thousand people in health institutionsThe logarithm of the number of medical technical personnel/population at the year-end (1000 persons)Persons/
1000 persons
Positive
S4Ratio of urban–rural per capita transport and communications expenditurePer capita transport and communications expenditure of urban households/per capita transport and communications expenditure of rural household%Negative
S5Ratio of urban–rural per capita education, cultural, and recreation expenditurePer capita education, cultural and recreation of urban households/per capita education, cultural, and recreation expenditure of rural household%Negative
S6Ratio of urban–rural per capita healthcare and medical services expenditurePer capita healthcare and medical services of urban households/per capita healthcare and medical services expenditure of rural household%Negative
Table 2. Score of urban–rural integration index.
Table 2. Score of urban–rural integration index.
Districts and Counties2013201420152016201720182019
Wanzhou District3.10003.16493.21383.26153.35303.41173.5103
Fuling District3.29173.30333.40563.47583.73253.77413.8692
Dadukou District4.70004.93875.09545.66185.57955.27665.4547
Jiangbei District5.54875.75915.92146.03306.44006.82126.8793
Shapingba District4.80724.83765.11924.94434.92545.03695.1503
Jiulongpo District4.75234.57794.80334.76954.90694.85074.8879
Nan’an District4.07853.96074.26564.42774.48074.68164.7285
Beibei District4.26394.39394.51234.54084.33244.73864.6020
Qijiang District3.08242.99342.88203.22612.85733.61483.9047
Dazu District2.31662.55173.00722.69882.47992.86313.2120
Yubei District3.17653.30293.62323.81583.67023.81273.8656
Ba’nan District3.64913.76094.00984.04344.28424.26204.2618
Qianjiang District2.60482.81842.89202.92023.04603.26273.2079
Changshou District3.30093.28613.43473.39153.58893.64373.9474
Jiangjin District2.77942.75802.91963.02893.26983.32193.4866
Hechuan District2.70722.65192.87913.01623.31373.43913.5416
Yongchuan District3.26243.26613.08493.24423.33613.64233.7447
Nanchuan District2.19862.32782.21272.32732.99993.11423.2380
Bishan District3.06932.87052.81773.45503.57873.60433.6695
Tongliang District2.47822.58812.98043.18503.26073.42393.5283
Tongnan District1.58512.29992.15552.39142.67152.60762.7606
Rongchang District3.00902.70952.94963.08523.12403.43923.6185
Kaizhou District1.92152.12052.13241.89532.06822.48382.4934
Liangping District2.16532.23262.50592.40892.48462.11652.2574
Wulong District1.80932.05231.97042.42772.50732.64092.7843
Chengkou County1.11251.18291.06911.58001.89212.16852.0698
Fengdu County1.74501.77372.02782.10912.37722.73292.9756
Dianjiang County2.28111.88502.00822.21502.40292.72822.8725
Zhongxian County1.71712.04302.25272.27612.45312.69902.8726
Yunyang County1.06701.18921.40231.45081.69552.03662.5631
Fengjie County1.58951.59091.66181.87941.89682.27942.4554
Wushan County0.79250.68111.01221.27921.80492.28052.5866
Wuxi County2.07322.21912.09112.84872.86252.99961.7962
Shizhu County1.65961.79532.16912.39562.78102.92363.0070
Xiushan County1.52071.58961.78302.03032.05282.42502.5737
Youyang County0.96481.30041.90881.82021.92492.03672.1829
Pengshui County1.10900.79680.76111.00851.22291.53921.6758
Table 3. The effect of TDR on urban–rural integration in Chongqing between 2013 and 2019.
Table 3. The effect of TDR on urban–rural integration in Chongqing between 2013 and 2019.
Independent VariableDependent Variable: Urban–Rural Integration Index
Model (1)Model (2)Model (3)Model (4)
du·dt_land0.2915 ***0.2720 ***
(0.0907)(0.072)
du·dt_capital 0.1446 *0.1007
(0.0848)(0.0822)
d1 0.0017 *** 0.0017 ***
(0.0004) (0.0004)
d2 0.0032 0.0038
(0.0047) (0.0048)
d3 0.0001 * 0.0001 *
(0.0001) (0.0001)
d4 0.0000 −0.0001
(0.0003) (0.0003)
d5 −0.0004 −0.0004
(0.0009) (0.0009)
d6 −0.0003 −0.0003
(0.0002) (0.0002)
Constant−0.3573 ***−1.3408 ***−0.2066 **−1.1430 ***
(0.0849)(0.3046)(0.0806)(0.3211)
Observations259259259259
Year FEYesYesYesYes
Area FEYesYesYesYes
R-square0.97290.97910.97250.9786
Note: *, **, and *** represent 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels, respectively. Standard errors are clustered by area in parentheses.
Table 4. The heterogeneity analysis results.
Table 4. The heterogeneity analysis results.
Independent VariableDependent Variable: Urban–Rural Integration Level
Higher Agricultural Land ValueLower Agricultural Land ValueHigher Industrial Land ValueLower Industrial Land Value
Model (1)Model (2)Model (3)Model (4)Model (5)Model (6)Model (7)Model (8)
du·dt_land−2.9020 ***−2.7216 ***0.2926 ***0.3158 ***0.4398 ***0.4270 ***0.00500.080009
(0.0000)(0.0794)(0.0961)(0.0635)(0.0889)(0.0683)(0.0627)(0.0719)
d1 0.0007 0.0022 *** 0.0009 *** 0.0022 ***
(0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0002) (0.0004)
d2 0.0038 −0.0033 −0.0026 0.0183 ***
(0.0063) (0.0067) (0.0049) (0.0060)
d3 0.0001 ** −0.0007 0.0002 *** −0.0023 ***
(0.0001) (0.0008) 0.0000) (0.0006)
d4 −0.0001 0.0009 0.0001 −0.0003
(0.0004) (0.0008) (0.0003) (0.0005)
d5 −0.0007 0.0010 −0.0008 0.0030 *
(0.0009) (0.0015) (0.0008) (0.0014)
d6 −0.0002 −0.0016 −0.0000 −0.0004 **
(0.0002) (0.0024) (0.0000) (0.0001)
Constant1.9502 ***1.4609 ***−0.4278 ***−1.4552 **−0.4330 ***−0.7506 ***1.8155 ***1.0010 ***
(0.0475)(0.3039)(0.0742)(0.6627)(0.0769)(0.2524)(0.0537)(0.2929)
Observations126126126126126126126126
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Area FEYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
R-square0.97530.97920.90850.94210.98540.98910.96000.9779
Note: *, **, and *** represent 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels, respectively. Standard errors are clustered by area in parentheses.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, Y.; Tian, L.; Wang, Z.; Wang, C.; Gao, Y. Effects of Transfer of Land Development Rights on Urban–Rural Integration: Theoretical Framework and Evidence from Chongqing, China. Land 2023, 12, 2045. https://doi.org/10.3390/land12112045

AMA Style

Wang Y, Tian L, Wang Z, Wang C, Gao Y. Effects of Transfer of Land Development Rights on Urban–Rural Integration: Theoretical Framework and Evidence from Chongqing, China. Land. 2023; 12(11):2045. https://doi.org/10.3390/land12112045

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Yu, Li Tian, Ziyi Wang, Chenyue Wang, and Yuan Gao. 2023. "Effects of Transfer of Land Development Rights on Urban–Rural Integration: Theoretical Framework and Evidence from Chongqing, China" Land 12, no. 11: 2045. https://doi.org/10.3390/land12112045

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop