Next Article in Journal
Stakeholder Engagement: Achieving Sustainability in the Construction Sector
Previous Article in Journal
The Effects of Isolation and Natural Park Coverage for Landrace In situ Conservation: An Approach from the Montseny Mountains (NE Spain)
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

Ten Reasons to Take Peak Oil Seriously

Physics Department, Renewable and Clean Energy Program, Sustainability, Energy and the Environment (SEE) Program, University of Dayton, Dayton, OH 45469-2314, USA
Sustainability 2013, 5(2), 664-694; https://doi.org/10.3390/su5020664
Submission received: 3 December 2012 / Revised: 30 January 2013 / Accepted: 1 February 2013 / Published: 12 February 2013

Abstract

:
Forty years ago, the results of modeling, as presented in The Limits to Growth, reinvigorated a discussion about exponentially growing consumption of natural resources, ranging from metals to fossil fuels to atmospheric capacity, and how such consumption could not continue far into the future. Fifteen years earlier, M. King Hubbert had made the projection that petroleum production in the continental United States would likely reach a maximum around 1970, followed by a world production maximum a few decades later. The debate about “peak oil”, as it has come to be called, is accompanied by some of the same vociferous denials, myths and ideological polemicizing that have surrounded later representations of The Limits to Growth. In this review, we present several lines of evidence as to why arguments for a near-term peak in world conventional oil production should be taken seriously—both in the sense that there is strong evidence for peak oil and in the sense that being societally unprepared for declining oil production will have serious consequences.

1. Introduction

The depletion of non-renewable natural resources was clearly seen to be one of the key factors in The Limits to Growth [1]. Due to the high level of aggregation used in the first versions of the World3 model, there was no specific analysis of individual resources, such as oil. However, soon after the publication of Limits to Growth (LtG), the world experienced the first oil shock; the consequences of natural resource shortage, albeit artificially induced, became painfully clear.
There have been two updates published by some of the authors of the original LtG, as well as several other reviews of LtG. Some attempts were made to look more specifically at individual resources, going beyond the highly aggregated variable of the original LtG [2,3]. To a lesser degree, assessments were also made of the reliability of the projections made in the original work [4].
Fifteen years prior to LtG, M. King Hubbert had also used the simple idea that unlimited exponential growth cannot be maintained in a finite system to project that oil production in the continental US would likely reach a maximum in the late 1960s and go into decline thereafter, depending on the assumed total amount of recoverable oil [5]. Much as there are many who deny the possibility of biospheric limits to growth in general, often expressed through misrepresentations of the techniques and message of LtG, Hubbert’s work has also been maligned. Although US production of crude oil did peak in 1970, the potential for an extension of “peak oil” to world resources has not been part of public consciousness. The goal of this review is to approach the idea of peak oil from different angles and to construct a solid case that there is enough evidence of a near-term peak in world crude oil production that one cannot afford not to take the possibility seriously.
The concept of peak oil is unfortunately surrounded by a large cloud of uncertainty. In fact, trying to understand the exact details of the timing of peak production for any fossil fuel resource is difficult, partly because the size of the resource in the ground is poorly known. Beyond questions of geology, there are multiple interactions between economic drivers and oil production, with GDP growth and oil consumption being highly correlated; in addition, there are greater incentives to explore for more oil driven by high prices in the face of strong demand. Eventually, there will also be viable large-scale substitutes available for oil, although replacing a raw material that is so integral to industrialized society will take a long period of time. These properties of complex interacting systems are at the core of the LtG analysis. In the end, however, it is difficult to deny that a finite resource must at some point reach a maximum in extraction rate, after which production will decline. Extraction of conventional oil commenced in 1859 and has now reached a production rate of approximately 27 Gb/a (billion barrels per year) over the past several years [6]. (Here, we define conventional oil as crude oil plus lease condensate and do not include in this category extra-heavy oil, oil sands, natural gas liquids, light tight (shale) oil or biofuels; one barrel is 42 gallons or 159 liters.) The importance of the potential for a near-term peak in world oil production is obvious: modern society has grown so dependent on supplies of liquid fuels that a lack thereof would likely have severe consequences for economic growth and development [7,8]. As has been frequently pointed out by other authors [9], the timing of peak production compared to society’s prior preparations is the key issue.
The discussion of finite fossil-fuel resources goes back to the late-eighteenth century, when William Stanley Jevons speculated that British production of coal, which had been increasing at a fairly constant exponential growth rate for many decades, could not possibly maintain that same growth far into the future [10]. Jevons’s son took up the same issue a half-century later and, with the help of the British Geological Survey, came to the conclusion that Great Britain had large enough resources to comfortably last a few centuries, even in the face of increasing demand [11]. In fact, production of coal did peak in Britain at about the time of the First World War and has declined ever since. At the same time, however, it is interesting to note that Jevons was worried about coal production exactly because he thought of coal as being a necessary pre-requisite for British economic might and could not conceive of a substitute that would be as useful and plentiful; even mentioning oil as a resource that would not be able to take the place of coal. Thus, we have in the writings of one family of economists and natural scientists the essence of the tension seen in the current peak oil debate; a warning about the danger of depleting crucial finite resources and the overconfidence of projections about plentiful future resources.
As has often been pointed out [12,13], from the earliest days of oil production, there have been claims that the world would be running out of oil “soon”. While it is clear that the world has not run out of oil, Hubbert’s projections for the US, correct in the timing of peak production and within about 10% of the peak rate of production, served to temporarily generate discussion about finite resources and the need for alternatives. In 1998, Colin Campbell and Jean Lahererre [14] published an article that catalyzed a much more serious interest in peak oil. After that article, at least 25 books were published on various aspects of peak oil by 2007 (see [15] for a list). Interestingly, until about 2007, there were very few peer-reviewed publications about peak oil; since then, the list of papers has exploded. Many of the papers were reviewed or referenced in a 2009 report by the UK Energy Research Center [16], and the number has continued to increase rapidly since that report was published. At the same time, we have seen in the past few years renewed rejections of the immediacy of a peak in world oil production, partially because of the emergence of the techniques of hydraulic fracturing (fracking) and horizontal drilling to extract light oil from tight formations. Although this has currently lead to an increase in production of oil in the United States, even optimistic estimates of the total resource available do not lead to the conclusion that this source will provide more than a temporary relief of pressure on world oil supplies.
In the following discussion of ten reasons to take peak oil seriously, the focus will be on production of crude oil. While it is clear that there are other sources of liquid fuels (oil sands, oil from tight shale formations, natural gas liquids, biofuels, etc.) and that to some extent these will be viable substitutes for crude oil, for the most part, each of these represents an expensive alternative to past supplies of relatively cheap crude oil and each requires significantly higher energy inputs to extract and process, thereby decreasing the net amount of energy available for society. Once cheaply available conventional oil is no longer available, the dynamics of the energy system change. The arguments are presented in separate sections, with no particular order of importance, followed by a discussion of peak oil consequences and a conclusion. Figure 1 shows the current distribution in world production of various liquid fuel resources.
Figure 1. Data from the US Energy Information Administration [6]; the relative shares of different liquid fuels in 2011.
Figure 1. Data from the US Energy Information Administration [6]; the relative shares of different liquid fuels in 2011.
Sustainability 05 00664 g001

2. Ten Reasons to Take Peak Oil Seriously

2.1. Stagnating Supplies

World production of crude oil has not increased for over seven years, through periods of both low and high economic growth. Figure 2 shows data from the US Energy Information Administration for world production of both crude oil alone (blue) and for total liquids (red) [6]. Looking first at the bottom curve, production of crude oil did not change at all (in a statistically significant sense) during the strong economic growth of 2005–2008. There was a decline in production, driven by consumption decreases, in 2008–2009, followed by a slow increase back to pre-economic-downturn levels. Turmoil in the Middle East and North Africa contributed to the subsequent decrease in production in early 2011. In the upper curve in Figure 2, there is a slight increase in total world supply of liquid fuels. Therefore, given the non-increasing production of conventional oil, the increase in volume of total liquids must come from other sources; the data show increases, particularly in natural gas liquids, biofuels and, to a lesser extent, heavy oil, tar sands and shale oil.
Figure 2. World supply of conventional crude oil (bottom curve) and total liquids, including biofuels, oil sands, shale oil, natural gas liquids and refinery processing gain (top curve). Data from US Energy Information Administration, International Energy Statistics [6].
Figure 2. World supply of conventional crude oil (bottom curve) and total liquids, including biofuels, oil sands, shale oil, natural gas liquids and refinery processing gain (top curve). Data from US Energy Information Administration, International Energy Statistics [6].
Sustainability 05 00664 g002
As this trend toward liquid fuels other than conventional crude oil continues, two important points are worth noting. First, in Figure 2, we show a volumetric measure of fuels, as opposed to gross energy content of those fuels. Both natural gas liquids and biofuels have volumetric energy densities that are only 60% that of conventional crude oil; demand is for the actual useful energy provided by fuels and, therefore, requires additional volume if energy density decreases. Plotting energy vs. time shows a slightly smaller upward trend, but this discrepancy will increase with time in the future. The second point is that nonconventional liquid fuels, including biofuels, require higher energy inputs for extraction, processing, refining and transport than conventional oil. Although some of the energy input may be in the form of carriers other than the liquid fuels themselves, the move toward nonconventional fuels points to a need to account for net energy use for each sector, since it is the total energy system that is of fundamental interest. Furthermore, even in the case of conventional oil production, the energy return on energy invested (EROEI) in extraction has been decreasing over time, implying that a given amount of final liquid fuel energy (mainly for transportation, but in some areas, for electricity generation as well) itself requires energy consumption that would otherwise be available for other sectors of the total system [17].
An argument against concern about peak oil is precisely that we will find suitable, if not perfect, substitutes for conventional oil when the economic and technological conditions are ripe. One can turn this logic around, however, by saying that the very fact that oil sands, shale oil, corn-to-ethanol and coal-to-liquids are being taken seriously, although these are expensive, input-energy-intensive substitutes, is likely a signal that the world is both running up against limits to conventional crude oil production expansion and would like to supply the infrastructure already in place. The plot in Figure 2 is scaled from 60 Mbpd to 100 Mbpd to show a relevant range of production. In 1980, world production of conventional oil was approximately at the lower end of this range, thus illustrating the amount of growth occurring after the oil shocks of the 1970s. The EIA projects [18,19] that world liquid fuel demand will be approximately 95 Mbpd within one decade, a growth rate approximately double that of the last several years.

2.2. Rising Prices

Crude oil prices have increased dramatically since the late 1990s, with interruptions only during periods of economic recession, as shown in Figure 3. Although there are claims that this price increase was due to either speculative trading activity or to deliberate withholding of oil from the world market by quasi-monopolistic players, the same price-increase behavior would be expected if nearing a peak in production. Published literature investigating the causes of recent price increases tend to find only a small role for speculation and a much larger role being played by more fundamental supply and demand factors [7,20,21,22,23,24,25,26,27].
Figure 3. Yearly average Brent crude oil price from 1990–2011. Data from BP Statistical Review of World Energy, 2012. Data are in $US2011
Figure 3. Yearly average Brent crude oil price from 1990–2011. Data from BP Statistical Review of World Energy, 2012. Data are in $US2011
Sustainability 05 00664 g003
We can demonstrate this point more concretely by looking at the tight historical correlation between oil consumption and GDP, shown in Figure 4 (a) with data from the past 25 years (more generally, the correlation is between energy and GDP, but oil has a similar pattern). In what is presented here, we used some simple arguments that are borne out by detailed econometric studies, many of which are reviewed by Hamilton [27]. Data, such as those shown in Figure 4 a, from the past quarter century illustrate the income elasticity of demand, defined as:
Sustainability 05 00664 i001
Econometric analyses determine the elasticity for oil worldwide to be about 0.5, although for developing countries responsible for much of current increase in demand, the income elasticity tends to be closer to unity [27]. Here, the numerator is the fractional change in quantity of oil consumed and the denominator is the fractional income (GDP) change. In Figure 4b, to emphasize the changing dynamic in the first decade of the 21st century, we plot scaled world GDP (yellow) along with scaled world oil consumption (red) from 2002 after the end of the recession that started in 2007. For roughly three years, the two track closely, as they have historically; after that point, world oil production leveled off. One can interpret this as “missing” the oil production that would “normally” have been available, given the observed economic growth. For a given demand, as driven by economic growth and the empirically observed income elasticity of demand, the lack of supply implies that there will be an increase in price, conditioned on the price elasticity of demand.
Figure 4. (a) Correlation between world oil consumption and world GDP, both plotted as logarithms. (b) Scaled GDP and oil production (left-hand axis) and oil price (right-hand axis).
Figure 4. (a) Correlation between world oil consumption and world GDP, both plotted as logarithms. (b) Scaled GDP and oil production (left-hand axis) and oil price (right-hand axis).
Sustainability 05 00664 g004
Using our value for the income elasticity and substituting GDP for income, one would expect to have seen an increase in production of 4–5% over the 2005–2008 time period. Since that supply did not materialize, one would expect prices to rise consonant with the own-price elasticity of demand, given by:
Sustainability 05 00664 i002
Here, the numerator is again the fractional change in supply, and the denominator is the fractional price change. Short-term (less than one year or time period of the econometric analysis) elasticities of demand for oil are around –0.1 [28,29,30]; for the “missing” increase in supply, this would imply an increase in world oil price on the order of about 45% or $30/barrel, to around $90, which is consistent with observed yearly average prices. A somewhat higher income elasticity, along with a somewhat higher longer-term (one-year or greater) price elasticity, would lead to the same result. Thus, independent of the actual reason for the “missing” supply, there is no need to resort to blaming speculators for the rise in prices [7]. One can also use these data to estimate the effect of supply shortages on the economy [31].

2.3. Individual Country Peaks

Perhaps the most familiar indicator of a potential peak in world oil production is that many individual countries and regions (many contributing only small quantities) have entered and remained in a mode of declining conventional crude oil production, with the United States being the most prominent example. For the continental US, peak production occurred in 1970; the addition of Alaskan production helped slow the decline (and led to a temporary reversal). More recently, production of nonconventional oil from shale formations in North Dakota and Texas has again helped to slightly increase US production.
Most recently, the International Energy Agency’s 2012 World Energy Outlook [18] received widespread media attention upon release, because of the projection that the United States would become once again the world’s largest producer of liquid fuels by 2020. Aside from the fact that the IEA and other agencies have generally been overly-optimistic about future production trends (see Section 2.10.), three points were generally overlooked in analyses of this surprising development. First, in their projections, conventional oil production continues to decrease, as it has for many years. New production comes in the form of natural gas liquids and from shale oil. Second, in these same projections, the U.S. overtakes Saudi Arabia by only a few percent and only temporarily; after 2020, U.S. production again plateaus and then begins a decline, whereas Saudi production is supposed to continue growing beyond the projection time period. Finally, it should be noted that even with the new development of non-conventional oil and with the inclusion of natural gas liquids and of biofuels, the projected peak production in the 2020s would at most be at the level of U.S. production of crude oil alone in 1970. That is, only in the most optimistic estimate, and by “counting” every kind of liquid fuel, might the past peak production of the US be bested [32].
In fact, most of the world’s oil producing countries are past peak production [33], as seen from data supplied by BP and the EIA [6,34]. Of the forty top-producing countries, at least thirty are on a declining production path, and very few are on a trajectory that is clearly upward. In total, more than sixty countries have already passed a peak in production [33].

2.4. Decreasing Discoveries

Discoveries of oil in new fields peaked in the mid-1960s. Production of oil necessarily follows discovery; for a finite resource, one would expect to see cumulative discovery (and with a time delay, cumulative production) follow a path that rises as discoveries commence and reaches a plateau as the rate of new discoveries decreases. The logistic function, defined for cumulative production by:
Sustainability 05 00664 i003
is often used as a simple mathematical description of this process, but there is little physical reason to believe that the logistic function should be the best choice [16]. In fact, in the case of discoveries, the initial increase is often faster than a logistic, as large fields are usually found early [16,34,35,36].
Figure 5. Cumulative production of oil from the continental US, together with a logistic curve fit to the data. The lower dashed curve is the fit that would have been found in 1980 using data to that point. The upper dot-dash curve is the current projection.
Figure 5. Cumulative production of oil from the continental US, together with a logistic curve fit to the data. The lower dashed curve is the fit that would have been found in 1980 using data to that point. The upper dot-dash curve is the current projection.
Sustainability 05 00664 g005
In fact, the logistic description of U.S. oil production has been relatively good. As will be shown below, it is somewhat difficult to make a projection of the ultimate recoverable quantity using production data in advance of the peak in production; after the peak, it seems to be a good predictor, although, data for the U.S. follow this pattern deceptively well, compared to other regions [37,38,39]. In Figure 5, the production of oil in the continental U.S. is shown, together with a projection of the logistic curve corresponding to an ultimate recoverable quantity of 200 Gb.
Extensions of the logistic curve technique to world conventional oil production are shown in Figure 6, where both cumulative and yearly production data and logistic curves are shown. As of 2011, cumulative production was about 1,166 Gb. As has already been discussed, it is difficult to use the logistic function with past data to reliably predict the value of ultimately recoverable resource (URR). Here, we show the result of anon-linear least-squares fit to past production, using two different estimates of ultimately recoverable oil, 2,000 Gb and 3,000 Gb. The former should be considered a minimum value of URR to be expected. Parameters from the fits are such that there is a 5.3%/year initial exponential growth rate and peak-production years of 2008 and 2018 for 2,000 Gb and 3,000 Gb, respectively. Due to a large decrease in OPEC production during the decade between 1975 and 1985, the actual production curve is not smooth, somewhat complicating the interpretation of the logistic fits to the data. However, two main points are illustrated in Figure 6, independent of the precision of fit between the data and the logistic model. In rough numbers, past production is a bit over 1,000 Gb, and, assuming an additional 1,000 Gb (red curves) or 2,000 Gb (green curves), the delay in timing of peak production is only 10 years. Put another way, each additional billion barrels of oil delays the peak by only about 3.6 days [40,41]. The second point, highly relevant to the current special issue, is shown by the purple curve in Figure 6b, which shows the 7.5% per year exponential growth in rate of production that occurred over the first century of world oil production. Clearly, that exponential growth could not be maintained indefinitely, for many of the reasons discussed in LtG and in the updates that followed [1,2,3,42].
The USGS made estimates in its 2,000 Assessment [43] based on likely discoveries and additions to reserves from existing, already-discovered fields, but only assuming a time-horizon out to 2025. In follow-up work to their 2,000 Assessment [43], authors from USGS were satisfied that progress toward projected discoveries were on track to meet the 3,000 Gb estimates, especially with respect to reserve growth from previously discovered fields, while less oil had been discovered in new fields [44]. The issue of how reliable the USGS techniques may be when extended from experience in the U.S. to the rest of the world has also been discussed at length in the UKERC report [16].
Figure 6. Fits to actual production data for world conventional crude oil production. (a) World cumulative production (Gb) data (yellow squares) with logistic function fits for 5.5%/year initial growth rate and 2,000 Gb (red, lower curve) and 3,000 Gb (green, upper curve) ultimate recovery. (b) Yearly world crude oil production (Gb/year) with parameters corresponding to the curves in (a). The (purple) curve in the right-hand panel represents a 7.5%/year exponential growth rate that continued for the first century of oil production.
Figure 6. Fits to actual production data for world conventional crude oil production. (a) World cumulative production (Gb) data (yellow squares) with logistic function fits for 5.5%/year initial growth rate and 2,000 Gb (red, lower curve) and 3,000 Gb (green, upper curve) ultimate recovery. (b) Yearly world crude oil production (Gb/year) with parameters corresponding to the curves in (a). The (purple) curve in the right-hand panel represents a 7.5%/year exponential growth rate that continued for the first century of oil production.
Sustainability 05 00664 g006
Use of the logistic curve technique requires some comment. It is clear that the method is over-simplified, as far as understanding details of the resource production process is concerned. There are also serious questions that can be raised about the use of the technique as a reliable predictor of the amount of oil to be recovered or of the exact timing of the peak [16,45,46]. On the other hand, the technique works remarkably well as a heuristic model of oil production for a large region. Analyzing data by extrapolating past trends should be viewed critically, as will be discussed below. Although Hubbert himself did not start out using this technique, he did so in later work and refined his analysis over time. One point that is clear, however, is that he did not simply assume that the contemporary stated oil reserves were equivalent to the ultimately recoverable quantity of oil. As shown in figures he used [5,47], it was obvious that past production plus current reserves would be supplemented by future field extensions and new discoveries. An additional estimate, beyond that of declared reserves, was necessary for determining the URR.
Beyond the use of data for past production with the hope of understanding the potential for future production growth, there is one method that can perhaps lead to more reliable estimates. As summarized by several authors [16,35,36], rather than concentrating on so-called “1P reserves”, which tend to be reported conservatively, and with the expectation that additional oil in these fields will be found and that the fields will be extended, a more reasonable approach is to count “2P reserves”, which are estimated to be available with a 50% probability. By proper accounting for oil in these fields through back-dating or assigning the resources to the date of initial field discovery, regardless of when a new fraction of the oil in place is deemed declarable as a reserve quantity, a very different picture is found of cumulative discoveries over time [14]. Although thoroughly discussed in various publications [16], the technique of backdating suffers from the problem that the necessary data are only available from proprietary databases that are very expensive to access.

2.5. Finding and Development Costs

There is surprisingly little data available on the economic driving factors of oil discovery, but what little exists in the published literature tends to indicate a small price elasticity of new supply, on the order of 0.1–0.2 [30,48,49]. Therefore, economic driving factors are fairly unimportant in driving the discovery of new oil resources. Although the price elasticity of demand for oil is low, rising prices will certainly suppress demand; at the same time, if prices increase sufficiently, additional oil from existing fields or extracted with expensive technologies that were previously not economically viable can be moved into the reserves category. The tradeoff between these two factors may or may not serve to set an upper limit on maximum oil production. Although recently discovered fields have tended to be relatively small compared to the mega-giant and super-giant fields discovered in the middle of the past century, it is not completely out of the question that new, extremely large resources could be found. It is not logically necessary that the largest fields are found first, as evidenced by the discovery of smaller fields in the U.S. prior to those of East Texas [50]. In any case, finding new sources of oil does appear to have become more difficult (geographically and geologically more challenging) and more expensive (deeper and more complicated drilling).
Over the past several years, as demonstrated by the data gathered by the EIA and other sources [51,52,53], as shown in Figure 7, costs for finding new oil resources have risen dramatically. Figure 6 shows the EIA capital cost index for US oil field operations, scaled such that the index is equal to 100 in the year 2000. Two versions are shown, one (red squares) with deflated values and one (light blue crosses) without inflation. The IHS CERA upstream capital cost index (UCCI) is similarly scaled to a value of 100 in the year 2000 and tracks the relative costs of a portfolio of oil and gas infrastructure (offshore, onshore, pipeline) projects. Part of the rise has been due to industry bottlenecks for equipment and rigs, but the need to explore in increasingly challenging environments and at increasing depths has also played a role [51,52,53,54]. In another ongoing set of EIA data (recently discontinued), finding and lifting costs for producers of oil and gas were published annually [51]. These data also show a strong increase in costs over the past decade for those companies reporting data.
Figure 7. Oil and gas cost indices and the real price of oil. Oil capital cost index from EIA [52], scaled to 100 for the year 2000, and from IHS Cambridge Energy Research Associates [53]. Oil price (right-hand axis) is from BP.
Figure 7. Oil and gas cost indices and the real price of oil. Oil capital cost index from EIA [52], scaled to 100 for the year 2000, and from IHS Cambridge Energy Research Associates [53]. Oil price (right-hand axis) is from BP.
Sustainability 05 00664 g007
These trends seem to indicate that the “easy oil” is no longer available and certainly not in regions that are readily accessible to exploration companies. We will return to this theme below, but it is clear that as exploration and extraction costs increase, we can expect the price of oil to increase as well. The dynamics of supply and demand will have a large role in setting the market price, and inertia in the extraction sector may lead to temporary out-of-balance conditions, but one would expect the market price to be equal to the cost of producing the marginal barrel of oil. An interesting question would be to address the causality of the relationship between oil exploration and production costs, on the one hand, and oil prices on the other; from Figure 7, there is clearly a strong correlation between the two. In the end, it is clear that increasingly expensive exploration and production efforts are economically viable if the market price of oil is high enough for producers to recover their costs. Costs have been rising, and producers are still moving forward with new projects. Once again, the fact that expensive resources, such as oil sands and light tight (shale) oil, are economically viable is an indicator of scarcity of cheaper conventional resources.
There is an interesting divergence in opinion as to extraction costs of oil. In recently published work [55], estimates of remaining resources of conventional and non-conventional oil and natural gas are compiled, along with the costs of extraction for these resources. In this estimate, for extraction costs of under $20/bbl, there is a world-wide resource of approximately 3,500 Gb of conventional oil; including unconventional resources, nearly 30,000 Gb of resource is available for extraction costs of less than $35/bbl. Not only are these estimates dramatically different than those presented thus far, they also can lead to the false conclusion that there must currently be a severe distortion in oil markets that leads to both prices exceeding $100/barrel and costs for finding and producing oil that average $40/bbl today, with more expensive regions having costs exceeding $50/bbl [51]. There are reasons to doubt the reliability of the optimistic resource estimates [16], but more importantly, the presentation of cumulative availability curves is not equivalent to being able to make a statement about expected prices of oil. Average extraction costs across grades are not equivalent to the marginal cost of barrels being produced at a given time, which should set the market price [56].
In another example, from the USGS [57], estimates are made of the cost of producing oil in the National Petroleum Reserve in Alaska, an area that has been relatively well explored and with familiar, if not easy, conditions for putting infrastructure in place. Using the mean estimate for oil in place of 0.9 Gb, the authors calculate that approximately 50% of this amount can be economically extracted if oil prices are $90/bbl or more, and none would be economically viable if market priceAguilera et al. [55], and [57] discusses only well-defined conventional resources.
Although direct comparisons are difficult to make due to varying techniques and definitions used in calculating extraction costs, it is striking that both the more detailed study of a given region [57] and actual experience within the past decade [51] show markedly higher costs of producing oil than would be indicated based on a more optimistic estimate of resource availability. One point that is often overlooked in forecasts of energy costs and availability is the potential for a feedback effect of energy prices on extraction costs. As described in Attanasi and Freeman, “Major components of oil and gas industry costs, such as drilling and service industry costs, are affected by oil and gas price levels and changes that commonly follow economic cycles. Between early 2005 and early 2011, world-market prices for crude oil have fluctuated between $34 per barrel and nearly $150 per barrel. The oil and gas industry typically faces increasing costs when price increases, particularly if the industry tries to rapidly increase output.” This phenomenon explains the close correlation seen in Figure 7.

2.6. Spare Capacity

Saudi Arabia is generally seen as the world swing-producer for oil, with the largest reserves of conventional crude oil and the ability to raise output as needed. In fact, Saudi production decreased during the 2006–2008 period, but did start to ramp up again after the recession. As a side note, this overall lack of increase in production came in spite of a dramatic increase in the number of drilling rigs active in the country, as shown in Figure 8. More to the point, looking at several years’ worth of editions of the US EIA International Energy Outlook shows the optimism with which Saudi capabilities were viewed. Starting in 2003, the reference scenario called for production of 13.6 MMbpd in 2010 and 23.8 MMbpd by 2025 [58]. In the arguably more relevant “high oil price” scenario, production was expected to be 11.4 MMbpd in 2010 and 17.6 MMbpd in 2025. For more recent editions of the IEO (2009 and 2011), the reference scenario corresponds to recently observed prices that would have belonged to a previous “high price” scenario and projects only about 11 MMbpd in 2025 and only 15 MMbpd in 2035 [19,59]. The newest edition from 2012 projects production of about 11 MMbpd throughout the period to 2035, with a slight rise near the end [60].
Figure 8. Saudi Arabia output of petroleum. Production is given by the (blue) diamonds, rig count by the (red) squares.
Figure 8. Saudi Arabia output of petroleum. Production is given by the (blue) diamonds, rig count by the (red) squares.
Sustainability 05 00664 g008
There are various ways to interpret the past disparity between actual production of Saudi oil and the expectations of energy agencies, such as the IEA and the US EIA, expectations that have been scaled back over time. One view is that OPEC, led by the Saudis, is in favor of high oil prices to increase their own revenue. Therefore, OPEC countries intentionally limit production for their own benefit. A counter-argument is that oil prices of $100+, as experienced currently and prior to the start of the economic recession of 2007–2009, are too high for importing countries and simply lead to demand destruction through moves toward greater efficiency and alternative modes of transportation or through decreased economic activity. The latter possibility has long been recognized, making the lack of increased production by Saudi Arabia and OPEC as a whole prior to 2008 that much more puzzling. It clearly takes a period of years to develop new fields, with investment planning occurring even earlier, but the world production capacity limit was well-defined during the price run-up starting around the turn of the century and certainly played a role in the high prices of oil in recent years [21]. Is it possible that the Saudis could not increase production as much as was expected from them by importing countries?
A fascinating window into this question was opened by the release of the Wikileaks documents showing a series of discussions between US and Saudi officials, as well as with both current and former Aramco officials [61,62,63]. The gist of the released conversations was essentially that the Saudis had spent $120 billion during the height of the boom in prices to bring their production capacity to 12.5 MMbpd. The Wikileaks documents appear to cast doubt on the possibility of production greater than about 12 MMbpd being achieved for more than short periods of time and this at a time when the US EIA was projecting production of 20 MMbpd or more. In the end, one point that seems clear is that the world lacks transparent sources of information from which fully objective conclusions might be based.
The International Energy Agency, in recent editions of its World Energy Outlook, has been warning about the confluence of relatively rapid economic growth, especially in developing countries, and the lack of sufficient prior investment in the petroleum system [64,65]. Due to this under-investment, the IEA has seen the likelihood of a severe supply crunch in the near future. In their most recent World Energy Outlook 2012 [18], the country expected to contribute by far the most to future supply growth, beyond the shorter-term contribution from the US and a slight increase from Saudi Arabia (an additional 1 MMbpd by 2035), is Iraq. According to these projections, Iraq will triple its production from 2.7 MMbpd to over 8 MMbpd by 2035 to become the world’s fourth leading producer [18]. Essentially, a large percentage of expected future growth in oil production is from a country with severe political and infrastructural challenges that may delay or preclude such increases in production. Shortages due to lack of investment do not correspond to the conventional definition of peak oil, but should this eventuality come to pass, the effects on world economies will be indistinguishable from a true resource-limited peak.

2.7. Export Capabilities of Producing Countries

One consequence of economic and population growth in oil-producing countries is that consumption increases; if production does not grow at least as much as consumption, the result is a decrease in the availability of oil for export [66,67,68,69]. Although not a sign of peak oil directly, decreasing export capabilities of producing countries will have the effect on importers of reducing supply. If there is a limited (or no) ability to expand production, as would be the case near a peak, then trade-offs will have to be made between domestic consumption to support industries, commercial activity and household transportation and the potential for income through exports.
As is always the case with energy forecasts, there is a great deal of uncertainty in projecting trends for the consumption paths for countries that are also oil exporters. However, given that developing countries in particular have always followed a path of increased consumption of energy as wealth increases, it is reasonable to assume this as a starting point. Taking this as a starting point, along with production data for these same countries, it is not surprising that one finds many scenarios in which net exports will decrease [68]. Previous history also shows prominent examples of countries that change from being net exporters and, in the case of Indonesia, even a member of OPEC, to being net-import countries, as both population and per-capita development levels increase [69].
Data from BP for production and consumption show that the largest exporting countries were able to increase net exports steadily during the late 1980s and 1990s and into the beginning of this century [70]. China was not a insignificant exporter and has also managed to continue increasing production of oil to the present. However, with China’s rapid economic growth of the past two decades, it has become a large net importer of oil (the BP data show production and consumption data for all liquid fuels, not only conventional crude oil). Since about 2005, at the same time worldwide crude oil production has stagnated, exports from the largest exporters have also reached a plateau or decreased slightly.
A further important point concerning exports is that of subsidies often provided by producing countries to their own citizens [71]. Prices for fuel in many Middle East countries that are large producers of oil are as much a factor of ten less than prices in other countries, even those at similar stages of development [71]. These subsidies have two major consequences, both with repercussions for the world oil market. First, by artificially keeping costs for fuels low, inefficiency is encouraged. Whereas most countries have decreased energy intensity (defined as energy consumed per dollar of economic output) over the past several decades, Saudi Arabia, for example, has become less efficient, with energy intensity increasing continuously [71]. The second effect of artificially low prices for energy is that foregone income to the oil-producing sector leads to lowered incentives for investment in new and expanded infrastructure. The International Energy Agency has already been projecting for several years that current levels of investment in oil and gas infrastructure are significantly less than what is necessary to offset aging and production decline of existing capacity, with the potential to lead to supply bottlenecks [64,72].

2.8. System Inertia and Timing

Another approach to looking at peak oil production is that the challenge is fundamentally one of flow rates and time scales and not of stocks. That is, there may be plenty of oil (conventional and non-conventional) in the ground, but that it simply cannot be extracted fast enough to satisfy growing demand. In Figure 9 are shown two paths for past and potential future production of oil and other liquids. We use the fits discussed in Sec. 5 with a total URR of conventional oil of approximately 2,000 Gb to determine logistic function yearly production curves for past production. In the total for OPEC and ROW (Rest of the World) conventional oil, we have not included enhanced oil recovery and Arctic/Deepwater oil, both additional conventional resources. One adjustment was made in that OPEC historical production was fit using two logistic curves, in an attempt to better account for the form of the historical data that show a breakpoint in the 1970s during the energy crises. For nonconventional oil, we use a combination of current production, historical and industry-projected rates of production increase, along with estimates of total recoverable amounts, to construct curves for future supply [72,73]. Finally, using projected growth rates for biofuels and natural gas liquids [65], we include those curves as well. This is a very simple model, but taken in the spirit of using estimates of recoverable quantities provided by agencies, such as the IEA, as a starting point. Since there is no economic input in the form of supply and demand interactions, these curves are derived purely from the deterministic nature of the logistic function; once the URR has been used as an input parameter and historical data patterns are observed to be certain that the projected logistic curves match with past production, the logistic curve is defined for all time periods. We do leave as a free parameter for unconventional oil resources the growth rate of capacity build-up.
In Figure 9 (a), we assume that the new technologies (enhanced oil recovery (EOR), Arctic) and nonconventional resources (oil sands and shale) have rates of increase in production of 7%/year, reflecting an optimistic extension of historical experience, whereas in Figure 9 (b), those rates are 10%, a higher rate than was ever sustained for conventional sources and significantly higher than projected rates for oil sand development, even under recent optimistic economic conditions [73]. Two main points come from this simple analysis. First, although the resources are assumed to be in the ground, there is a bottleneck in production. Historically, there has never been a prolonged period in which a fossil resource has increased in production by more than about 7%/year, even with conventional resources [42]. Similar issues have been pointed out previously, with an emphasis on limitations to the economically viable rate of build-up of capital, since investments that are forced to occur too quickly are more expensive [56].
The second point, that in each case shown in Figure 9, total world production of liquid fuels peaks temporarily in the very near future, declines and then, in this simple deterministic model, after a few decades, begins to rise again. The reality is that the secondary peak would likely never materialize, since the near-term gap between supply and demand, with little time for world economies to react and adapt, would force large-scale fuel- and technology-switching, following much the same logic discussed in Section 2. Further implications of the inability to increase supply are discussed in the final section of this paper. More details of this model are presented elsewhere [45], but it must be pointed out that, due to its simplicity and lack of economic dynamics, the results are again simply indicative of the potential for a near-term peak.
Figure 9. Possible production trajectories under assumptions of growth rates that reflect past history (a) or for significantly more rapid growth rates (b). Total conventional ultimately recoverable resource (URR) is 2,500 Gb (OPEC, Rest of the World (ROW), enhanced oil recovery (EOR), Arctic); URR for oil sands and shale oil assumed to be 1,000 Gb each. Included in shale is light, tight oil, although that is a recognized to be a different unconventional source.
Figure 9. Possible production trajectories under assumptions of growth rates that reflect past history (a) or for significantly more rapid growth rates (b). Total conventional ultimately recoverable resource (URR) is 2,500 Gb (OPEC, Rest of the World (ROW), enhanced oil recovery (EOR), Arctic); URR for oil sands and shale oil assumed to be 1,000 Gb each. Included in shale is light, tight oil, although that is a recognized to be a different unconventional source.
Sustainability 05 00664 g009
There is a further interesting feature that arises out of this analysis. We note that non-conventional and other sources begin production well before the “easier” and cheaper sources of oil are depleted and, in fact, well before they peak in production in most cases. A rational approach to optimal exploitation of natural resources would lead one to expect a sequential extraction of resources, starting with the cheapest, progressing to the next more expensive category, etc. [74]. Since, however, within each category, we can rather think that there will be an overlapping progression of logistic-like curves, there is a need to pull forward in time the extraction of more-expensive resources before the less-expensive resources are fully depleted. The resulting rapid increase in costs and, therefore, prices of liquid fuels is illustrated schematically in Figure 10 (a), with output data from the deterministic logistic extraction model shown in Figure 10 (b).
Figure 10. Cost availability curves.(a) schematic marginal production cost curves. In this representation, extraction costs for each individual resource contribute to an overall curve that increases much more rapidly than one would expect from a “rational” extraction sequence, always proceeding from the cheapest available resource to the next most expensive, etc. Concrete results from the deterministic logistic model of extraction of different resource grades is shown in (b). A linear increase in costs would be predicted from a perfectly sequential extraction of resources; the output of the model shows that the average cost is close to that linear approximation, but the marginal cost is usually much higher.
Figure 10. Cost availability curves.(a) schematic marginal production cost curves. In this representation, extraction costs for each individual resource contribute to an overall curve that increases much more rapidly than one would expect from a “rational” extraction sequence, always proceeding from the cheapest available resource to the next most expensive, etc. Concrete results from the deterministic logistic model of extraction of different resource grades is shown in (b). A linear increase in costs would be predicted from a perfectly sequential extraction of resources; the output of the model shows that the average cost is close to that linear approximation, but the marginal cost is usually much higher.
Sustainability 05 00664 g010
The starting point for this figure is data for extraction cost and recoverable quantity estimates from the IEA [72]. Since we model for each resource a logistic-type curve in production, as overall demand increases and depletion of a given resource sets in, although there may be 50% or more of the resource still in place, it is necessary to start extracting the next most expensive resource; if the markets are functioning properly, this will only work if the price paid for that resource covers the increased extraction costs. Effectively, the curves published by IEA [72] and, more recently, by Aguilera [75] represent “cost availability curves” and should not be read as a snapshot in time of the amount of resource available at a given cost or to be considered as marginal extraction cost curves. As shown in Figure 10 (b), as soon as the growth rate of production of one resource begins to slow, as it must, to meet rising demand, a new resource must be tapped. That new resource has a higher extraction cost and, therefore, demands a higher market price to be viable. This dynamic automatically means that the owners of the less expensive resources capture the scarcity rent; in other words, the shift of extraction cost curves leads to a situation that would cause some to ask, “If there is so much cheap oil in the ground, why are the prices so high right now?” Current estimates of costs of producing various types of oil show maximum costs of $80/barrel, although the vast majority of oil is being produced for under $30/barrel [69].

2.9. Reserves-to-Production Ratio

Resources of oil in the ground can be divided into several different categories that have been mentioned in the passing previous section: conventional crude oil, natural gas liquids, non-conventional oil shale (kerogen), light tight oil (shale oil), etc. Furthermore, as exploration proceeds, resources become better defined, both geologically and economically. A common categorization of reserves, that fraction of the resource base that is technologically and economically recoverable, is based on probabilities of extraction feasibility. “Proved” or 1P reserves are generally taken to exist with a 90% likelihood, whereas “probable” or 2P reserves will have a 50% likelihood of availability. Defining exact reserve quantities is therefore inherently uncertain [14,33,36,76].
The most easily available data are for 1P reserves [70]. The ratio of declared reserves to current production is often quoted as the “years left” for a resource. This quantity was critically analyzed in LtG as being very misleading for a system with growing production. As we see in Figure 11, for the UK and Norway, R/P has little relation to production itself. In the UK, R/P has been increasing during the time of steepest production decline, whereas in Norway, R/P has leveled out, with production decreasing sharply [34]. Sorting out reserves information for crude oil alone is difficult; the growth seen in reserves data is augmented by the addition of some of the non-conventional sources mentioned above. From year to year, the reserves data do show increases, even in the face of continued production, as new reserves taken from the “resources” category become economically viable and are more than enough to make up for decreases in reserves due to production.
Figure 11. Yearly production (blue squares) and the reserves-to-production ratio (red triangles) for the UK and Norway
Figure 11. Yearly production (blue squares) and the reserves-to-production ratio (red triangles) for the UK and Norway
Sustainability 05 00664 g011
Note that this interpretation of the R/P ratio is somewhat different from what is often used. Those who are technological and resource optimists rightly criticize the fact that this ratio means little, since it is almost certain that current reserves will increase and that R/P reflects a static view of resources. However, it is rarely pointed out that a constant or even a continually increasing reserve-to-production ratio can be consistent with an actual decline in production of the resource. Thus, it really is the case that this ratio means nothing at all as a diagnostic of a potential peak in world oil production. A detailed discussion of depletion and R/P ratios using more detailed modeling can be found elsewhere [77].
Declared reserves of oil do continue to grow, as reported in the BP Statistical Review of World Energy [34]. Some authors have claimed that reserves, especially in the case of OPEC countries, are possibly overstated, due to production quotas in the 1980s that were based on declared reserves [14]. Several countries showed sudden and dramatic increases in declared reserves from one year to another, often of 100% or more, without convincing evidence of large discoveries. Notwithstanding these possibilities, the more important point is that made above.

2.10. Past History of Depletion and Optimism

It is certainly clear that fossil fuels represent finite resources and, therefore, cannot be extracted indefinitely. In Figure 12, the actual past production for two countries, Norway and Mexico, are shown using EIA data. Each year in the International Energy Outlook (IEO), the EIA projects future production for different countries and regions. In several cases, projections were repeatedly made for peak production coming several years in the future for countries whose peak production was already in the past. For example, production in Norway has been in decline since 2000 (Figure 12 (a)), although the EIA continued to project increases for several years after that peak. Similarly, for the UK, predictions of future increases in production came well after production had begun to decline. More recently, Mexico, with a large fraction of its production coming from the large Cantarell field, has seen decreasing production (Figure 12 (b)) and at a rapid rate.
Figure 12. Yearly production from (a) Norway and (b) Mexico (both with blue diamonds), together with projections by the EIA for future production from various volumes of the International Energy Outlook, as labeled.
Figure 12. Yearly production from (a) Norway and (b) Mexico (both with blue diamonds), together with projections by the EIA for future production from various volumes of the International Energy Outlook, as labeled.
Sustainability 05 00664 g012
The point here is not as much the unsurprising one that various countries have passed peak production, but rather, that one of the agencies most actively involved in forecasting the availability of resources could be so much in error and always in the direction of being overly-optimistic. One can imagine that in the case of some countries, making predictions of future production is difficult due to political issues (Iraq or Iran, for example) or due to a lack of certainty in the investment environment, leading to sub-optimal long-term decisions being made. However, Norway and the UK clearly do not fall into that category.
Previous examples of “peaking” include the mining of anthracite coal in the U.S. and production of coal in England. Anthracite is a high-quality, low-sulfur coal, but our maximum rate of yearly production occurred in the very early part of this century, as shown in Figure 13. There were certainly more reasons than simply geological exhaustion that led to declining production, but geology just as clearly played a role in production decline. Likewise, in England, coal, which had been the fuel of the industrial revolution, went into production decline on the eve of the First World War, as has been discussed in the context of optimistic estimates of world coal resources by Rutledge [78].
Figure 13. Yearly production of anthracite in the U.S.
Figure 13. Yearly production of anthracite in the U.S.
Sustainability 05 00664 g013
As mentioned in the introduction, the current peak oil debate was preceded over a century ago by the debate in England over peak coal. The economist and philosopher of science, W. Stanley Jevons, wrote about the threat to British economic prosperity if coal production were not to keep pace with internal demand brought about by increasing wealth and population [10]. His son, H. Stanley Jevons, writing a few decades later, had the advantage of the latest complete data from the British Geological Survey and put together what we might now term an integrated assessment model [11], including projections of population growth, demand for coal based on growing wealth and, most importantly, estimating the availability of coal at given extraction costs, based on geology and technological progress in being able to extract coal economically.
Figure 14. Production of coal in England. Historical production is shown in three segments: up to 1865, when W.S. Jevons wrote The Coal Question; from 1865 to 1912, when his son wrote about coal, and then production after 1912. The triangles show projections made by H.S. Jevons in 1912 using careful geological and socioeconomic projections.
Figure 14. Production of coal in England. Historical production is shown in three segments: up to 1865, when W.S. Jevons wrote The Coal Question; from 1865 to 1912, when his son wrote about coal, and then production after 1912. The triangles show projections made by H.S. Jevons in 1912 using careful geological and socioeconomic projections.
Sustainability 05 00664 g014
The results of his projections are shown in Figure 14. The different regions of data represent the historical record to 1865, when W. Stanley Jevons started worrying about coal-mine exhaustion in Britain, followed by production data between 1865 and 1912, the data available to H. Stanley Jevons. The latter estimated peak production in about 2100, at a production level approximately three times that of 1912. In actuality, production started declining in the very year that his work was published, never to increase significantly again. Total coal production in Britain will eventually reach somewhat less than 30 Gt; extrapolating the estimates of Jevons would lead to a conclusion that roughly ten-times as much coal should have been available. It is often claimed that a key feature of the peak oil debate is that those warning of a peak are always too pessimistic [79], but an argument can be made that there is a significant record of intelligent observers being overly optimistic as well. In spite of the production record of coal in England, it was not until the 1960s, a half-century after the peak, that official surveys of estimated ultimate coal production were decreased from 200 Gt to the more realistic 30 Gt range [78].
It may be pointed out that the actual coal resource in the ground in the UK, fields that extend under the English Channel to continental Europe, may still be very large. However, this is precisely the point about oil resources and part of the often heated discussion between those who accept a near-term (decade or less) peak in oil production and those who see no danger in the near future [75]. Resources in the ground may be very large, but extractability at acceptable costs may limit what is eventually recovered, as will a turn to alternatives.

3. Discussion: Consequences of Peak Oil

There are two final reasons as to why peak oil should be taken seriously, although with a different reading of that phrase. The first involves the economic consequences of a shortage of liquid fuels for a world addicted to oil, especially for transportation needs. Secondly, although it might seem to be a benefit to the earth’s climate for us to run into a shortage of liquid fossil fuels, the opposite may very well be the case.
If we are at or near a peak in the production of oil, the dynamics of supply and demand will undoubtedly drive prices of oil significantly higher. Soon after the beginning of the recession that started in 2007, there was some speculation about the relationship between high oil (and other energy) prices and that economic downturn. Hamilton examined the connection using examples from past oil price-spikes and subsequent recessions [7]. Perhaps more interestingly, although still somewhat tenuous, is the thought that high energy prices might be tied to an increase in mortgage delinquencies [8]; we have seen even now, after the recession is officially past, that the housing sector played a key role in both the bubble that preceded the recession and the lack of significant recovery since. If there is even a modicum of truth to the thesis linking high oil prices to economic distress, it behooves us to take seriously even a slight chance of peak oil. Various aspects of the linkage between oil supply and the economy have been presented by several authors [31,80,81,82,83].
The tight correlation between oil consumption and economic growth, discussed in Section 2, and the consequences just mentioned, is one of the feedback loops that lies at the heart of the original Limits to Growth model. Our transportation systems have developed slowly over the past century, such that there is an inherent difficulty of breaking the link between existing infrastructure and the fuel that feeds that infrastructure [9].
The second additional interpretation of the challenge posed by peak oil is that of climate change. Fossil fuel resource scarcity or bottlenecks on production would seem at first glance to be exactly what is needed to prevent carbon dioxide emissions from driving the climate system into a potentially dangerous new state. However, even fairly pessimistic estimates of recoverable fossil fuel resources do not limit emissions sufficiently to avoid going well beyond a 2 °C target of global average increase with respect to pre-industrial temperature (roughly, 450 ppmv atmospheric CO2 concentration) [81,84,85,86,87,88].
Beyond the question of how large the carbon resource might be, there is a further danger to the climate from substitutions that can and will be made. As EROEI drops for conventional oil, each unit of produced oil has embodied in it more CO2 emissions than earlier units of the same energy source. More importantly, as conventional oil becomes more scarce, non-conventional resources become more economically viable in the sense that higher market prices will likely lead to some resources moving from the resources to reserves category, as has been the case with oil sands over time. On the other hand, high prices for energy, including oil, might place constraints on the amount of available capital for creating a large new infrastructure in unconventional oil production. Some of these may not result in significantly higher CO2 emissions (e.g., shale oil), but others may have a large effect. One example in the latter category is the oil sands industry in Canada [87,89]; another example might be the conversion of coal to liquid fuels, with concomitant increase in emissions compared to fuels from conventional oil. In each of these cases, peak conventional oil production, which would be expected to lead to an overall decrease in demand for liquid fuels, might still imply an increase or little decrease in carbon emissions that would itself force the world up against another limit to growth—that of the atmosphere to absorb excess carbon, which had been buried in the ground for tens of millions of years, in a very short period measured in only decades.

4. Conclusions

A variety of indicators for an approaching scarcity of extractable resources has been presented in this paper. No single indicator can be said to prove that peak oil is near; however, gathering together many strands of evidence helps solidify the case that this is something to take seriously and that it will likely have consequences that could be avoided with sufficient advance planning. A UK Energy Research Centre report of 2009 found little evidence to support a peak in oil production occurring after 2030, for example [16]. Given time scales needed for making an energy transition, this would be a near-term peak [9]. Our focus has been on conventional oil resources and feasible production; there will inevitably be increased substitution of conventional oil by other liquid fuels and, perhaps, electrification of the transportation sector in the long term. As was the case with Malthus in the early 19th century, in the 1950s, when M. King Hubbert first broached the possibility of peak U.S. oil production, and even more so in the 1970s after publication of Limits to Growth, it is still unpopular to suggest that natural resources might set an upper bound on the exponential growth of human socioeconomic systems.
Although the subject of this survey paper is the near-term limit to production of conventional oil, implicitly there is a broader theme under consideration. To the extent which our energy system is based on finite fossil resources and we continue to rely on and extract this one-time endowment, we will require increasing amounts of ancillary resources for each unit of final energy production. For example, energy inputs to the extraction sector will continue to increase, thereby decreasing the EROEI [17,42]. Many non-conventional resources also require extraction of water; depending on the region, water availability can begin to set limits on both fossil fuel extraction and on the production of electricity [18,90]. As modern biomass gains in share of the energy system, not only will we release increasing amounts of carbon dioxide to the atmosphere, but climate change impacts will begin to set limits to further growth as well. In one sense, it is not precisely the issue of peak oil that should be of greatest concern. Perhaps the main contribution of Limits to Growth was to bring into focus the importance of interconnected feedback loops between large numbers of natural and socioeconomic systems. The concept of peak oil has never been about an absolute limit to extraction of the last gram of carbon from the earth, but rather about patterns of extraction of the cheap conventional oil to which we have become addicted and that are effectively limited by a combination of above-ground factors.
The question as to whether there will be limits to growth is, in the end, seemingly one of a fundamental belief position [91]. On the one extreme are those who feel there can be no limits, either because there are nearly infinite supplies of fossil fuels or because human societies will always find the necessary substitutes and do so in a timely fashion. This view has been borne out for the most part by the history of the past two centuries or so. However, even two centuries is not a long period of time compared to the several millennia over which human society has developed. Therefore, those who point out the limits of our ability to exploit natural systems, including fossil fuels, water and the atmosphere, are effectively pointing out that we will at some point return to the need for a balanced solar budget. Many international and national agencies, universities and companies are realizing the necessity of a significant change from the habits of the past century. The fact that we are taking note of the pressures being placed on multiple systems at the present moment, in the first half of the 21st century, is exactly the key message that was delivered by Limits to Growth forty years ago.

Acknowledgments

The author would like to acknowledge many discussions with colleagues Rex Berney and Bruce Craver at the University of Dayton and with colleagues at the Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research, especially Nico Bauer and John Schellnhuber for encouragement to pursue publication of this paper. The origin of this paper came from an invitation from Evan Hillebrand to give a presentation and participate in a panel discussion at the University of Kentucky, Patterson School of Diplomacy. I would also like to acknowledge the very detailed and helpful comments of three anonymous referees.

Conflict of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Meadows, D.H.; Meadows, D.L.; Randers, J.; and Behrens III, W.W. The Limits to Growth; Universe Books: New York, NY, USA, 1972. [Google Scholar]
  2. Meadows, D.H.; Meadows, D.L.; Randers, J. Beyond the Limits: Confronting Global Collapse, Envisioning a Sustainable Future; Chelsea Green Publishing: White River Junction, VT, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar]
  3. Meadows, D.H.; Randers, J.; Meadows, D.L. The Limits to Growth: The 30-year Update; Chelsea Green Publishing: White River Junction, VT, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  4. Turner, G.M. Comparison of The Limits to Growth with 30 years of reality. Glob. Env. Change 2008, 18, 397–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Hubbert, M.K. Nuclear Energy and the Fossil Fuels; Presented at the American Petroleum Institute, Spring meeting of the Southern District, Division of Production; Shell Development Co.: San Antonio, TX, USA, 1956. [Google Scholar]
  6. Energy Information Administration-International Energy Statistics. Available online: http://www.eia.gov/cfapps/ipdbproject/IEDIndex3.cfm (accessed on 25 January 2013).
  7. Hamilton, J.D. Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007-2008. In National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series; Publisher: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2009; Volume 15002. [Google Scholar]
  8. Kaufmann, R.K.; Gonzalez, N.; Nickerson, T.A.; Nesbit, T.S. Do household energy expenditures affect mortgage delinquency rates? Energ. Econ. 2011, 33, 188–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Hirsch, R.; Bezdek, R.; Wendling, R. Peaking of World Oil Production: Impacts,Mitigation and Risk Management; US Department of Energy NETL: Pittsburgh, PA, USA, 2005. Available online: http://www.netl.doe.gov/publications/others/pdf/oil_peaking_netl.pdf (accessed on 10 February 2013).
  10. Jevons, W.S. The Coal Question: An Inquiry Concerning the Progress of the Nation, and the Probable Exhaustion of our Coal-mines, 3rd ed; Augustus M. Kelley: New York, NY, USA, 1965. [Google Scholar]
  11. Jevons, H.S. The British Coal Trade; E.P. Dutton & Co.: New York, NY, USA, 1915. [Google Scholar]
  12. Maugeri, L. Oil: Never cry wolf. Why the petroleum age is far from over. Science 2004, 304, 1114–1115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Adelman, M.A.; Lynch, M.C. Fixed view of resource limits creates undue pessimism. Oil Gas J. 1997, 95, 56–60. [Google Scholar]
  14. Campbell, C.J.; Laherrere, J.H. The end of cheap oil. Sci. Am. 1998, 3, 78–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Brecha, R.J.; Berney, R.; Craver, B. Revisiting Hafemeister’s science and society tests. Am. J. Phys. 2007, 75, 916–930. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Sorrell, S.; Speirs, J.; Bentley, R.; Brandt, A.; Miller, R. Global Oil Depletion: An Assessment of the Evidence for a Near-term Peak in Global Oil Production; UK Energy Research Centre: London, England, 2009. Available online: http://www.ukerc.ac.uk (accessed on 10 February 2013).
  17. Cleveland, C. Net energy from the extraction of oil and gas in the United States. Energy 2005, 30, 769–782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. International Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2012; OECD/IEA: Paris, France, 2012.
  19. Energy Information Administration, International Energy Outlook 2011; DOE/EIA-0484(2011); US DOE Energy Information Administration: Washington, D.C., USA, 2011.
  20. Dées, S.; Karadeloglou, P.; Kaufmann, R.K.; Sánchez, M. Modelling the world oil market: Assessment of a quarterly econometric model. Energ. Policy 2007, 35, 178–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Dees, S.; Gasteuil, A.; Kaufmann, R.; Mann, M. Assessing the Factors Behind Oil Price Changes; Working Paper 855; European Central Bank: Frankfurt, Germany, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  22. Kaufmann, R.K.; Ullman, B. Oil prices, speculation, and fundamentals: Interpreting causal relations among spot and futures prices. Energ. Econ. 2009, 31, 550–558. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Kaufmann, R.K. The role of market fundamentals and speculation in recent price changes for crude oil. Energ. Policy 2011, 39, 105–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Fan, Y.; Xu, J.-H. What has driven oil prices since 2000? A structural change perspective. Energ, Econ. 2011, 33, 1082–1094. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Kesicki, F. The third oil price surge-What’s different this time? Energ. Policy 2010, 38, 1596–1606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Büyüksahin, B.; Harris, J. Do speculators drive crude oil futures prices. Energ. J. 2011, 32, 167–202. [Google Scholar]
  27. Hamilton, J. Understanding crude oil prices. Energ. J. 2009, 30, 179–206. [Google Scholar]
  28. Cooper, J.C.B. Price elasticity of demand for crude oil: Estimates for 23 countries. OPEC Review 2003, 3, 1–8. [Google Scholar]
  29. International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook 2011; Chapter 3-Oil Scarcity, Growth and Global Imbalances; International Monetary Fund: Washington D.C., USA, 2011.
  30. Benes, J.; Chauvet, M.; Kamenik, O.; Kumhof, M.; Laxton, D.; Mursula, S.; Selody, J. The Future of Oil: Geology versus Technology; Working Paper WP/12/109; IMF: Washington, D.C., USA, 2012. Available online: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12109.pdf (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  31. Hirsch, R.L. Mitigation of maximum world oil production: Shortage scenarios. Energ. Policy 2008, 36, 881–889. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Miller, R. Future oil supply: The changing stance of the International Energy Agency. Energ. Policy 2011, 39, 1569–1574. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Sorrell, S.; Miller, R.; Bentley, R.; Speirs, J. Oil futures: A comparison of global supply forecasts. Energ. Policy 2010, 38, 4990–5003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. BP, Statistical Review of World Energy 2011; BP: London, UK, 2011.
  35. Sorrell, S.; Speirs, J.; Bentley, R.; Brandt, A.; Miller, R. Global oil depletion: A review of the evidence. Energ. Policy 2010, 38, 5290–5295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Bentley, R.; Mannan, S.; Wheeler, S. Assessing the date of the global oil peak: The need to use 2P reserves. Energ. Policy 2007, 35, 6364–6382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Nehring, R. Two basins show Hubbert’s method underestimates future oil production. Oil Gas J. 2006, 104, 37–42. [Google Scholar]
  38. Nehring, R. How Hubbert method fails to predict oil production in the Permian Basin. Oil Gas J. 2006, 104, 30–35. [Google Scholar]
  39. Nehring, R. Post-Hubbert challenge is to find new methods to predict production. Oil Gas J. 2006, 104, 43–46. [Google Scholar]
  40. Bartlett, A. An analysis of US and world oil production patterns using hubbert-style curves. Math. Geol. 2000, 32, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Kaufmann, R.; Shiers, L. Alternatives to conventional crude oil: When, how quickly, and market driven? Ecol. Econ. 2008, 67, 405–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Höök, M.; Li, J.; Johansson, K.; Snowden, S. Growth rates of global energy systems and future outlooks. Nat. Resour. Res. 2012, 21, 23–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Ahlbrandt, T.S.; Charpentier, R.R.; Klett, T.R.; Schmoker, J.W.; Schenk, C.J. US Geological Survey World Petroleum Assessment-Analysis of Assessment Results; United States Geological Survey: Washington, D.C., USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  44. Klett, T.R.; Gauthier, D.L.; Ahlbrandt, T.S. An evaluation of the USGS world petroleum assessment 2000. Am. Assoc. Petr. Geol. B 2005, 89, 1033–1042. [Google Scholar]
  45. Brecha, R.J. Logistic curves, extraction costs and effective peak oil. Energ. Policy 2012, 51, 586–597. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Sorrell, S.; Speirs, J. Hubbert’s legacy: A review of curve-fitting methods to estimate ultimately recoverable resources. Nat. Resour. Res. 2010, 19, 209–230. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Hubbert, M.K. The world’s evolving energy system. Am. J. Phys. 1981, 49, 1007–1029. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Krichene, N. World crude oil and natural gas: A demand and supply model. Energ. Econ. 2002, 24, 557–576. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Reynolds, D. Using non-time-series to determine supply elasticity: How far do prices change the Hubbert curve? OPEC Review 2002, 6, 147–167. [Google Scholar]
  50. Reynolds, D. The mineral economy: How prices and costs can falsely signal decreasing scarcity. Ecol. Econ. 1999, 31, 155–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. EIA, Performance Profiles of Major Energy Producers; US DOE Energy Information Administration: Washington D.C., USA, 2011.
  52. EIA. Oil and Gas Lease Equipment and Operating Costs 1994 Through 2009; Energy Information Administration: Washington, D.C., USA, 2010. Available online: http://www.eia.gov/pub/oil_gas/natural_gas/data_publications/cost_indices_equipment_production/current/coststudy.html (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  53. IHS CERA. Upstream Capital Costs Index. HIS CERA: Englewood, CO, USA, 2012. Available online: http://www.ihs.com/info/cera/ihsindexes/index.aspx (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  54. International Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2011; Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: Paris, France, 2011.
  55. Aguilera, R.; Eggert, R.; Lagos, G.; Tilton, J. Depletion and the future availability of petroleum resources. Energ. J. 2009, 30, 141–174. [Google Scholar]
  56. Jakobsson, K.; Bentley, R.; Söderbergh, B.; Aleklett, K. The end of cheap oil: Bottom-up economic and geologic modeling of aggregate oil production curves. Energ. Policy 2012, 41, 860–870. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Attanasi, E.; Freeman, P. Economic Analysis of the 2010 US Geological Survey Assessment of Undiscovered Oil and Gas in the National Petroleum Reserve in Alaska; Open file report 2011–1103; USGS: Reston, VA, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  58. Energy Information Administration, International Energy Outlook 2003; DOE/EIA-0484(2003); US DOE Energy Information Administration: Washington D.C., USA, 2003.
  59. Energy Information Administration, International Energy Outlook 2009; DOE/EIA-0484(2009); US DOE Energy Information Administration: Washington D.C., USA, 2009.
  60. Energy Information Administration, International Energy Outlook 2012; DOE/EIA-0484(2012); US DOE Energy Information Administration: Washington D.C., USA, 2012.
  61. Wikileaks. US embassy cables: Saudi oil company oversold ability to increase production, embassy told, 2012. 2012. Available online: http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2011/feb/08/oil-saudiarabia (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  62. Wikileaks. US embassy cables: US queries Saudi Arabia's influence over oil prices. Available online: http://www.guardian.co.uk/world/2011/feb/08/saudiarabia-oil (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  63. Wikileaks. WikiLeaks cables: Saudi Arabia cannot pump enough oil to keep a lid on prices; US diplomat convinced by Saudi expert that reserves of world's biggest oil exporter have been overstated by nearly 40, 2012. Available online: http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2011/feb/08/saudi-oil-reserves-overstated-wikileaks (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  64. International Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2009; Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: Paris, France, 2009.
  65. International Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2010; Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: Paris, France, 2010.
  66. Gately, D.; Al-Yousef, N.; Al-Sheikh, H.M.H. The rapid growth of domestic oil consumption in Saudi Arabia and the opportunity cost of oil exports foregone. Energ. Policy 2012, 47, 57–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Rubin, J.; Buchanan, P. OPEC’s growing call on itself. CIBC World Markets Occasional Report. 2007, 62, pp. 1–6. Available online: http://research.cibcwm.com/economic_public/download/occrept62.pdf (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  68. Brown, J.J.; Foucher, S. Peak Oil vs. Peak Exports; Association for the Study of Peak Oil and Gas: Washington, D.C., USA, 2010. Available online: http://aspousa.org/2010/10/peak-oil-versus-peak-exports/ (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  69. Fantazzini, D.; Höök, M.; Angelantoni, A. Global oil risks in the early 21st century. Energ. Policy 2011, 39, 7865–7873. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  70. BP, Statistical Review of World Energy 2012; BP: London, UK, 2012.
  71. Lahn, G.; Stevens, P. Burning Oil to Keep Cool: The Hidden Energy Crisis in Saudi Arabia; Chatham House-Royal Institute of International Affairs: London, England, 2011. Available online: http://www.chathamhouse.org/sites/default/files/public/Research/Energy,%20Environment%20and%20Development/1211pr_lahn_stevens.pdf (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  72. International Energy Agency, World Energy Outlook 2008; Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: Paris, France, 2008.
  73. Canadian Association of Petroleum Producers. Crude Oil-Forecast, Markets and Pipelines; Technical Report; CAPP: Calgary, Alberta, Canada, 2012. Available online: http://www.capp.ca/forecast/Pages/default.aspx (accessed on 8 February 2013).
  74. Herfindahl, O.C. Depletion and Economic Theory. In Extractive Resources and Taxation; University of Wisconsin Press: Madison, WI, USA, 1967; pp. 63–90. [Google Scholar]
  75. Aguilera, R.F.; Eggert, R.G.; Lagos, G.; Tilton, J.E. Depletion and the future availability of petroleum resources. Energ. J. 2009, 30, 141–174. [Google Scholar]
  76. Sorrell, S.; Speirs, J.; Bentley, R.; Miller, R.; Thompson, T. Shaping the global oil peak: A review of the evidence on field sizes, reserve growth, decline rates and depletion rates. Energy 2012, 37, 709–724. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Jakobsson, K.; Söderbergh, B.; Höök, M.; Aleklett, K. How reasonable are oil production scenarios from public agencies? Energ. olicy 2009, 37, 4809–4818. [Google Scholar]
  78. Rutledge, D. Estimating long-term world coal production with logit and probit transforms. Int. J. Coal Geol. 2011, 85, 23–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Lynch, M. Forecasting oil supply: Theory and practice. Q. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2002, 42, 373–389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Tverberg, G.E. Oil supply limits and the continuing financial crisis. Energy 2012, 37, 27–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Nel, W.P.; Cooper, C.J. Implications of fossil fuel constraints on economic growth and global warming. Energ. Policy 2009, 37, 166–180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Lutz, C.; Lehr, U.; Wiebe, K. Economic effects of peak oil. Energ. Policy 2012, 48, 829–834. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Kerschner, C.; Hubacek, K. Assessing the suitability of input-output analysis for enhancing our understanding of potential economic effects of peak oil. Energy 2009, 34, 284–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Kharecha, P.; Hansen, J. Implications of "peak oil’’ for atmospheric CO2 and climate. Global Biogeochem. Cy. 2008, 22, 3012. [Google Scholar]
  85. Brecha, R. Emission scenarios in the face of fossil-fuel peaking. Energ. Policy 2008, 36, 3492–3504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Vernon, C.; Thompson, E.; Cornell, S. Carbon dioxide emission scenarios: Limitations of the fossil fuel resource. Procedia Environ. Sci. 2011, 6, 206–215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Brandt, A.R.; Farrell, A.E. Scraping the bottom of the barrel: Greenhouse gas emission consequences of a transition to low-quality and synthetic petroleum resources. Climatic Change 2007, 84, 241–263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Höök, M.; Tang, X. Depletion of fossil fuels and anthropogenic climate change—A review. Energ. Policy 2013, 52, 797–809. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Söderbergh, B.; Robelius, F.; Aleklett, K. A crash programme scenario for the Canadian oil sands industry. Energ. Policy 2007, 35, 1931–1947. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Rong, F.; Victor, D. Coal liquefaction policy in China: Explaining the policy reversal since 2006. Energ. Policy 2011, 39, 8175–8184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Lloyd, B. The growth delusion. Sustainability 2009, 1, 516–536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Brecha, R.J. Ten Reasons to Take Peak Oil Seriously. Sustainability 2013, 5, 664-694. https://doi.org/10.3390/su5020664

AMA Style

Brecha RJ. Ten Reasons to Take Peak Oil Seriously. Sustainability. 2013; 5(2):664-694. https://doi.org/10.3390/su5020664

Chicago/Turabian Style

Brecha, Robert J. 2013. "Ten Reasons to Take Peak Oil Seriously" Sustainability 5, no. 2: 664-694. https://doi.org/10.3390/su5020664

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop