Next Article in Journal
Optimal Pricing in Recycling and Remanufacturing in Uncertain Environments
Next Article in Special Issue
Population Estimates from Orbital Data of Medium Spatial Resolution: Applications for a Brazilian Municipality
Previous Article in Journal
Does Internal Control Contribute to a Firm’s Green Information Disclosure? Evidence from China
Previous Article in Special Issue
Rapidity of Change in Population Age Structures: A Local Approach Based on Multiway Factor Analysis
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Agglomeration Effect of Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling: Evidence of South Korea

Incheon Institute, Incheon 22711, Korea
Sustainability 2020, 12(8), 3198; https://doi.org/10.3390/su12083198
Submission received: 25 March 2020 / Revised: 11 April 2020 / Accepted: 13 April 2020 / Published: 15 April 2020
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Urban Growth and Demographic Dynamics)

Abstract

:
Since workplace skills present diverse dimensions of a worker’s ability, it has recently received renewed interest by researchers examining the growth of cities. The purpose of the paper explores the advantage of regional concentrations of workers specialized in different types of skills. Specifically, the analysis estimates the agglomeration effects of skill-based labor pooling on wage levels and wage growth in South Korea. To this end, it constructs skill-based labor pool indices for cognitive, social, technical, and physical skills at a provincial level. The indices show an uneven geographical distribution in varying degrees across four types of skills. The regression results indicate that the urban wage premium of skill-based local labor pooling varies according to types of skills. The greatest magnitude of benefit is incurred by workers in cognitive-skill-oriented occupations and moderate benefits are found in technical- and physical-skill-oriented occupations. An urban wage premium is non-existent in social-skill-oriented occupations. In addition, the wage growth model with job mobility shows that the urban wage premium immediately affects workers who change jobs and relocate to denser areas. As high-wage occupations earn higher wage premiums when workers in these occupations are concentrated, it supports patterns of the polarization of both skills and their effects.

1. Introduction

Studies related to workers’ skills have highlighted their importance in fostering insight into the growth of cities and the divergence of regional economies [1,2]. While education, a conventional measure of a worker’s human capital, indirectly represents the competency of a worker, skills are a more direct measure of the multi-dimensional aspects of the worker’s ability to perform required tasks in the workplace [3]. As artificial intelligence and automation in industrial production advance and the gap between high- and low-skill cities widens, an examination of the nature of skills may provide a comprehensive understanding of the transforming features of urban economic growth [4].
The advantage of agglomeration economies in urban areas and wage premiums accrued by workers who change employers and work locations have been well documented in empirical studies [5,6]. Urban economic theorists have developed models related to the concentration of various firms and production factors in a city and their generation of urban advantages: sharing specialized production inputs, enhancing learning and spreading specific knowledge, and facilitating higher-quality matches between workers and firms [7]. In particular, a thick labor market represents a source of agglomeration economies by reducing employee search costs, increasing churning rates, and improving the likelihood of strong matches between workers and firms [8,9]. This line of study has indicated that a large local labor pool has a positive effect on both firms and workers during job searches and matching processes in populated urban areas. A local labor pool, however, is not a homogeneous entity. Workplace skills, including technical expertise, physical strength, knowledge field, and even the social/collaborative atmosphere vary across cities. Hence, a diverse composition of skill levels and types in a local labor pool is a key feature accounting for divergent regional advantages stemming from the agglomeration of workers [3]. Regardless of the recent diverging patterns of regional skills [4], only a few studies [10,11] have examined the effect of an agglomeration of workers with a variety of skill types and levels.
This paper explores the regional advantages of a nexus of skills and local workforces. It focuses on regional concentrations of workers with particular skill types. To this end, it presents an index of skill-based local labor pooling. While workplace skills in an occupation typically consist of multi-dimensional components, each occupation may be characterized by a main skill type, that is, one that is more frequently used in that occupation than in other occupations and needed in order to fulfill the tasks of that job. Hence, some occupations can be categorized into one group based on their main skills. By categorizing occupations based on their common characteristics of skillsets, this study constructs a skill-based labor pool index. This analysis takes into account four distinctive types of skills: cognitive, social, technical, and physical. The degree of regional concentration of workers with various skill types differs according to regional characteristics such as the industrial structure or the educational and vocational institutes. A prior study identified different spatial patterns among cognitive, technical, and manual skills [2]. Therefore, an examination of variations in cognitive-, social-, technical-, and physical-skill-based local labor pooling would provide valuable insights into our understanding of agglomerations and the future growth of cities.
The empirical analysis in this study estimates the effects of an agglomeration of skill-based labor pooling on wage levels as well as wage growth in South Korea. The first model examines how skill-based local labor pooling is associated with the productivity of local economies measured by wage levels. Typically, a more populated urban area has a wage premium due to self-selection and better allocation of workers and firms. The empirical model seeks to determine differences in the urban wage premium among four skill groups. It assumes that some occupations with some distinctive skills may gain greater benefits from local labor pooling than others. For example, if a worker tends to learn from interactions with co-workers with similar tasks, the concentration of workers with similar skills is more critical for that job. Possibly, cognitive and social skills are more likely to have been cumulatively acquired from work experience and interaction with others while physical and low technical skills related to manual tasks are much less likely to benefit from the experience and knowledge spillover from agglomerations.
The second model investigates how a skill-based local labor pool affects the return of job mobility. The expected return of job mobility, wage growth, heavily depends on how much a worker’s accumulated skills are valued in a new job. If the required tasks of a new job differ markedly from those of past jobs, the skills acquired in the past job will be devalued, and job mobility will result in a significant decrease in wages. If vacancies that seek experience from previous jobs are limited in the local economy, a worker should choose to accept a less suitable local job or relocate to other cities. As occupational and regional mobility are a tradeoff [12], when a worker changes jobs to a location where similar-skill-content jobs are more available, such job mobility would lead to faster wage growth. Thus, an index of skill-based local labor pooling is a key factor that determines the return of job mobility.
For empirical analyses, we access three datasets. We use the Korea Network for Occupations and Workers (KNOW) and the Regional Employment Survey (RES) to construct skill-based local labor pool indices and then combine the indices with the Korean Labor and Income Panel Study (KLIPS) to estimate the effects of skill-based local labor pools.
The rest of the paper consists of five sections. Section 2 summarizes the existing literature that relates to the effects of local labor pools and discusses the contributions of the empirical analysis. Section 3 introduces a method of constructing indices of skill-based local labor pools and presents their features. Section 4 describes the panel data for wage and job mobility patterns, and Section 5 presents the analytical models and results. Section 6 concludes the paper and discusses the implications of the analysis.

2. Literature Review

A substantial number of studies have devoted efforts to examining the role of local labor pooling. Duranton and Puga [7] presented a theoretical foundation that shows that improving the quality and frequency of matching employees with firms serves as a channel through which local labor pooling contributes to the productivity of local firms. Abel and Deitz [8] provided empirical findings that a thick labor market helps college graduates in the United States find jobs that more closely match their education. Andini et al. [13] examined four aspects of local labor pools, including turnover, learning, matching, and hold up, and their Italian empirical analysis showed a positive association between turnover and on-the-job training and labor market density. Roca and Ruga [14] argued that workers accumulate their human capital in large cities. They showed empirical evidence of the accumulation and persistence of work experience by Spanish workers in large cities. A study by Bleakley and Lin [9] on the U.S. local labor market showed that although the overall turnover rate was lower in a denser labor market, it increased for young workers and played an important role in raising the wages of young workers. Andersson et al. [15] demonstrated the complementary relationship between worker and firm quality in the thick labor market, which led to an increase in productivity for both. These lines of theoretical and empirical research extensively support the significance of local labor pooling to the growth of cities.
Combining workplace skills and agglomeration has recently emerged in local labor market analyses. Gathmann and Schönberg [11] showed that some skills are portable and important sources of wage growth. In Germany, about 40% of wage growth was attributed to task-specific human capital. Bacolod et al. [3] analyzed how agglomeration affects the value of worker skills, including cognitive, social, and motor skills. The urban wage premium is greater in those with cognitive and social skills than in those with motor skills. Examining the relationship between skill clusters and mobility, Geel and Backers-Gellner [16] developed an indicator of a skill cluster and found that job mobility within a skill cluster led to higher wage gains than that between skill clusters.
Previous studies have provided abundant empirical evidence supporting the substantial influence of local labor pooling in terms of the accumulation of human capital and the positive wage effect. In addition, researchers have referred to skills to explain the increasing gap among regional economies, identify the transferability of human capital, and measure the agglomeration effect based on types of skills. In response to renewed interest in skills and agglomeration, this study extends the literature by building indices of local labor pooling based on diverse skill types, exploring geographical patterns of the nexus of skills and occupations, and measuring the differentiated impact of local agglomeration across various features of skills.

3. Geography of Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling

To understand the impact of the agglomeration effect of skill-based local labor pooling, we need to identify the types and levels of skills required for occupations and then draw a map for the geographical distribution of skills and labor. This section presents an approach to construct a skill-based local labor pool index using datasets from the KNOW and the RES and then discusses some spatial patterns of skill-based local labor indices. We follow three steps. First, as workplace skills are comprised of multiple dimensions, we need to reduce the number of dimensions by categorizing them into conceptualized factors. Through factor analysis, we identify four skill factors from the KNOW, which contains information about the importance and the level of 44 skill types required for each occupation. Second, the scores of the four skill factors are calculated through the two-digit Korean Standard Occupation Classification (KSOC). Finally, an index of skill-based local labor pools is computed in Equation (1) as follows:
Skill-Based   Local   Labor   Pool i s = j s E i j ×   W j s
where E i j is the number of workers in occupation j and region i , and W j s is the score of skill s required for occupation j. The skill score indicates the effective use of a certain skill in an occupation compared to its use in other occupations. If the required importance and level of a certain skill in an occupation are more than average, that skill is effective and valuable for fulfilling the tasks of that occupation. The skill score, W j s , is zero when W j s is less than average. The skill-based local labor pool index is a sum of workers in similar skill-content occupations weighted by the effective use of skills.
Several key features about skill categorization and spatial patterns are presented below. To identify types of skills that fulfill the tasks of occupations, we employ the raw data of the KNOW surveyed from 2001 and 2015. The KNOW survey asks incumbents how important a particular type of skill is in an occupation and what level of that skill is required to fulfill the tasks of that occupation. The questionnaire includes 44 types of skills that comprehensively cover basic, cognitive, psychomotor, resource management, technical, sensory, and physical skills. To reduce the dimensions of skills, we perform a factor analysis, the results of which appear in Table 1. The table lists the 44 types of skills categorized into four factors whose eigenvalues exceed one.
According to the factor-loading values in Table 1, 44 types of skills are allocated to four factors. The first represents cognitive skills, consisting of reading comprehension, active learning, critical thinking, reasoning, attentiveness, and so on. The second factor comprises social skills and constitutes inter-personal and managerial elements, including persuasion, negotiation, instruction, service orientation, management, and so on. The third factor mainly includes technical skills such as equipment selection, installation, programming, operation monitoring, troubleshooting, and repairing. The final factor, physical skills, includes manual dexterity, reaction time and speed, and visual and auditory skills.
We then calculate the average scores of the four factors—cognitive, social, technical, and physical skills—across the two-digit KSOC, including the 48 occupational groups displayed in Table 2, and normalize each score with a zero mean and one standard deviation. If the importance and skill level required in an occupation fall below the average of all other occupations, the skill score is negative. For example, while the scores of cognitive and technical skills in food service occupations are negative, those of social and physical skills are positive. This is because the main tasks of a restaurant server consist of taking orders accurately, engaging with customers in a friendly manner, preparing checks, and so forth.
Taking the highest and lowest scores of the four skill scores in an occupation, we rearranged all occupations as noted in the last column of Table 2. Since the common characteristics of each group of occupations were distinctive with regard to skill requirements, the table shows four skill-based occupational groups. The first consists of occupations that require the highest level cognitive skills, which are more valuable in scientific professions and related occupations, legal and administrative occupations, and business and finance professions and related occupations. They are categorized as cognitive-skill-oriented occupations. Second, for some occupations such as senior public officials and senior corporate officials; public, business administration, and marketing management occupations; professional service management occupations; sales and customer service managers; financial clerical occupations; and transport and leisure service occupations and others, the social skill scores are much higher than those of the other three skills, which are social-skill-oriented occupations. Third, occupations related to machine operations are categorized as technical-skill-oriented occupations, including engineering professionals and technical occupations, metal coremakers and related trade occupations, transport and machine-related trade occupations, electric and electronic-related trade occupations, and food processing-related machine operating occupations. The final group of occupations constitutes physical-skill-oriented occupations in which the physical skill scores are higher than those of other skills. These occupations with the higher physical skill scores include culture, arts, and sports professionals and related occupations; police, fire fighting, and security-related service occupations; cooking and food service occupations; construction and mining-related elementary occupations; cleaning and guard-related elementary occupations; and others.
Applying the results of the skill score calculations to Equation (1), we construct the local skill labor pooling index at a provincial level. Figure 1 and Table 3 present the provincial comparative advantage of a concentration of workers by skill types. They are a relative ratio between a provincial portion of a skill-based local labor pool index to a provincial portion of the population. It shows the relative concentration of workers in cognitive-, social-, technical-, and physical-skill-oriented occupations.
We identify several patterns in the comparative advantages of skill-based local labor pooling. The capital city and adjacent provincial areas of Gyeonggi have an advantage in workforces with cognitive and social skills. The old southeastern industrialized belt, Ulsan and Gyeongnam, and the outskirts of capital areas such as Incheon and Chungnam are specialized in technically skilled workforces. The workforces of planned cities such as Sejong and Daejeon have a relative advantage in cognitive and social skills. Daejeon was designed for developing the science and technology cluster, and Sejong was built for relocating administrative functions from Seoul to Sejong. The less developed provinces and adjacent rural areas of Gangwon, Chungbuk, Jeonbuk, and Jeonnam show higher values in physical skill labor pooling. Jeju, which is specialized in tourism, has a large workforce with social and physical skills.
One important aspect is the extent to which skilled workers with unique skillsets are geographically concentrated or evenly distributed. Displayed at the bottom of Table 3 are the standard deviations of the four skill indices across the provinces: 0.27 for cognitive skills, 0.12 for social skills, 0.23 for technical skills, and 0.14 for physical skills. Workforces with cognitive and technical skills are relatively more concentrated while those with social and physical skills are more evenly distributed.

4. Data Description

To estimate the agglomeration effect of skill-based local labor pooling, we combine the index of the skill-based local labor pool and panel data from the Korean Labor and Income Panel Study (KLIPS) in the analysis. The KLIPS traced employment status and income level for individual households and their members during 20 waves from 1998 to 2017. It provides a work history that covers every job status during the surveyed period. The work history includes job-related information such as the sequence of jobs, the type of jobs (permanent, temporary, or daily job), type of payment, main job or not, occupation, age, education attainment, size of firm, location of firm, job mobility, and monthly wage. We use the KLIPS work history information about individuals working between 2013 to 2017 because the provincial-level occupational statistics are available for only those periods in South Korea. The provincial occupational statistics are drawn from the Regional Employment Survey (RES). The analysis is restricted to the cases observed in consecutive five years and permanent workers. Year to year, 10,443 individuals were observed. Some moved between unemployed and employed statuses, and data for the year of unemployment were eliminated because they did not contain wage information. The survey asks individuals whether they held the same job in a previous year. This question enables us to accurately identify job mobility on an annual basis. When the employed status was held for two consecutive years and the job of a current year is not the same as that of a previous year, it is identified as job mobility.
The variables employed in this analysis are listed in Table 4. They are grouped as personal-, job-, and province-related variables. The average age of the sample is 46 and the percentage of male workers is 57.3%. Regarding education attainment, the sample consists of 35.0% with a high school diploma, 17.6% with a two-year vocational college degree, and 30.4% with a four-year university or higher degree. Job-related variables include monthly wage, firm size, job mobility or no job mobility, and scores for cognitive, social, technical, and physical skills. The share of workers who changed employers is 8.7% in the sample. The province-related variables are population, population density, and cognitive-, social-, technical-, and physical-skill-based labor pool indices.
Furthermore, the patterns of job mobility are displayed in Table 5, Table 6 and Table 7. Table 5 shows how the rate of job mobility differs across individual characteristics. Female workers are slightly more mobile than male workers. While the rate of job mobility of females is 9.1%, that of males is 8.4%. The younger the worker is, the higher the probability of job mobility, which is consistent with previous empirical analysis that found that young workers tend to experience a period of job shopping and then settle down in a career job [17]. The rate of job mobility is 14.3% for ages 20–29, 9.1% for ages 30–39, and 8.2% for ages 40–49. The job mobility rate stabilizes at about age 50 at 7.7%. Regarding educational attainment, job mobility rates do not appear to significantly differ: for high school graduates, it is 9.3%, for 2-year vocational college graduates 9.1%, and for four-year university or more 8.0%.
Table 6 and Table 7 show the job mobility patterns by occupation and location. Job mobility within a one-digit occupation was slightly higher than that between one-digit occupations. The percentage within a one-digit occupation was 52.1%. Within-occupation mobility is more frequent in occupations that include managers, professionals and related workers, and craft and related trade workers. Between-occupation job mobility more commonly occurs in occupations that include service worker and sales worker occupations. As these workers change occupations, they are more likely to lose job-specific human capital, experiencing greater wage losses than other workers.
Regarding within- and between-province job mobility, the within-province job mobility is more common than the between-province job mobility. The ratio of within-province job mobility was almost 80%. As job mobility with relocation incurs additional moving costs, the higher rate of within-province job mobility is a predictable pattern. There is some variation in between-province job mobility across provinces, however. The between-province job mobility rates tend to be higher in the metro provinces such as Seoul, Daegu, Incheon, and Gwangju while the within-province job mobility rate is higher in non-metro provinces, including Gangwon, Chungbuk, Jeonbuk, and Gyeongnam. If the moving costs of between-province job mobility were compensated for, the return of job mobility from some metro provinces may become higher than others.

5. Analysis and Results

The analysis begins with an examination of the urban wage premium hypothesis with skill-based local labor pool indices. The analytical model for estimating the urban wage premium is expressed in Equation (2).
ln W k i t = β X k i t + δ L i s t + ϕ k + ε k t
where the dependent variable is the log of the monthly wage of individual k in province i at time t , X k i t denotes the characteristics of individual k in province i at time t , including age, gender, education attainment, and L i s t is the skill-based local labor pool index for skill s in province i at time t . ϕ k represents unobserved individual characteristics such as innate intelligence and ability. The model follows the estimate approach of Glaeser and Mare [5], in which OLS regression constrains ϕ to be zero. While the application of an individual fixed-effect model may correct the omitted bias of unobserved individual characteristics, this application loses most of the variation in individual characteristics in this analysis.
The results of the estimations of urban wage premium models with the skill-based local labor pool indices are shown in Table 8. With respect to conventional variables for urban wage premium in models 1 and 2, workers obtain higher wages in denser, larger urban areas. Two variables, population and population density, are statistically significant at a 1% level. The elasticity of population density and size to worker’s wage level was 0.022 and 0.032. The sign of the variables of individual characteristics is congruent to the expected. The wages of male workers are 37.5% higher than those of female workers. The wage curve is convex over age with a negative sign of an age-squared variable. Education attainment explains the variation in wages. All three dummies for education attainment are statistically significant. Compared to the wages of individuals who have not graduated from high school, the wages of high school, 2-year vocational college, and 4-year or more university graduates are 8.7%, 23.7%, and 26.9% higher, respectively. The variable of firm size is also significant, and the elasticity of firm size to wage level is 0.090. As a whole, the estimate results of the conventional urban wage premium model are highly consistent with those of previous empirical studies.
Models 3, 4, 5, and 6 in Table 8 show the results of estimates with a subset of samples with similar skill-content occupations, as noted in Table 2. The main interest of the analysis is the significance and magnitude of the variables of the skill-based local labor pooling indices. In model 3, the wage level of workers specialized in cognitive skills is significantly higher in areas in which workers with these skills are concentrated. One percentage increase of a cognitive skill labor pool index is associated with a 0.075 percentage increase of wage level. The cognitive skill score variable representing the price of cognitive skill and education dummies are not significant, partly because the prerequisite of jobs requiring high-level cognitive skills is at least four years of university study, and their productivity is not simply assessed by quantitatively measured scores. Their activities may consist of far more than routine tasks. The firm size variable is significant and its magnitude is higher than that of other models. The wage level of workers in cognitive-skill-oriented occupations is highly related to the features of the workplace, that is, the firm size and its location.
Regarding social-skill-oriented occupations, the social skill local labor pool index is not significant while the social skill score is a statistically significant variable in model 4 of Table 8. Social-skill-oriented occupations are more heterogeneous compared to other occupational groups. From an occupational hierarchy perspective, some employees, such as senior officials, business managers, and professional service managers, are on a higher order than customer service, sales, and personal service workers. The social skill scores in this group vary markedly, shown in Table 2. Social skill scores are a key explanatory variable for determining the wage levels of this group. However, from a spatial perspective, social-skill-oriented occupations are the most evenly distributed, so wage differences across provinces are not found by the empirical model.
Model 5 shows that both the technical skill score and technical skill local labor pool index are statistically significant variables. One percentage increase of a technical skill labor pool index led to a 0.025 percentage increase of the wage level of technically skilled workers. Information and communication, transport and machine, and electric and electronic occupations are those requiring higher technical skill levels. The variables of gender, age, and educational level are statistically significant. In particular, the gender wage gap is the widest in technical-skill-oriented occupations.
Finally, the physical skill score and physical skill local labor pool index are also significant, shown in model 6. Jobs that require stronger physical skills are police, fire fighting, and security, construction and mining, and driving and transport. For this group of occupations, an urban wage premium is found, but the elasticity of a physical skill labor pool index to the wage level is relatively lower than that of cognitive-skill-oriented occupations. In addition, the benefits of education for those in physical-skill-oriented occupations are modest. In short, the empirical analysis of South Korea showed that the urban wage premium is mostly found in occupations that require different sets of skills, except social-skill-oriented occupations. The magnitudes of the urban wage premium, in order from high to low, are cognitive-, physical-, and technical-skill-oriented occupations.
The next analytical model examines how the return of job mobility differs across provinces where the skill-based local labor pool varies. The analysis employs the wage growth model with interactive variables expressed in Equation (3).
ln Δ W a g e k t i = β X k t i + θ M k t j i + δ M k t j i × Δ L j i s t + ε k t
where the dependent variable is the growth in monthly wages from year to year of individual k in province i at time t , X k t i is a time-varying variable of individual k in province i at time t , M k t j i is the job mobility of individual k from province j to i at time t , and M k t j i × Δ L i s t is an interactive variable that represents the change in skill-based local labor pool indices between province j and i ( Δ L j i s t ) related to job mobility ( M k t j i ). For example, if a technically skilled worker relocates from a rural area to an industrialized urban area, the interactive variable has a positive value; it is expected that this type of job change, along with relocation, is associated with faster wage growth.
Model 1 in Table 9 shows the effect of job mobility on wage growth on average. Job mobility itself is positively associated with wage growth. The wage growth of those who change jobs is 4.3% higher than those who do not. Model 2 takes into account cases of those who change jobs and locations simultaneously. The interactive variable of job mobility*population size change is the difference between the population sizes of the prior and present provinces where they work. Model 2 indicates a statistically positive sign of the interactive variable. Migration associated with job changes to more populated areas increases the likelihood of faster wage growth. Models 3 to 6 show the effects of job mobility on wage growth by four occupational groups. The effects, however, are not significant for all occupational groups. The effects are positive only in cognitive- and technical-skill-oriented occupations but not in social- and physical-skill-oriented occupations. The wage growth rates of those who changed jobs in the cognitive- and technical-oriented occupation groups are 5.4% and 4.9% higher, respectively.
Table 10 presents the effects of skill-based labor pooling on wage growth from job mobility. As a whole, these regression models show that the return of job mobility differs across occupational groups and that it is affected by the degree of skill-based labor pooling. Significant effects of skill-based labor pooling on wage growth from job mobility occurs in the cognitive-, technical-, and physical-skill-oriented occupational groups. The magnitude of the effects of skill-based labor pooling on wage growth is the highest in the technical-skill-oriented occupational groups. When workers change to occupations whose main tasks required technical skills and relocate to areas with a denser population of technically skilled workers, their wage growth rates are 15.4% higher. The magnitudes of cognitive and physical skill labor pool indices in wage growth from job mobility are 13.8% and 11.8%, respectively.
In summary, the analytical models provide evidence of differentiated urban wage premiums based on workplace skills in South Korea. First, the elasticity of population density and size to wages ranges from 0.022 to 0.032, lower than those reported in previous studies [18]. These relatively small magnitudes are somewhat surprising because economic growth has simultaneously occurred with rapid urbanization in South Korea, and urban areas typically provide better job opportunities. It can be explained partly by the spatial unit of analysis, the province, where a large portion of variations is condensed. In addition, the urban wage premium varies considerably according to types of skills. The analysis finds the highest wage premium in cognitive-skill-oriented occupations but only a moderate urban wage premium in the technical and physical-skill-oriented occupations and no urban wage premium in the social-skill-oriented occupations. As the wage levels of cognitive-skill-oriented occupations are high, the benefits of urbanization are more likely to be accrued by those with higher-quality jobs. The job mobility analysis shows immediate benefits to workers who move to denser areas. Those who change jobs and relocate to places with a concentration of similar skill-content workers experience faster wage growth. Particularly, the analysis finds a strong positive effect of cognitive, technical, and physical skill labor pooling on wage growth from job mobility. As a result, this analysis demonstrates that skill-based labor pooling is a significant factor in wage levels and wage growth in South Korea.

6. Conclusions

The paper explored the agglomeration effect of skill-based labor pooling on wage levels and growth in the case of South Korean regional economies. To this end, we developed skill-based labor pooling indices involving cognitive-, social-, technical-, and physical-skill-oriented occupations at a provincial level. These indices showed uneven geographical distributions of four types of skills; cognitive and technical skills were more concentrated while social skills were evenly distributed over the provinces. Then, the analytical model estimated the effect of skill-based labor pooling indices on wage levels and wage growth. The results showed that the wage premium stemming from local labor pooling significantly varied according to the types of skills. The magnitude of benefits was the largest in cognitive-skill-oriented occupations, modest in technical- and physical-skill-oriented occupations, and non-existent in social-skill-oriented occupations. Finally, the analysis also discovered that the agglomeration effect of skill-based labor pooling was immediate to those who changed jobs and relocated to denser areas.
From this study, we suggest several directions of research. For one, the study categorized 44 abilities and skill requirements into four skill types; however, several variations occur within each group, particularly in social skills, which would require a more thorough investigation of the nature of workplace skills and a more nuanced skill classification. In addition, the analysis did not account for the accumulation of workplace skills, or experience. As work experience is an essential element for establishing close matches between workers and firms, a future study could separate young workers from older workers in an examination of the agglomeration effect. Another research topic relates to the relationship between skill-based labor pooling and regional economic performance. Since skill-based labor pooling proffers a regional economic advantage, it impacts region-wide economies and may lead to polarization of regional economies. Thus, skill-based labor pooling could explain the path of regional economic growth.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Berry, C.R.; Glaeser, E.L. The divergence of human capital levels across cities. Pap. Reg. Sci. 2005, 84, 407–444. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Scott, A.J. Space-time variations of human capital assets across US metropolitan areas, 1980 to 2000. Econ. Geogr. 2010, 86, 233–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Bacolod, M.; Blum, B.S.; Strange, W.C. Skills in the city. J. Urban Econ. 2009, 65, 136–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Sunley, P.; Martin, R.; Gardiner, B.; Pike, A. In search of the skilled city: Skills and the occupational evolution of British cities. Urban Stud. 2020, 57, 109–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Glaeser, E.L.; Mare, D.C. Cities and skills. J. Labor Econ. 2001, 19, 316–342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Overman, H.G.; Puga, D. Labor pooling as a source of agglomeration: An empirical investigation. In Agglomeration Economics; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2010; pp. 133–150. [Google Scholar]
  7. Duranton, G.; Puga, D. Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2004; Volume 4, pp. 2063–2117. [Google Scholar]
  8. Abel, J.R.; Deitz, R. Agglomeration and job matching among college graduates. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2015, 51, 14–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Bleakley, H.; Lin, J. Thick-market effects and churning in the labor market: Evidence from US cities. J. Urban Econ. 2012, 72, 87–103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Elvery, J.A. City size and skill intensity. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2010, 40, 367–379. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Gathmann, C.; Schönberg, U. How general is human capital? A task-based approach. J. Labor Econ. 2010, 28, 1–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Reichelt, M.; Abraham, M. Occupational and regional mobility as substitutes: A new approach to understanding job changes and wage inequality. Soc. Forces 2017, 95, 1399–1426. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Andini, M.; De Blasio, G.; Duranton, G.; Strange, W.C. Marshallian labour market pooling: Evidence from Italy. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 2013, 43, 1008–1022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Roca, J.D.L.; Puga, D. Learning by working in big cities. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2017, 84, 106–142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Andersson, F.; Burgess, S.; Lane, J.I. Cities, matching and the productivity gains of agglomeration. J. Urban Econ. 2007, 61, 112–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Geel, R.; Backes-Gellner, U. Occupational mobility within and between skill clusters: An empirical analysis based on the skill-weights approach. Empir. Res. Vocat. Educ. Train. 2011, 1, 21–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Topel, R.H.; Ward, M.P. Job mobility and the careers of young men. Q. J. Econ. 1992, 107, 439–479. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Andersson, M.; Klaesson, J.; Larsson, J.P. The sources of the urban wage premium by worker skills: Spatial sorting or agglomeration economies? Pap. Reg. Sci. 2014, 93, 727–747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Figure 1. Geographical distribution of skill-based local labor pooling. (a) Cognitive-skill-based local labor pool index, (b) social-skill-based local labor pool index, (c) technical-skill-based local labor pool index, and (d) physical-skill-based local labor pool index.
Figure 1. Geographical distribution of skill-based local labor pooling. (a) Cognitive-skill-based local labor pool index, (b) social-skill-based local labor pool index, (c) technical-skill-based local labor pool index, and (d) physical-skill-based local labor pool index.
Sustainability 12 03198 g001aSustainability 12 03198 g001b
Table 1. Factor Analysis for Ability and Skill Requirements.
Table 1. Factor Analysis for Ability and Skill Requirements.
CodeAbility and Skill RequirementFactor 1Factor 2Factor 3Factor 4Uniqueness
aq1Reading Comprehension0.7880.331
aq2Active Listening0.7790.305
aq3Writing0.7540.356
aq4Speaking0.6690.4050.360
aq5Mathematics0.6290.461
aq6Logical Analysis0.7370.315
aq7Critical Thinking0.6260.458
aq8Category Flexibility0.6440.418
aq9Memory0.5740.435
aq10Spatial Perception0.4780.514
aq11Reasoning0.6340.418
aq12Learning Strategies0.6050.4020.402
aq13Attentiveness0.5520.422
aq14Monitoring0.4900.5010.423
aq15Social Perceptiveness0.6480.345
aq16Coordination0.6160.364
aq17Persuasion0.4000.7060.304
aq18Negotiation0.7140.332
aq19Instructing0.4500.4990.456
aq20Service Orientation0.6590.415
aq21Complex Problem Solving0.4940.5220.370
aq22Judgment and Decision Making0.4440.5710.373
aq23Time Management0.5760.412
aq24Management of Financial Resources0.6310.443
aq25Management of Material Resources0.4820.5020.446
aq26Management of Personnel Resources0.6530.375
aq27Troubleshooting0.6380.360
aq28Technology Design0.7040.390
aq29Equipment Selection0.7230.345
aq30Installation0.7570.336
aq31Programming0.4830.540
aq32Quality Control Analysis0.6650.420
aq33Operation and Control0.7330.332
aq34Equipment Maintenance0.7750.283
aq35Repairing0.7880.289
aq36Operation Monitoring0.7770.289
aq37Systems Analysis & Evaluation0.5160.480
aq38Manual Dexterity0.5180.5350.407
aq39Control Movement Abilities0.4870.6390.324
aq40Reaction Time and Speed Abilities0.6810.330
aq41Physical Strength Abilities0.6790.409
aq42Flexibility, Balance, and Coordination0.7250.346
aq43Visual Abilities0.6800.438
aq44Auditory Abilities0.6860.411
Table 2. Skill Scores for the Two-Digit Korean Standard Occupation Classification (KSOC).
Table 2. Skill Scores for the Two-Digit Korean Standard Occupation Classification (KSOC).
Two-Digit KSOCCognitiveSocialTechnicalPhysicalType
Science Professionals and Related Occupations0.815−0.2380.184−0.408Cognitive
Health-, Social-Welfare-, and Religion-Related Occupations0.2120.159−0.3430.255
Education Professionals and Related Occupations0.4080.230−0.3330.056
Legal and Administrative Occupations0.7860.517−0.451−0.263
Business and Finance Professionals and Related Occupations0.4520.401−0.121−0.201
Senior Public Officials and Senior Corporate Officials0.3121.028−0.364−0.332Social
Public, Business Administration, and Marketing Management Occupations0.0720.708−0.354−0.411
Professional Services Management Occupations0.2450.568−0.202−0.116
Construction, Electricity, and Production-Related Managers−0.3700.1350.436−0.310
Sales and Customer Service Managers−0.3110.589−0.180−0.117
Administration and Accounting-Related Occupations−0.0520.223−0.195−0.258
Financial Clerical Occupations−0.0150.403−0.293−0.064
Legal and Inspection Occupations0.1540.232−0.5880.330
Customer Service, Information Desk, Statistical Survey, and Other Clerical Occupations−0.1060.164−0.642−0.026
Caregiving, Health, and Personal Service Workers−0.4080.143−0.3390.131
Transport and Leisure Services Occupations−0.2250.254−0.3720.078
Sales Occupations−0.2490.339−0.154−0.096
Store Sales and Rental Sales Occupations−0.3570.239−0.204−0.044
Information and Communication Professionals and Technical Occupations−0.019−0.2060.613−0.484Technical
Engineering Professionals and Technical Occupations0.189−0.2220.411−0.412
Skilled Forestry Occupations−0.533−0.167−0.135−0.193
Wood- and Furniture-, Musical-Instrument-, and Signboard-Related Trade Occupations−0.4780.0420.3930.134
Metal-Coremaker-Related Trade Occupations−0.628−0.4550.3880.135
Transport- and Machine-Related Trade Occupations−0.535−0.3820.6470.226
Electric- and Electronic-Related Trade Occupations−0.500−0.1700.4380.210
Food-Processing-Related Machine Operating Occupations−0.669−0.4230.3630.037
Textile- and Shoe-Related Machine Operating Occupations−0.747−0.2730.1980.045
Chemical-Related Machine Operating Occupations−0.433−0.4480.1160.077
Metal- and Nonmetal-Related Machine Operating Occupations−0.529−0.2590.3100.073
Machine Production and Related Machine Operating Occupation−0.440−0.3790.2540.152
Electrical- and Electronic-Related Machine Operating Occupations−0.295−0.4050.4140.099
Water Treatment and Recycling-Related Operating Occupation−0.455−0.3480.374−0.005
Wood, Printing, and Other Machine Operating Occupations−0.560−0.2310.4500.229
Culture, Arts, and Sports Professionals and Related Occupations0.0950.050−0.2480.291Physical
Police, Fire Fighting, and Security-Related Service Occupations−0.1220.085−0.2420.576
Cooking and Food Service Occupations−0.5360.047−0.3010.133
Agricultural and Livestock-Related Skilled Occupations−0.656−0.206−0.0180.111
Skilled Fishery Occupations−1.052−0.316−0.0090.192
Food-Processing-Related Trades Occupations−0.660−0.129−0.0020.049
Textile-, Clothing-, and Leather-Related Trade Occupations−0.363−0.1750.0290.199
Information-and-Communications-Technology-Related Occupations−0.726−0.3260.1390.360
Other Technical Occupations−0.480−0.0120.2050.483
Driving and Transport-Related Occupations−0.712−0.414−0.1210.428
Construction and Mining-Related Elementary Occupations−0.087−0.4620.1770.948
Cleaning and Guard-Related Elementary Occupations−0.424−0.108−0.131−0.072
Household Helpers, Cooking Attendants, and Sales-Related Elementary Workers−0.743−0.140−0.280−0.008
Armed Forces−0.0860.099−0.0870.368
Agriculture, Forestry, Fishery, and Other Service Elementary Occupations−0.583−0.302−0.0600.107
Table 3. Comparative Advantage of Province and Skill-based Local Labor Pooling.
Table 3. Comparative Advantage of Province and Skill-based Local Labor Pooling.
TypeProvince NameComparative Advantage of Local Skill Labor Pooling IndexPopulation Percent by Province
CognitiveSocialTechnicalPhysical
Metro ProvinceSeoul1.291.210.860.8919.0%
Busan0.980.970.890.976.7%
Daegu0.971.060.870.974.8%
Daejeon1.301.091.010.962.9%
Incheon0.860.961.160.975.7%
Gangju1.111.020.941.022.8%
Ulsan0.750.821.431.112.3%
Non-Metro ProvinceGyeonggi1.091.031.170.9424.9%
Gangwon0.740.840.631.173.0%
Chungbuk0.890.881.031.163.1%
Chungnam0.760.851.221.194.1%
Jeonbuk0.840.890.651.173.6%
Jeonnam0.610.760.711.103.7%
Gyeongbuk0.620.841.011.095.2%
Gyeongnam0.790.851.131.076.5%
Special DistrictJeju0.821.040.611.281.3%
Sejong1.660.980.860.660.5%
St. Dev. of Skill-based Indices0.270.120.230.14
Table 4. Variables Description.
Table 4. Variables Description.
VariableMeanStd. Dev.MinMax
Personal-relatedGender0.5730.49501
Age46121888
Share of High School0.3500.47701
Share of 2-Year Vocational College0.1760.38101
Share 4-Year University or More0.3040.46001
Job-relatedWage23715644200
Firm Size2482530060,000
Share of Job Mobility0.0870.28201
Cognitive Skill Score−0.2940.366−1.0521.021
Social Skill Score−0.0260.351−1.3151.028
Technical Skill Score−0.0910.354−0.6940.822
Physical Skill Score0.0200.303−0.8481.159
Province-relatedPopulation6,207,0504,525,717210,88412,900,000
Population Density448361479216,761
Cognitive Skill Labor Pool Index1931580412
Social Skill Labor Pool Index3863020786
Technical Skill Labor Pool Index2271770545
Physical Skill Labor Pool Index3232230678
Table 5. Frequency of Job Mobility Across Individual Characteristics.
Table 5. Frequency of Job Mobility Across Individual Characteristics.
Frequency of Job MobilityPercentage of Job MobilityTotal Observations
GenderMale10338.4%12,314
Female8399.1%9191
Age Group20–2922114.3%1547
30–394839.1%5312
40–495268.2%6427
50–593777.7%4888
60–691827.7%2378
EducationLess Than High School2988.2%3642
High School7039.3%7536
2-Year Vocational College3469.1%3787
More Than 4-Year University5258.0%6540
Sum18728.7%21,505
Table 6. Frequency of Job Mobility within and between Occupational Groups.
Table 6. Frequency of Job Mobility within and between Occupational Groups.
Frequency of Job MobilityPercentage of Job MobilityTotal
within 1-Digit Occupationbetween 1-Digit Occupationswithin 1-Digit Occupationbetween 1-Digit Occupations
Managers141253.8%46.2%26
Professionals and Related Workers26112467.8%32.2%385
Clerks10411647.3%52.7%220
Service Workers9913342.7%57.3%232
Sales Workers10214341.6%58.4%245
Skilled Agricultural, Forestry, and Fishery Workers2365.3%94.7%38
Craft and Related Trades Workers1027458.0%42.0%176
Equipment, Machine Operating, and Assembling Workers11810752.4%47.6%225
Elementary Workers15613653.4%46.6%292
Sum95888152.1%47.9%1839
Table 7. Frequency of Job Mobility within and between Provinces.
Table 7. Frequency of Job Mobility within and between Provinces.
Frequency of Job MobilityPercentage of Job MobilityTotal
within Provincebetween Provinceswithin Provincebetween Provinces
Metro ProvinceSeoul2599074.2%25.8%349
Busan1362186.6%13.4%157
Daegu721979.1%20.9%91
Daejeon401572.7%27.3%55
Incheon703169.3%30.7%101
Gwangju381473.1%26.9%52
Ulsan41785.4%14.6%48
Non-Metro ProvinceGyeonggi3488380.7%19.3%431
Gangwon24485.7%14.3%28
Chungbuk611283.6%16.4%73
Chungnam872478.4%21.6%111
Jeonbuk49590.7%9.3%54
Jeonnam441081.5%18.5%54
Gyeongbuk722574.2%25.8%97
Gyeongnam1431888.8%11.2%161
Jeju90100.0%0.0%9
Sum149337879.8%20.2%1871
Table 8. Regression Results for Urban Wage Premiums with Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling.
Table 8. Regression Results for Urban Wage Premiums with Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling.
Conventional Urban Wage Premium ModelSkill-Based Local Labor Pooling Model
Model 1Model 2Model 3
(Cognitive-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 4
(Social-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 5
(Technical-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 6
(Physical-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Individual Variables
Gender0.375 ***(0.011)0.372 ***(0.011)0.261 ***(0.033)0.372 ***(0.020)0.427 ***(0.030)0.343 ***(0.024)
Age0.070 ***(0.003)0.069 ***(0.003)0.034 ***(0.009)0.051 ***(0.006)0.103 ***(0.008)0.053 ***(0.007)
Sq. Age−0.001 ***(0.000)−0.001 ***(0.000)−0.000 ***0.000 −0.001 ***0.000 −0.001 ***0.000 −0.001 ***0.000
Education Dummy
High School 0.087 ***(0.020)0.091 ***(0.020)−0.147(0.106)0.225 ***(0.060)0.139 ***(0.044)−0.003(0.027)
2-Year Vocational College0.237 ***(0.023)0.243 ***(0.023)0.024(0.107)0.322 ***(0.062)0.258 ***(0.051)0.140 ***(0.045)
4-Year University or More0.269 ***(0.022)0.275 ***(0.022)−0.045(0.107)0.350 ***(0.061)0.395 ***(0.047)0.173 ***(0.046)
Firm Size0.090 ***(0.003)0.090 ***(0.003)0.141 ***(0.009)0.088 ***(0.005)0.072 ***(0.006)0.066 ***(0.008)
Provincial Variables
Population Density0.022 ***(0.003)
Population Size0.032 ***(0.006)
Skill Score
Cognitive−0.028(0.062)
Social0.461 ***(0.091)
Technical0.140 **(0.063)
Physical0.210 ***(0.058)
Skill-Based Local Labor Pool
Cognitive0.075 ***(0.014)
Social0.014(0.010)
Technical0.025 **(0.012)
Physical0.031 **(0.015)
Intercept3.065 ***(0.081)2.745 ***(0.127)3.693 ***(0.229)3.332 ***(0.152)2.216 ***(0.207)3.565 ***(0.193)
Observations4503450375215659701051
R-square0.4480.4450.4080.4470.4450.411
Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. *** significant at 1% level, ** at 5% level, and * at 10% level.
Table 9. Regression Result for Effect of Job Mobility.
Table 9. Regression Result for Effect of Job Mobility.
Model 1
(All Occupations)
Model 2
(All Occupations)
Model 3
(Cognitive-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 4
(Social-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 5
(Technical-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 6
(Physical-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Time-Varying Variables
Age −0.001 ***0.000 −0.001 ***0.000 0(0.001)−0.001(0.001)−0.001 **(0.001)−0.001 **(0.001)
Firm-Size0.002(0.002)0.002(0.002)0.004(0.006)−0.001(0.003)0.002(0.004)0.011 **(0.005)
Effect of Job Mobility
Job Mobility Dummy0.043 ***(0.011)0.054 *(0.030)0.028(0.019)0.049 **(0.024)0.036(0.022)
Job Mobility × Population Size Change0.069 ***(0.022)
Intercept0.080 ***(0.016)0.090 ***(0.015)0.046(0.046)0.071 ***(0.026)0.098 ***(0.037)0.069 **(0.031)
Observations4120 4120 6691430910958
Adj. R-square0.0060.0050.0010.0010.0070.01
Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. *** significant at 1% level, ** at 5% level, and * at 10% level.
Table 10. Regression Result for Effect of Interactive Variables between Job Mobility and Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling.
Table 10. Regression Result for Effect of Interactive Variables between Job Mobility and Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling.
Model 1
(Cognitive-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 2
(Social-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 3
(Technical-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Model 4
(Physical-Skill-Oriented Occupations)
Time-Varying Variables
Age0.000 (0.001)−0.001(0.001)−0.002 **(0.001)−0.001 **(0.001)
Firm-Size0.003(0.006)−0.001(0.003)0.001(0.004)0.010 **(0.005)
Interactive Variables
Cognitive × Job Mobility0.138 ***(0.052)
Social × Job Mobility−0.006(0.038)
Technical × Job Mobility0.154 ***(0.044)
Physical × Job Mobility0.118 **(0.056)
Intercept0.062(0.045)0.077 ***(0.026)0.110 ***(0.036)0.080 ***(0.030)
Observations6691430910958
Adj. R-square0.0010.0010.0070.01
Note: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. *** significant at 1% level, ** at 5% level, and * at 10% level.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Choi, T. Agglomeration Effect of Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling: Evidence of South Korea. Sustainability 2020, 12, 3198. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12083198

AMA Style

Choi T. Agglomeration Effect of Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling: Evidence of South Korea. Sustainability. 2020; 12(8):3198. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12083198

Chicago/Turabian Style

Choi, Taelim. 2020. "Agglomeration Effect of Skill-Based Local Labor Pooling: Evidence of South Korea" Sustainability 12, no. 8: 3198. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12083198

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop