Next Article in Journal
Amplitude-Versus-Angle (AVA) Inversion for Pre-Stack Seismic Data with L0-Norm-Gradient Regularization
Previous Article in Journal
The Shape Entropy of Small Bodies
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Multiperson Decision-Making Using Consistent Interval-Valued Fuzzy Information with Application in Supplier Selection

1
School of Computer Science, Chengdu University, Chengdu 610059, China
2
Department of Mathematics, COMSATS University Islamabad, Lahore Campus, Lahore 53710, Pakistan
3
Department of Mathematics, University of Education Bank Road Campus, Lahore 54000, Pakistan
4
Department of Mathematics, Virtual University, Lahore 54000, Pakistan
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2023, 11(4), 879; https://doi.org/10.3390/math11040879
Submission received: 28 December 2022 / Revised: 31 January 2023 / Accepted: 7 February 2023 / Published: 9 February 2023
(This article belongs to the Topic Data-Driven Group Decision-Making)

Abstract

:
This study describes a consistency-based approach for multiperson decision-making (MPDM) in which decision-makers’ suggestions are expressed as incomplete interval-valued fuzzy preference relations. The presented approach utilizes Lukasiewicz’s t-norm in conjunction with additive reciprocity to obtain comprehensive interval valued fuzzy preference relations from each expert, and the transitive closure formula also produces L-consistency. We would evaluate the consistency weights of the experts using consistency analysis. Experts are allocated final priority weights by combining the consistency weights and preset weights. A collective consistency matrix is then constructed from the weighted sum of preference matrices. After computing the possibility degrees, the normalization procedure is utilized to generate complimentary matrices, and the final ranking values of alternatives are derived as well. Finally, a numerical example demonstrates the efficacy of the suggested approach following a comparison analysis.

1. Introduction

Decision-making (DM) problems are associated with all aspects of modern life, including the assessment of human resource quality, location of facilities and selection of infrastructure projects. MPDM is a situation in which a number of experts collaborate on some possible set of available alternatives for choosing the best option, although each expert could have specific inspirations or goals and a separate decision-making process. Several techniques to handle MPDM situations have been proposed recently [1,2]. Preference relation seems to be the most famous expression included in MPDM since it is a powerful resource to model decision procedures when we need to incorporate expert preferences into group preferences [3]. Primarily, two kinds of pairwise comparisons have been used to incorporate decision models; multiplicative preference relations (MPRs) [4] and fuzzy preference relations (FPRs) [5], the latter being more common for expressing the expert’s preferences over alternatives.
In the case of FPR, the expert allocates a numerical value to each pair of alternatives within [0, 1] and indicates the preferable strength of one alternative over the other. By doing so, the first and logical question immediately arises: what criteria must be met in order to obtain consistent results in the final ranking? There are three important and graded stages of rationality in connection to preference relations:
  • Indifference,
  • Reciprocity,
  • Transitivity.
The mathematical modeling of all such rationale assumptions depends greatly on the scales used to set the choice values [6].
In the literature, it is frequently described that the third level guarantees consistent information, and the property is known as a consistency property. The lack of consistency leads to unreliable judgments, and it is, therefore, important to analyze the conditions that remain a part of consistency. On the other hand, it is difficult to achieve fully consistent information in practice, particularly while evaluating choices for a large range of possibilities. Many structures for the transitivity of FPRs have been proposed in the literature, and precision can be seen explicitly. The notion of transitivity that has been found to be most appropriate for fuzzy ordering is L-transitivity, i.e., r i k max ( r i j + r j k 1 , 0 ) , and finds the weakest one [7]. In this paper, L-transitivity is used for preference ordering and ranking of alternatives by constructing fully consistent preference relationships. In addition, it is a really radical concept to model such types of transitivity, and there is very little published research on this context.
It is frequently difficult to evaluate an expert’s preference using a precise, crisp scale in real-world scenarios since they may have a vague understanding of the preferred values of one alternative over another. An interval valued fuzzy preference relation (IVFPR) is one such strategy where decisions are made in the form of intervals. IVFPRs may flexibly indicate ambiguous preferences over alternatives because intervals can rationally cover and convey the ambiguity and uncertainty of human judgment. Recent studies on IVFPRs focus mainly on the nature of:
(i)
The consistency analysis;
(ii)
The evaluation of priority weights.
The consistency of the IVFPRs does not necessitate any contradiction in the judgments of experts. For certain cases, however, it might be difficult for experts to come forward with absolutely clear results on alternatives. However, priority weights resulting from inconsistent IVFPRs contribute to an untrustworthy judgment. The consistency of IVFPRs is, therefore, an important issue. In 2008, Xu and Chen [8] presented additive and multiplicative consistent IVFPRs as an extension of the additive and multiplicative consistent FPRs. Chen and Zhou [9] suggested an approach for MPDM with IVFPRs in 2011 and provided a quality test for IVFPRs. Liu et al. [10] developed a definition for consistent IVFPR in 2012 by assessing whether or not two FPRs generated by the IVFPR were consistent. After introducing the interval [0.5, 0.5] in 2014, Xu et al. [11] established the additive consistency of the IVFPR and looked into the relationship between the multiplicative consistency and the additive consistency of IVFPR. In 2015, Wang and Li [12] introduced some properties for multiplicative consistent IVFPR after investigating the multiplicative transitivity defined in [13]. In 2018, Wang et al. [14] investigated a MPDM method with IVFPRs based on geometric consistency. The max-consistency index and min-consistency index of an IVFPR are derived based on their geometric consistency. In 2021, Cheng et al. [15] introduced a new consistency definition of interval multiplicative preference relation with desirable properties, and the sufficient and necessary conditions of the new consistency definition were also provided. In 2023, Shu et al. [16] proposed a method for group decision-making with interval multiplicative preference relations based on geometric consistency.
Almost all of the preceding work is focused on IVFPRs for comprehensive data. However, in the case of MPDM, certain circumstances are inescapable in which an expert lacks appropriate information on the issue owing to time limits, a lack of experience, and a lack of skill within the problem area [17,18,19,20,21,22]. An incomplete preference structure will be constructed as a result of the expert’s potential inability to provide his or her perspective on the particular aspects of the situation. There are a few MPDM studies that deal with incomplete interval valued fuzzy preference relations (IIVFPRs), although there has been research based on incomplete FPRs published in the literature [11,12].
This study introduces an innovative MPDM method for scenarios where group recommendations are given as IIVFPRs. The algorithm focuses on obtaining complete L-consistent interval valued fuzzy relations in the form of matrices. First, the proposed method estimates the missing preference values and constructs the consistent matrix for each IVFPR for each expert. Secondly, in order to calculate the average degree of preference of each alternative over all remaining alternatives, an interval normalizing approach is used to integrate all consistent IVFPRs into a collective consistent matrix. Thirdly, it calculates the possibility degree and constructs the complementary matrix. Finally, it determines the ranking values of each alternative.

2. Preliminaries

As is generally known, a fuzzy subset A of a set U is a mapping A : U [ 0 , 1 ] , and the value A ( u ) for a certain u is typically connected with some expert’s level of confidence. An accepted viewpoint holds that attributing an exact number to an expert’s judgment is overly limiting and that assigning a range of values is more realistic. This means replacing the interval [ 0 , 1 ] of fuzzy values by the set L = [ l , l + ] 0 , 1 2 with l l + .
Definition 1
([23,24]). A fuzzy set A on universe of discourse X is known as an interval valued fuzzy set if it is described by a mapping A : X L , where L = [ l , l + ] 0 , 1 2 with l l + .
T-norms are employed as conjuctors in fuzzy logic. Therefore, we will define one of them and explain how its interval valued counterpart works.
Definition 2
([25]). A mapping T : [ 0 , 1 ] × [ 0 , 1 ] [ 0 , 1 ] having commutative, associative, and increasing nature with T ( 1 , a ) = a for all a [ 0 , 1 ] is known as triangular norm (t-norm). The concept of a t-norm on [ 0 , 1 ] can be extended to subintervals of [ 0 , 1 ] .
Definition 3
([23]). An extended t-norm, T e , is an increasing, commutative, associative, and L × L L mapping that satisfies:
T e ( [ 1 , 1 ] , [ l , l + ] ) = [ l , l + ] for all [ l , l + ] L .
Let T be a triangular norm. The mapping T e is defined as:
T e ( [ l , l + ] , [ m , m + ] ) = [ T ( l , m ) , T ( l + , m + ) ]
for [ l , l + ] , [ m , m + ] L , is an extended t-norm on ( L , ) , where ⊆ represents the crisp set inclusion. The extended interval t-norm corresponding to Lukasiewicz’s t-norm can be computed by:
T L ( [ l , l + ] , [ m , m + ] ) = [ max ( l + m 1 , 0 ) , max ( l + + m + 1 , 0 ) ] .
Definition 4
([3]). A fuzzy preference relation R over a finite set X of alternatives, X = { x 1 , x 2 ,   x 3 , , x n } , is a fuzzy set on the product set X × X , i.e., it is characterized by a membership function μ R : X × X [ 0 , 1 ] .
On s similar pattern, an interval valued preference relation (IVPR) R ¯ over a finite set X of alternatives, X = { x 1 , x 2 ,  …,  x n } , is an interval valued fuzzy set on the product set X × X , i.e., it is characterized by a membership function μ R ¯ : X × X L . Hence R ¯ = r ¯ i j n × n where r ¯ i j = [ r i j , r i j + ] ,   0 r i j r i j + 1 ,   r ¯ i j = [ 1 , 1 ] r ¯ j i and r ¯ i i = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] for all i , j N .
As is common in the literature on FPRs, an IVFPR on X can also be conveniently expressed by an n × n matrix R = ( r ¯ i j = [ r i j , r i j + ] ) n × n , where r ¯ i j denotes the degree of preference of alternative x i over the alternative x j with r ¯ i j L ,   r ¯ i j + r ¯ j i = 1 ¯ (additive reciprocity) for 1 i n and 1 j n . If r ¯ i j = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] , then there is no difference between the alternatives x i and x j .
Definition 5.
An IVFPR R ¯ is said to be L-consistent, if for i j k { 1 , 2 , 3 , , n } it holds:
r ¯ i k T L ( r ¯ i j , r ¯ j k ) ( L - t r a n s i t i v i t y )
which implies that r i k max ( r i j + r j k 1 , 0 ) and r i k + max ( r i j + + r j k + 1 , 0 ) hold at the same time.
Definition 6.
An IVFPR relation R ¯ = ( r ¯ i j ) n × n is said to be incomplete if it contains at least one unknown preference value r ¯ i j for which the expert has no idea about the degree of preference of alternative x i over the alternative x j .
Next, we present the procedure to estimate the missing preference values in an IIVFPR and to construct the L-consistent complete fuzzy preference matrix.

3. Procedure to Receive Complete IVFPRs

For the determination of missing preferences in the IIVFPR R ¯ = ( r ¯ i j ) n × n , the measures for the pairs of alternatives for known and unknown preference values are shown in the following sets:
A v = { ( i , j ) i j i , j { 1 , 2 , 3 , , n } }
E v = { ( i , j ) A v r ¯ i j is known }
M v = { ( i , j ) A v r ¯ i j is unknown }
where A v is associated with the overall set of pairs of alternatives with known and unknown preference values of one alternative over another; E v and M v are related to the sets of pairs of alternatives for which the corresponding preference values of the one alternative over the other are known and unknown, respectively. It is to be noted that the preference value of alternative x i over x j belongs to the family of closed subintervals of [ 0 , 1 ] (i.e., r ¯ i j L ( [ 0 , 1 ] ) ). Since r ¯ i j = [ 1 , 1 ] r ¯ j i , r ¯ i i = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] for 1 i n and 1 j n , therefore, based on L-transitivity r ¯ i k T L ( r ¯ i j , r ¯ j k ) , the following set can be defined to determine the unknown preference value r ¯ i k of alternative x i over alternative x k :
H i k 1 = { ( i , k ) , j i , ( i , j ) E v , ( j , k ) E v and ( i , k ) M v } ,
for i = { 1 , 2 , 3 , , n } , j = { 1 , 2 , 3 , , n } and k = { 1 , 2 , 3 , , n } . Based on (6), we can determine the unknown preference value r ¯ i k for x i over x k as follows:
r ¯ i k = max ( j H i k 1 T L ( r ¯ i j , r ¯ j k ) ) , if H i k 1 [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] , otherwise
By using the condition r ¯ i j = [ 1 , 1 ] r ¯ j i , the value of r ¯ k i can be calculated as follows:
r ¯ k i = 1 r i k + , 1 r i k
Therefore, the new sets of pairs of alternatives for which preference values of one alternative over the other are known and unknown will be:
E v = E v { ( i , k ) , ( k , i ) } ,
M v = M v / { ( i , k ) , ( k , i ) } .
To get the L-consistency, compute the transitive closure of the IVFPR after having the complete form by using:
r ¯ i k = max j i , k r ¯ i k , T L r ¯ i j , r ¯ j k such that r ¯ i k = [ 1 , 1 ] r ¯ k i .
Example 1.
Let R ¯ = ( r ¯ i j ) 4 × 4 be an IIVFPR for the alternatives x 1 , x 2 , x 3 , and x 4 , given as follows:
R ¯ = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] r ¯ 12 [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] r ¯ 21 [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] r ¯ 24 [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] [ 0.1 , 0.6 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 0.4 ] r ¯ 42 [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ]
where r ¯ 12 , r ¯ 21 , r ¯ 24 and r ¯ 42 are unknown preference values. Now, applying (6)–(10) to estimate the unknown preference values for the alternative x i over x k , 1 i 4 and 1 k 4 , we obtain:
E v = { ( 1 , 3 ) , ( 1 , 4 ) , ( 2 , 3 ) , ( 3 , 1 ) , ( 3 , 2 ) , ( 3 , 4 ) , ( 4 , 1 ) , ( 4 , 3 ) } , M v = { ( 1 , 2 ) , ( 2 , 1 ) , ( 2 , 4 ) , ( 4 , 2 ) } . H 12 = { 3 } , r ¯ 12 = T L ( r ¯ 13 , r ¯ 32 ) = [ max ( r 13 + r 32 1 , 0 ) , max ( r 13 + + r 32 + 1 , 0 ) ] , = [ 0 , 0.5 ] . r ¯ 21 = [ 1 , 1 ] [ 0 , 0.5 ] = [ 0.5 , 1 ] .
E v = { ( 1 , 2 ) , ( 1 , 3 ) , ( 1 , 4 ) , ( 2 , 1 ) , ( 2 , 3 ) , ( 3 , 1 ) , ( 3 , 2 ) , ( 3 , 4 ) , ( 4 , 1 ) , ( 4 , 3 ) } , M v = { ( 2 , 4 ) , ( 4 , 2 ) } . H 24 = { 1 , 3 } , r ¯ 24 = max ( T L ( r ¯ 21 , r ¯ 14 ) , T L ( r ¯ 23 , r ¯ 34 ) ) = max ( [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] , [ 0 , 0.8 ] ) = [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] . r ¯ 21 = [ 1 , 1 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] = [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] .
Hence, the complete IVFPR is obtained under the above process as:
R ¯ = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0 , 0.5 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] [ 0.5 , 1 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] [ 0.1 , 0.6 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 0.4 ] [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ]
By applying (11) on (12), R ¯ becomes an L-consistent IVFPR R ¯ ˜ as follows:
r ¯ 12 = max j = 3 , 4 [ 0 , 0.5 ] , T L r ¯ 1 j , r ¯ j 2 = max [ 0 , 0.5 ] , [ 0 , 0.5 ] , [ 0 , 0.7 ] = [ 0 , 0.7 ] r ¯ 21 = [ 1 , 1 ] [ 0 , 0.7 ] = [ 0.3 , 1.0 ] r ¯ 13 = max j = 2 , 4 [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] , T L r ¯ 1 j , r ¯ j 3 = max [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] , [ 0 , 0.5 ] , [ 0 , 0.2 ] = [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] r ¯ 31 = [ 1 , 1 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] = [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] r ¯ 14 = max j = 2 , 3 [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] , T L r ¯ 1 j , r ¯ j 3 = max [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] , [ 0 , 0.5 ] , [ 0.2 , 0.8 ] = [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] r ¯ 41 = [ 1 , 1 ] [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] = [ 0.2 , 0.4 ] r ¯ 23 = max j = 1 , 4 [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] , T L r ¯ 2 j , r ¯ j 3 = max [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] , [ 0 , 0.9 ] , [ 0 , 0.2 ] = [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] r ¯ 32 = [ 1 , 1 ] [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] = [ 0.1 , 0.6 ] r ¯ 24 = max j = 1 , 3 [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] , T L r ¯ 1 j , r ¯ j 2 = max [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] , [ 0 , 0.8 ] , [ 0 , 0.8 ] = [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] r ¯ 42 = [ 1 , 1 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] = [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] r ¯ 34 = max j = 1 , 2 [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] , T L r ¯ 3 j , r ¯ j 4 = max [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] , [ 0 , 0.2 ] , [ 0 , 0.4 ] = [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] r ¯ 43 = [ 1 , 1 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] = [ 0.1 , 0.4 ]
Hence
R ¯ = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0 , 0.7 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] [ 0.3 , 1 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] [ 0.1 , 0.6 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 0.4 ] [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] .
However, R ¯ is not L-consistent so far because the following inequalities do not hold:
r 31 + max ( r 32 + + r 21 + 1 , 0 ) 0.4 0.6 ; r 32 + max ( r 34 + + r 42 + 1 , 0 ) 0.6 0.8 ; r 41 + max ( r 42 + + r 21 + 1 , 0 ) 0.4 0.9 ; r 43 + max ( r 42 + + r 23 + 1 , 0 ) 0.4 0.8 .
Therefore, we have to apply (11) again on (13), and the repeated application of (11) results in an L-consistent IVFPR R ¯ ˜ given as:
R ¯ ˜ = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0 , 0.7 ] [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] [ 0.3 , 1 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ]
one can easily check that (14) is fully L-consistent because r ¯ ˜ i k max ( r ¯ ˜ i j + r ¯ ˜ j k 1 , 0 ) i.e., r ˜ i k max ( r ˜ i j + r ˜ j k 1 , 0 ) and r ˜ i k + max ( r ˜ i j + + r ˜ j k + 1 , 0 ) , hold for i , j , k { 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 }   ( i j k ) .

4. Selection of Best Alternative(s) in MPDM with IIVFPRs

This section addresses a technique for MPDM based on incomplete interval valued fuzzy preference relations (IIVFPRs), and obtaining L-consistency is proposed. The procedure works in the following steps:
(i)
Estimation of the missing preference values;
(ii)
Conversion of the completed preference matrix into an L-consistent matrix;
(iii)
Consistency analysis of IVFPRs and measure of the consistency weight vector of the experts;
(iv)
Derivation of priority weights of the experts;
(v)
Aggregation of all consistent preference relations to receive the weighted collective matrix;
(vi)
Construction of complementary preference relation by calculating the possibility degree;
(vii)
Finally, the algorithm determines the score of each alternative for ranking the preference order of the alternatives.
Hence, in this section, the procedure given in Section 2 is extended for MPDM in IIVFPRs environment and toward the end, an explanatory example to validate the anticipated technique is also given. Suppose that there are n alternatives x 1 , x 2 , , x n , and m experts E 1 , E 2 , , E m with weight vector λ i ( i = 1 , 2 , 3 , m ) . Let R ¯ q be the IVFPR for expert E q shown as follows:
R ¯ q = r ¯ i j q n × n = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] r ¯ 12 q . . r ¯ 1 n q r ¯ 21 q [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] . . r ¯ 2 n q . . . . . . . . r ¯ n 1 q r ¯ n 2 q . . [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] ,
where r ¯ i j q L ( [ 0 , 1 ] ) is the preference value given by expert E q for alternative x i over x j , r ¯ i j q = [ 1 , 1 ] r ¯ j i q , r ¯ i i q = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] ,   1 i n , 1 j n and 1 q m . The proposed MPDM technique is given as follows:
Step-i: 
Determine the sets A v q , E v q and M v q of pairs of alternatives for known and unknown preference values, respectively, shown as follows:
A v q = { ( i , j ) i j i , j { 1 , 2 , 3 , , n } } ,
E v q = { ( i , j ) A v r ¯ i j q is known }
M v q = { ( i , j ) A v r ¯ i j q is unknown } ,
where 1 i n , 1 j n , and 1 q m . Now, construct the set H i k q based on the sets E v q and M v q , and is used to estimate the unknown preference values r ¯ i k q for the alternative x i over x k by expert E q as follows:
H i k q = { j i , k ( i , j ) E v q , ( j , k ) E v q and ( i , k ) M v q } ,
r ¯ i k q = max j H i k q ( T L ( r ¯ i j q , r ¯ j k q ) ) , if H i k q [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] , otherwise .
By using the condition, r ¯ j i q = [ 1 , 1 ] r ¯ i j q , the value of r ¯ k i can be calculated as follows:
r ¯ k i q = 1 r i k q + , 1 r i k q
Hence
E v q = E v q { ( i , k ) , ( k , i ) } ,
M v q = M v q { ( i , k ) , ( k , i ) } .
Step-ii: 
An L-consistent matrix R ¯ ˜ q = r ¯ ˜ i j q n × n is obtained by using the following formula:
r ¯ ˜ i k q = max j i , k r ¯ i k q , T L r ¯ i j q , r ¯ j k q such that r ¯ ˜ i k q = [ 1 , 1 ] r ¯ ˜ k i q .
Step-iii: 
After evaluating the complete IVFPRs, we can then approximate the degrees of consistency of IVFPRs R ¯ q based on its similarity with the corresponding L-consistent R ¯ ˜ q by computing their distances. To estimate the consistency level of IVFPR given by the expert E q , construct the FPR A q = a i j q n × n and the consistency matrix A ˜ q = a ˜ i j q n × n for expert E q using average values as:
A q = a i j q n × n = 1 2 a i j q + a i j q + n × n
A ˜ q = a ˜ i j q n × n = 1 2 a ˜ i j q + a ˜ i j q + n × n
where preference values a i j q and a ˜ i j q fall in [ 0 , 1 ] , 1 i n , 1 j n , and 1 q m . Now, to estimate the consistency degree of an FPR A q based on its similarity with the corresponding L-transitive FPR A ˜ q , we use three levels:
1.
The L-consistent index ( L C I ) of a pair of alternatives is determined by using:
L C I ( r ¯ i j q ) = 1 d ( a i j q , a ˜ i j q )
where d ( a i j q , a ˜ i j q ) is the error (distance) measured by ε r ¯ i j q = d ( a i j q , a ˜ i j q ) = a i j q a ˜ i j q . Seemingly, the higher the value of L C I ( r ¯ i j q ) , the more consistent r ¯ i j q is with respect to the rest of the preference values involving alternatives x i and x j .
2.
The L C I of alternatives x i , 1 i n , is evaluated by:
L C I ( x i ) = 1 2 ( n 1 ) n j = 1 ( L C I ( r ¯ i j q ) + L C I ( r ¯ j i q ) )
3.
The L C I of an IVFPR R ¯ q is obtained by taking the average of all L C I of alternatives x i :
L C I ( R ¯ q ) = 1 n n i = 1 L C I ( x i )
As a result, utilizing the following relation, consistency weights can be allocated to experts.
C w ( E q ) = L C I ( R ¯ q ) q = 1 m L C I ( R ¯ q )
Step-iv: 
The final priority weights for experts shall be assigned after evolving the respective predefined weights and consistency weights using the following relationship:
w ( E q ) = λ q × C w ( E q ) q = 1 m λ q × C w ( E q )
where q = 1 m w ( E q ) = 1 . If λ q is not given, then consistency weights will be taken as the priority weights of the experts.
Step-v: 
Construct the cumulative matrix R ¯ C among all experts as shown below:
R ¯ C = r ¯ i j c n × n = m q = 1 w ( E q ) × r ¯ ˜ i j q n × n ,
where 1 i n , 1 j n .
Step-vi: 
Now, first, we calculate the average degree a v ¯ i of alternative x i over all other alternatives by using the interval normalizing method
a v ¯ i = j = 1 , j i n r ¯ i j c i = 1 i j , n j = 1 n r ¯ i j c , i = 1 , 2 , 3 , , n
then the possibility degree d i j = d ( a v ¯ i a v ¯ j ) by using the following formula [19]:
d ( a v ¯ i a v ¯ j ) = min max a v i + a v j a v i + a v j + a v j + a v i , 0 , 1
to construct the L-consistent complementary matrix D = d i j n × n , where d i j 0 ,   d i j + d j i = 1 ,   i , j = 1 , 2 , 3 , , n .
Step-vii: 
Finally, the ranking value R V ( x i ) of alternative x i can be determined by using the formula:
R V ( x i ) = 2 n ( n 1 ) n j = 1 , j i d i j ,
where 1 i n and i = 1 n R V ( x i ) = 1 .
Example 2.
A textile mill manager desires to select a suitable supplier to purchase the raw material for new products. Initially, the mill manager selects four suppliers, signified as x i ( i = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 ) , and presents them for further evaluation. A committee consisting of three experts E q ( q = 1 , 2 , 3 ) with weights vector λ q = ( 1 / 2 , 1 / 4 , 1 / 4 ) , respectively, from different departments, has been formed to assess the four suppliers x i ( i = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 ) . Suppose that the experts E q ( q = 1 , 2 , 3 ) provide their assessments in the form of the following IIVFPRs:
R ¯ 1 = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] r ¯ 12 1 [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] r ¯ 14 1 r ¯ 21 1 [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.2 , 0.7 ] [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 0.4 ] [ 0.3 , 0.8 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] r ¯ 41 1 [ 0.1 , 0.6 ] [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] ,
R ¯ 2 = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] r ¯ 12 [ 0.4 , 0.6 ] [ 0.2 , 0.9 ] r ¯ 21 [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.4 , 0.8 ] r ¯ 24 [ 0.4 , 0.6 ] [ 0.2 , 0.6 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.3 , 0.7 ] [ 0.1 , 0.8 ] r ¯ 42 [ 0.3 , 0.7 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] ,
and
R ¯ 3 = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.4 , 0.8 ] [ 0.3 , 0.9 ] r ¯ 14 3 [ 0.2 , 0.6 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] r ¯ 23 3 [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.7 ] r ¯ 32 3 [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] r ¯ 34 3 r ¯ 41 3 [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] r ¯ 43 3 [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] .
Step-i: 
By the utilization of (15) to (21), the unknown preference degrees for the IVFPR R ¯ 1 given by expert E 1 are calculated, and R ¯ 1 in complete form is:
R ¯ 1 = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0 , 0.6 ] [ 0.6 , 0.8 ] [ 0.2 , 0.7 ] [ 0.4 , 1.0 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.2 , 0.7 ] [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 0.4 ] [ 0.3 , 0.8 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.6 , 0.9 ] [ 0.3 , 0.8 ] [ 0.1 , 0.6 ] [ 0.1 , 0.4 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] .
Similarly, the missing preference values in R ¯ 2 and R ¯ 3 are estimated.
Step-ii: 
Now, applying (22) to get L-transitive IVFPR R ¯ ˜ 1 under the generalized t-norm T L as:
R ¯ ˜ 1 = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0 , 0.6 ] [ 0.2 , 0.8 ] [ 0.2 , 0.7 ] [ 0.4 , 1.0 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.2 , 0.8 ] [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 0.8 ] [ 0.2 , 0.8 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.4 , 0.9 ] [ 0.3 , 0.8 ] [ 0.1 , 0.6 ] [ 0.1 , 0.6 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] .
In a similar manner, L-transitive IVFPRs R ¯ ˜ 2 and R ¯ ˜ 3 against experts E 2 and E 3 are determined:
R ¯ ˜ 2 = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0 , 0.9 ] [ 0.3 , 0.7 ] [ 0 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 1.0 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.3 , 0.8 ] [ 0 , 0.9 ] [ 0.3 , 0.7 ] [ 0.2 , 0.7 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.2 , 0.7 ] [ 0.1 , 1.0 ] [ 0.1 , 1.0 ] [ 0.3 , 0.8 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] , R ¯ ˜ 3 = [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] [ 0 , 0.8 ] [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0 , 0.8 ] [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 1.0 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] [ 0.2 , 1 ] [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] [ 0.1 , 0.9 ] [ 0.5 , 0.5 ] .
Step-iii: 
To this end, we transform the IVFPRs R ¯ q and R ¯ ˜ q ( q = 1 , 2 , 3 ) into corresponding FPRs A q and A ˜ q ( q = 1 , 2 , 3 ) by using (23) and (24):
A 1 = 0.50 0.30 0.70 0.45 0.70 0.50 0.45 0.65 0.30 0.55 0.50 0.75 0.55 0.35 0.25 0.50 and A ˜ 1 = 0.50 0.30 0.50 0.45 0.70 0.50 0.50 0.65 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.65 0.55 0.35 0.35 0.5 ,
A 2 = 0.50 0.10 0.50 0.55 0.90 0.50 0.60 0.45 0.50 0.40 0.50 0.50 0.45 0.55 0.50 0.50 and A ˜ 2 = 0.50 0.45 0.50 0.45 0.55 0.50 0.55 0.45 0.50 0.45 0.50 0.45 0.55 0.55 0.55 0.50 ,
A 3 = 0.50 0.60 0.60 0.35 0.40 0.50 0.25 0.75 0.40 0.75 0.50 0.50 0.65 0.25 0.50 0.50 and A ˜ 3 = 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.40 0.50 0.50 0.40 0.50 0.50 0.60 0.50 0.50 0.60 0.50 0.50 0.5 ,
Therefore, using (25)–(27) we can determine that
L C I ( R ¯ 1 ) = 0.94165 , L C I ( R ¯ 2 ) = 0.90835 and L C I ( R ¯ 3 ) = 0.89168 .
The consistency weights of the experts are, therefore, calculated using (28) as:
C w ( E 1 ) = 0.3435 , C w ( E 2 ) = 0.3313 , and C w ( E 3 ) = 0.3252
where q = 1 3 C w ( E q ) = 1 .
Step-iv: 
Expression (29) results in the final priority weights of the experts as:
w ( E 1 ) = 0.5114 , w ( E 2 ) = 0.2466 , and w ( E 3 ) = 0.2420
Step-v: 
The collective matrix R ¯ C against all experts is obtained by the use of (30)
R ¯ C = [ 0.5000 , 0.5000 ] [ 0.0242 , 0.7466 ] [ 0.2005 , 0.7995 ] [ 0.1023 , 0.7735 ] [ 0.2534 , 0.9758 ] [ 0.5000 , 0.5000 ] [ 0.1763 , 0.8000 ] [ 0.2288 , 0.9000 ] [ 0.2005 , 0.7995 ] [ 0.2000 , 0.8237 ] [ 0.5000 , 0.5000 ] [ 0.2781 , 0.8507 ] [ 0.2265 , 0.8977 ] [ 0.1000 , 0.7712 ] [ 0.1493 , 0.7219 ] [ 0.5000 , 0.5000 ] .
Step-vi: 
The average degree a v ¯ i , i = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 , of each alternative is derived by using the interval normalizing Formula (31)
a v ¯ 1 = [ 0.033164 , 1.083976 ] ; a v ¯ 2 = [ 0.066784 , 1.250432 ] ; a v ¯ 3 = [ 0.068823 , 1.156082 ] ; a v ¯ 4 = [ 0.048255 , 1.117248 ] .
Therefore, the possibility degree matrix D = ( d i j ) 4 × 4 is obtained by using (32):
D = ( d i j ) 4 × 4 = 0.5000 0.4552 0.4748 0.4886 0.5448 0.5000 0.5203 0.5337 0.5252 0.4797 0.5000 0.5138 0.5114 0.4663 0.4862 0.5000 .
Step-vii: 
Expression (33) gives the ranking value R v ( x i ) of alternative x i , 1 i 4 , as follows:
R v ( x 1 ) = 0.2364 ; R v ( x 2 ) = 0.2665 ; R v ( x 3 ) = 0.2531 ; R v ( x 4 ) = 0.2440 ,
where i = 1 4 R v ( x i ) = 1 . Thus, the final ranking of the alternatives is derived as follows:
x 2 > x 3 > x 4 > x 1 .
Thus, the best alternative is x 2 . The numerical illustration demonstrates the way in which the proposed technique for constructing a complete IVFPR based on L-consistency is implemented. In general, the proposed method is very straightforward to use when calculating uncertain preference values.

5. Comparison

Table 1 makes a comparison of the preference ranking of the alternatives of the proposed technique with the ones of Xu et al.’s method [11] under IIVFPRs and Zhang and Wang’s method [26] under complete IVFPRs.
From Table 1, we can observe that the preference order of the alternatives x 1 , x 2 , x 3 , x 4 , and x 5 obtained by the method of Xu et al. [11] is x 2 > x 4 > x 5 > x 3 > x 1 , while the proposed method results in x 5 > x 4 > x 2 > x 3 > x 1 . The positions of alternatives x 2 and x 5 have been interchanged while the order for others remained the same; this may be due to the inconsistency of complementary relation. Xu et al. [11] used additive transitivity, i.e., r i k = r i j + r j k 0.5 , for all i , j N to evaluate the final ranking. However, the complementary relation P = [ p i j ] constructed by Xu et al. as:
P = 0.5 0.217 0.389 0.284 0.311 0.783 0.5 0.685 0.572 0.581 0.611 0.315 0.5 0.387 0.409 0.716 0.428 0.613 0.5 0.514 0.689 0.419 0.591 0.486 0.5
is not additive consistent. For instance, if we take i = 1 and k = 2 , then the transitivity p 12 = p 1 j + p j 2 0.5 must be fulfilled for all j = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 , 5 , while from matrix P, we have: p 12 = 0.217 and p 13 + p 32 0.5 = 0.2024 , p 14 + p 42 0.5 = 0.212 , p 15 + p 52 0.5 = 0.23 . On the other hand, the possibility degree matrix D = [ d i j ] is given as follows:
D = 0.5000 0.1636 0.2099 0.0797 0.0145 0.8364 0.5000 0.5231 0.4446 0.3392 0.7901 0.4769 0.5000 0.4234 0.3259 0.9203 0.5554 0.5766 0.5000 0.3818 0.9855 0.6608 0.6741 0.6182 0.5000
based on L-consistency, i.e., r i k ( r i j + r j k 1 , 0 ) for all i j k N (for whole process). One can easily validate the L-consistency for all the preference values evaluated in D. We believe that the outcomes under consistent information are more reliable than others.
However, the preference order of alternatives x 1 , x 2 , x 3 , and x 4 in a practical example determined by the proposed method and Zhang and Wang’s method [26] are the same, i.e., x 3 > x 2 > x 1 > x 4 . Zhang and Wang [26] proposed a method to measure the proximity or compatibility between two interval numbers with values between 0 and 1. It uses a ratio-based compatibility degree and a compatibility measurement formula based on the geometric mean to evaluate the compatibility between two interval fuzzy preference relations. A procedure was developed to handle group decision-making problems with interval fuzzy preference relations.

6. Conclusions

This study develops a method for dealing with MPDM challenges when the data are provided in the form of IIVFPRs. The missing values have been estimated using the Lukasiewicz transitive property, and the information has been made completely consistent by applying the transitive closure procedure. The suggested method can be used with both complete and incomplete preference relations; in MPDM with complete IVFPRs, we just need to skip the stages that are needed to figure out the missing values. After adjusting the relevant consistency weights and predetermined weights, the priority weights for the experts were estimated. In order to be given more weight in the aggregation process, experts with high levels of consistency should logically be required to offer significant weights. The interval normalization technique was used to calculate the average priority level of each alternative compared to the others. After using possibility degrees to build the consistent, complementary fuzzy preference relation, the selection process started to rate each alternative and choose the best one. To demonstrate the effectiveness and viability of the suggested approach, some numerical examples were presented. Additionally, some comparisons with models proposed by Xu et al. [11] under IIVFPRs and Zhang and Wang [26] were presented. The outcomes proved the method’s viability and showed how, using the interval valued data, we may better understand the MPDM process. To sum up, the following are some of the main advantages of the suggested technique:
(1). When compared to existing consistency-based methods, the suggested method efficiently achieves the consistency of IVFPRs by estimating the missing preference values using Lukasiewicz’s transitivity; (2). Combining consistency weights and predetermined weights increased the reliability of expert weights, which were then used to quantify how consistently accurate the experts’ estimates were; (3). The suggested method is equally effective for preference relations that are both complete and incomplete; (4). When compared to other models [11], the suggested strategy produced substantially consistent preference relations.
However, there are a few limitations that require further study: (1). Because some aspects must be taken into account, MPDM may have too many criteria for the decision-making process, such as behavioral sciences, national discourse, risk level, etc. (2). When expressing their preferred comparisons, experts sometimes hesitate. It would be interesting to develop coping mechanisms for MPDM in the framework of type-2 interval fuzzy preference relations.
To the authors’ knowledge, there are not many approaches of this kind that have been suggested in the literature to address MPDM issues in the environment of IIVFPRs. This approach, in our opinion, deals with MPDM challenges more effectively.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, A.u.R.; Methodology, S.F.; Validation, X.Y., A.u.R., S.A. and M.H.; Formal analysis, X.Y., S.A., M.H. and S.F.; Investigation, A.u.R. and S.F.; Writing—original draft, A.u.R.; Supervision, S.A., M.H. and S.F.; Funding acquisition, X.Y. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by Natural Science Foundation of Sichuan, China (2023NSFSC0778) and Key Laboratory of Pattern Recognition and Intelligent Information Processing, Institutions of Higher Education of Sichuan Province (MSSB-2022-11).

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the editor and the anonymous reviewers, whose insightful comments and constructive suggestions helped us to improve the quality of this paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Chen, S.M.; Lin, T.E. A new method for group decision making using group recommendations based on interval fuzzy preference relations and consistency matrices. In Modern Advances in Applied Intelligence, Proceedings of the 27th International Conference on Industrial Engineering and Other Applications of Applied Intelligent Systems, IEA/AIE 2014, Kaohsiung, Taiwan, 3–6 June 2014; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2014; pp. 311–320. [Google Scholar]
  2. Pérez, I.J.; Cabrerizo, F.J.; Alonso, S.; Herrera-Viedma, E. A new consensus model for group decision making problems with non-homogeneous experts. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. Syst. 2013, 44, 494–498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Tanino, T. Fuzzy preference orderings in group decision making. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1984, 12, 117–131. [Google Scholar]
  4. Herrera, F.; Herrera-Viedma, E.; Chiclana, F. Multiperson decision-making based on multiplicative preference relations. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2001, 129, 372–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Tanino, T. Fuzzy preference relations in group decision making. In Non-Conventional Preference Relations in Decision Making; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1988; pp. 54–71. [Google Scholar]
  6. Herrera-Viedma, E.; Herrera, F.; Chiclana, F.; Luque, M. Some issues on consistency of fuzzy preference relations. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2004, 154, 98–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Venugopalan, P. Fuzzy ordered sets. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1992, 46, 221–226. [Google Scholar]
  8. Xu, Z.; Chen, J. Some models for deriving the priority weights from interval fuzzy preference relations. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2008, 184, 266–280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Chen, H.; Zhou, L. An approach to group decision making with interval fuzzy preference relations based on induced generalized continuous ordered weighted averaging operator. Expert Syst. Appl. 2011, 38, 13432–13440. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Liu, F.; Zhang, W.G.; Fu, J.H. A new method of obtaining the priority weights from an interval fuzzy preference relation. Inf. Sci. 2012, 185, 32–42. [Google Scholar]
  11. Xu, Y.; Li, K.W.; Wang, H. Incomplete interval fuzzy preference relations and their applications. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2014, 67, 93–103. [Google Scholar]
  12. Wang, Z.J.; Li, K.W. A multi-step goal programming approach for group decision making with incomplete interval additive reciprocal comparison matrices. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2015, 242, 890–900. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Wang, Z.J.; Li, K.W. Goal programming approaches to deriving interval weights based on interval fuzzy preference relations. Inf. Sci. 2012, 193, 180–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Wan, S.; Wang, F.; Dong, J. A group decision making method with interval valued fuzzy preference relations based on the geometric consistency. Inf. Fusion 2018, 40, 87–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Cheng, X.; Wan, S.; Dong, J. A new consistency definition of interval multiplicative preference relation. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 2021, 409, 55–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Wan, S.; Cheng, X.; Dong, J. Group decision-making with interval multiplicative preference relations. Knowl. Inf. Syst. 2023, 1–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Alonso, S.; Chiclana, F.; Herrera, F.; Herrera-Viedma, E.; Alcalá-Fdez, J.; Porcel, C. A consistency-based procedure to estimate missing pairwise preference values. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2008, 23, 155–175. [Google Scholar]
  18. Lee, L.W. Group decision making with incomplete fuzzy preference relations based on the additive consistency and the order consistency. Expert Syst. Appl. 2012, 39, 11666–11676. [Google Scholar]
  19. Xu, Z. On compatibility of interval fuzzy preference relations. Fuzzy Optim. Decis. Mak. 2004, 3, 217–225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Xu, Y.; Da, Q.; Wang, H. A note on group decision-making procedure based on incomplete reciprocal relations. Soft Comput. 2001, 15, 1289–1300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Wan, S.; Yuan, H.; Dong, J. Decision making with incomplete interval multiplicative preference relations based on stochastic program and interval category. Inf. Sci. 2021, 570, 403–427. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Xu, Y.; Patnayakuni, R.; Wang, H. Logarithmic least squares method to priority for group decision making with incomplete fuzzy preference relations. Appl. Math. Model. 2013, 37, 2139–2152. [Google Scholar]
  23. Cornelis, C.; Deschrijver, G.; Kerre, E.E. Implication in intuitionistic fuzzy and interval-valued fuzzy set theory: Construction, classification, application. Int. J. Approx. Reason. 2004, 35, 55–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Moore, R.E. Methods and Applications of Interval Analysis; Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics: Philadelphia, PA, USA, 1979. [Google Scholar]
  25. Klement, E.P.; Mesiar, R.; Pap, E. Triangular Norms; Kluwer Academic Publishers: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  26. Zhang, X.Y.; Wang, Z.J. Compatibility measurement-based group decision making with interval fuzzy preference relations. J. Algorithms Comput. Technol. 2017, 11, 31–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Table 1. Comparison of ranking of the alternatives.
Table 1. Comparison of ranking of the alternatives.
MethodsRanking Values/ScoresPreference Order
Xu et al.’s method [11] ω 1     ω 2     ω 3     ω 4     ω 5
0.136   0.250   0.178   0.222   0.215x2 > x4 > x5 > x3 > x1
The proposed method R ( x 1 )       R ( x 2 )       R ( x 3 )       R ( x 4 )       R ( x 5 )
0.0468  0.2143  0.2016  0.2434  0.2939x5 > x4 > x2 > x3 > x1
Zhang and Wang’s method [26]Ranking values are calculated in compatible modex3 > x2 > x1 > x4
The proposed method R ( x 1 )       R ( x 2 )      R ( x 3 )       R ( x 4 )
0.2054  0.2280  0.4321  0.1345x3 > x2 > x1 > x4
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Yu, X.; Rehman, A.u.; Ashraf, S.; Hussain, M.; Faizi, S. Multiperson Decision-Making Using Consistent Interval-Valued Fuzzy Information with Application in Supplier Selection. Mathematics 2023, 11, 879. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11040879

AMA Style

Yu X, Rehman Au, Ashraf S, Hussain M, Faizi S. Multiperson Decision-Making Using Consistent Interval-Valued Fuzzy Information with Application in Supplier Selection. Mathematics. 2023; 11(4):879. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11040879

Chicago/Turabian Style

Yu, Xiaodong, Atiq ur Rehman, Samina Ashraf, Muhammad Hussain, and Shahzad Faizi. 2023. "Multiperson Decision-Making Using Consistent Interval-Valued Fuzzy Information with Application in Supplier Selection" Mathematics 11, no. 4: 879. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11040879

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop