1. Introduction
To accelerate China’s economic transformation and upgrading and to realize sustainable development, during the 75th session of the United Nations General Assembly (UNGA) on 22 September 2020, the Chinese government proposed the “dual carbon” target, which entails reaching the peak of carbon dioxide emissions before 2030 and attaining carbon neutrality before 2060. To achieve these goals, the Chinese government has constructed a “1 + N” policy framework. The “1” in “1 + N” refers to the top-level design of the “dual carbon” target, namely, the Working Guidance for Carbon Dioxide Peaking and Carbon Neutrality in Full and Faithful Implementation of the New Development Philosophy (hereinafter called Working Guidance). The “N” in “1 + N” refers to the Action Plan for Carbon Dioxide Peaking Before 2030 (hereinafter called Action Plan) and the policy measures in key sectors and regions. Both core documents have explicitly stated that green finance should be used to help achieve the “dual carbon” target.
China was late to engage in green finance, but it has developed quickly in recent years. In 2015, the
Integrated Reform Plan for Promoting Ecological Progress first proposed the overall goal of establishing a green financial system. In 2016, the
Guidelines for Establishing the Green Financial System (hereafter called
Guidelines) was jointly issued by the People’s Bank of China and seven other departments, establishing the top-level framework for the green financial system. China is the first country to build a green financial system under the full leadership of the central government. In 2017, “pilot zones for green finance reform and innovations” were approved by the State Council to be set up in several areas in seven provinces, and China began to explore a “bottom-up” approach to green finance development. In October 2021, according to the requirements of the
Working Guidance and
Action Plan, the People’s Bank of China listed “implementing the major deployment of the ‘dual carbon’ target and improving the green finance field’s incentive mechanism and policy framework” as key tasks and established policy thinking for the growth of green finance, namely, the “three functions” and “five pillars” [
1]. By the end of 2022, China’s green loans balance was CNY 22.03 trillion, up 38.5% from the previous year, ranking top in the world in regard to the stock scale. A total of 66.7% of these green loans have been invested in projects with direct and indirect carbon reduction benefits, CNY 8.62 trillion and CNY 6.08 trillion, respectively [
2]. In 2022, China’s green bond issuance at home and abroad increased by CNY 983.899 billion, and the stock scale reached approximately CNY 3 trillion. In addition, green financial products and markets, green funds, green insurance, green PE/VC, and ESG investments have also made great progress [
3]. In a relatively short period, a rather complete green financial system has been constructed in China, which has laid a solid foundation for green financial product innovation and green financial market development.
Green finance, as a type of “sustainable finance” [
4], has developed rapidly under the background of a “dual-carbon” target. A growing number of scholars have paid attention to the economic effects of green finance. Previous studies have explored the effect of green finance development on green economic transformation and the economy’s sustainable growth, mainly from the perspectives of green innovation [
5,
6,
7,
8], environmental investments [
9], and corporate social and environmental responsibility [
10,
11]. In addition, other studies have examined how green finance affects investments and financing [
12,
13], financialization [
14], and banks’ cost-effectiveness [
15].
In recent years, China has entered an important period of economic structural transformation. Some industries have emerged with prominent contradictions between supply and demand. The overcapacity problem is becoming more pronounced. On 18 October 2013, the
Guidelines for Resolving Serious Contradictions in Overcapacity issued by the State Council stated that not resolving the overcapacity problem in a timely and appropriate manner means that industry losses and enterprise employee unemployment will expand, bank nonperforming assets will increase, energy resource constraints will be exacerbated, the ecological environment will deteriorate, and so on, causing a shackle that hinders the economy’s sustainable development. Overcapacity prevails in China’s traditional manufacturing industry, especially in energy-intensive and highly polluting industries, which include steel, coal, cement, plate glass, and so on [
16,
17,
18]. Green finance policies drive polluting enterprises’ technological innovation, inhibit overinvestments of polluting enterprises by optimizing credit resource allocations, and provide advantages for the effective management of overcapacity in polluting enterprises. Accordingly, exploring how green finance policies affect capacity utilization rate can not only effectively expand the comprehension of green finance policies’ microeconomic effects but also provide a reference for the upgrading of traditional capacity and the green transformation of polluting enterprises.
China’s overcapacity phenomenon is mainly explained from two aspects: market failure and governmental intervention. The “wave phenomenon” is the most important viewpoint from the perspective of market failure; that is, enterprises in developing countries can easily reach a consensus on promising industries for the future; however, incomplete information can lead to overinvestments in promising industries [
19]. Based on this viewpoint, some scholars conducted further analyses and found that improving enterprise informatization and promoting enterprise digital transformation can effectively reduce information incompleteness and alleviate overcapacity [
20,
21]. Similarly, Banerjee argues that incomplete information can lead to misjudgments of the external environment and trigger herding among enterprises, which can lead to overcapacity [
22]. Research from the perspective of governmental intervention suggests that the main causes of overcapacity include governmental intervention policies favoring large enterprises, key enterprises, and new strategic industries [
23,
24], excessive preferential policies implemented by local governments under political tournaments [
25,
26], and similarities among local leading industries [
27].
The primary function of green finance is to promote economic transformation by optimizing the allocation of financial resources; essentially, it is an environmental regulation [
6]. Therefore, the literature on how environmental regulation affects capacity utilization rate is also highly related to this paper. According to Han, environmental regulation resolves overcapacity mainly through the elimination of capacity that does not meet environmental standards, while the role of the technological innovation channel is limited [
28]. Du has a similar view, arguing that environmental regulation can improve backward production capacity by increasing investments in cleaning equipment for state-owned enterprises, and it can also increase production costs for enterprises, thereby eliminating backward production capacity [
29]. Other studies have explored the effect of environmental taxes on capacity utilization rate. Han and Wang find that an increase in environmental protection taxes can enhance the manufacturing capacity utilization rate [
30]. Yu et al. argue that reforming the environmental protection fee to a tax in China effectively increased enterprises’ capacity utilization rate [
31]. However, Domicián Máté et al. found that the impact of taxation is more fiscal than an incentive, arguing that increased environmental taxes do not reduce carbon emissions and denying the role of environmental taxes in green growth, such as improving capacity utilization rate [
32]. Although related studies have been relatively abundant, little is known about the policy effects of green finance policies on the capacity utilization rate, and this paper extended the research on the impact of environmental regulation on the capacity utilization rate. We use the promulgation of
Guidelines in 2016 as a quasinatural experiment and the difference-in-differences (DID) to study the effects and mechanisms of green finance policies on polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate. The results demonstrate that green finance policies greatly increase the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises, mainly by optimizing the allocation of financial resources and promoting technological innovation. Moreover, green finance policies have a greater effect on the capacity utilization rate of state-owned and large-scale polluting enterprises.
This paper includes the following contributions. Firstly, by studying the microeconomic effects of green financial policies from the new perspective of the capacity utilization rate, we expand the research on the economic effects of green finance policies and the effect of environmental regulations on the capacity utilization rate. We also provide decision support for optimizing the production capacity structure and accelerating the sustainable development process. Secondly, we explore the mechanisms by which green finance policies affect the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises from both empirical and theoretical perspectives. We identify and test the mechanisms of credit resource allocation and technological innovation to provide a basis for better utilizing financial tools and environmental regulation policies to address overcapacity. Thirdly, from the aspects of enterprise ownership and scale, we explore the heterogeneity of green financial policies that affect polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate to assist in accurately solving their overcapacity problems.
The remaining parts of this paper are as follows:
Section 2 analyzes the impact mechanism of green finance policies on polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate and proposes the relevant research hypotheses;
Section 3 introduces the models and variables of the empirical study;
Section 4 reports the results of the empirical study;
Section 5 conducts the test of the influence mechanism and heterogeneity analysis;
Section 6 concludes and makes recommendations.
2. Theoretical Analysis and Research Hypotheses
The ratio of actual output to potential capacity (or desirable capacity) is known as the capacity utilization rate. When the actual output of an enterprise is below its potential capacity (or desirable capacity), then it has overcapacity problems [
17,
33]. The overcapacity problem is essentially caused by an unbalanced supply and demand in the market and needs to be investigated from both the supply and demand sides. On the supply side, market failure and undue governmental interventions can trigger excessive investments by enterprises and make their supply capacity exceed the actual market demand, thus leading to overcapacity [
19,
23,
24]. From the demand side, insufficient enterprise innovation results in product homogenization, low value added, and low product competitiveness, which means that market demand cannot be met, thus inducing overcapacity. Therefore, to improve enterprises’ capacity utilization rates, on the one hand, correcting market failures, restraining government intervention, and inhibiting enterprise overinvestments are necessary. On the other hand, improving enterprise technological innovation to better meet market demand is necessary. Most overcapacity industries in China are polluting industries, and studies have shown that environmental regulation policies can greatly improve the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises [
28,
30,
31]. Implementation of green finance policy, which is a special environmental pollution regulation measure, changes the investment and technological innovation behavior of polluting enterprises, thereby greatly affecting the capacity utilization rate.
First, green financial policies can inhibit overinvestments in polluting enterprises and enhance their capacity utilization rate through the credit resource allocation mechanism. As an instrument for policy that promotes the green transformation of the economy, the main function of green finance policies is to prioritize the allocation of credit resources to green and nonpolluting enterprises. The implementation of green finance policies signals green development to the market, providing enterprises and investors with more complete information and, thus, avoiding the “wave phenomena” of investments in polluting industries. In addition, it can improve the level of enterprise environmental information disclosure, thereby hindering polluting enterprises’ greenwashing behavior to mislead investors, weakening their external financing ability, and inhibiting their overinvestments [
34]. On the other hand, in the context of fiscal decentralization and political tournaments, local governments often have a significant incentive to influence enterprise investments to meet the needs of political performance evaluations, local fiscal revenue growth, and the promotion of employment. Local governments allocate substantial credit funds to polluting and inefficient enterprises so they can keep expanding their production and investments, which, in turn, leads to an overcapacity problem [
26,
35]. The
Guidelines put forward several measures. First, the statistical system of green credit is to be improved, and green credit is to be incorporated into the macroprudential assessment framework to establish an effective incentive and restraint mechanism. Second, gradually setting up a green assessment mechanism for banks is proper to allow for the evaluation of the performance of banks’ green financial businesses. Third, lenders’ environmental legal responsibilities should be clarified to enable laws and regulations to constrain their actions. The implementation of these measures forces banks to raise the credit threshold, making enterprises’ (especially polluting enterprises) environmental compliance an important basis for lending to produce strong constraints on local governments’ excessive intervention motives [
12]. In short, green finance policies can improve polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate by inhibiting overinvestments in polluting enterprises, which is achieved by alleviating market failures and constraining excessive government interventions.
Second, green financial policies can stimulate polluting enterprises to increase investments in technological innovation and the capacity utilization rate. In new classical economics, the belief is that environmental regulations make enterprise production produce “costs following”, which means that environmental regulation policies cause polluting enterprises to purchase or upgrade pollution control equipment, pay more pollution control fees, increase their production costs, and reduce their profits and the scale of production investments [
36]. Green finance policy, as a special environmental regulation policy, also increases the financing and production costs of polluting enterprises to reduce the inefficient backward production capacity and raise the enterprise capacity utilization rate. On the other hand, environmental regulations may also produce “innovation compensation”. According to the Porter hypothesis, appropriate environmental regulations can force technological innovation in enterprises and improve their degree of technological innovation and production efficiency [
37]. In the long run, green financial policies raise the financing threshold and cost of polluting enterprises, forcing them to increase investments in technological innovation and achieve “innovation compensation” by improving production technology [
8]. Polluting enterprises can improve the capacity utilization rate through technological innovation. Technological innovation not only reduces polluting enterprises’ production costs and product prices to stimulate market demand but also improves the quality and differentiation of their products to better meet market demand [
38,
39]. In other words, green financial policies increase polluting enterprises’ production costs, eliminate backward production capacity, force polluting enterprises to increase investments in technological innovation, and ultimately improve their capacity utilization rate. The following research hypotheses are put forth:
Hypothesis 1. Green finance policies have a significant positive effect on the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises.
Hypothesis 2. Green finance policies improve the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises by restricting their allocation of credit resources.
Hypothesis 3. Green finance policies improve the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises by stimulating their technological innovation.
The effect of green finance policies on the enterprise capacity utilization rate varies significantly amongst enterprises with different ownership properties. On the one hand, unlike nonstate-owned enterprises (non-SOEs), state-owned enterprises (SOEs) are not only responsible for the main task of promoting national economic development but also shoulder social responsibilities such as scientific and technological progress, improving people’s livelihoods and environmental protection [
40]. Moreover, SOEs are often characterized by their large scale of business and assets and, thus, naturally have the advantage of serving the national strategy [
41]. Green finance policies often make state-owned polluting enterprises consciously take on greater responsibility for promoting green transformation and the development of production methods. By reducing production capacity and output, state-owned enterprises can reduce pollutant emissions, thereby significantly improving their capacity utilization rate. On the other hand, due to the closer political connection between SOEs and local governments, bank loans and preferential policies have a higher probability of being granted to SOEs, possibly leading to overcapacity [
42]. Green finance policies strictly limit banks’ lending to polluting enterprises (including state-owned polluting enterprises) by imposing strict green monitoring and performance evaluations. Accordingly, compared with nonstate-owned polluting enterprises, state-owned polluting enterprises’ financing behavior is more significantly impacted by the green finance policies, which also has a stronger inhibiting effect on their overinvestment behavior. Based on this point, we propose the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 4. Green finance policies have a greater effect on the capacity utilization rate of state-owned polluting enterprises than of nonstate-owned polluting enterprises.
The impact of green finance policies on enterprises’ capacity utilization rate is significantly different among enterprises of different scales. Large-scale polluting enterprises typically have better and more assets than those of small-scale polluting enterprises, which facilitates their ability to obtain bank mortgages. The implementation of green finance policies not only raises the financing threshold and costs faced by large-scale polluting enterprises; these enterprises also must face more stringent environmental protection controls, thus strictly restricting their capacity expansion. In addition, according to the Schumpeterian hypothesis, enterprises’ scale is positively correlated with technological innovation efficiency, and large-scale enterprises usually have more advantages in technological innovation [
43]. Therefore, green financial policies can provide stronger incentives for the technological innovation of large-scale polluting enterprises and, thus, increase the capacity utilization rate more substantially. Based on this point, we propose the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 5. Green finance policies have a greater effect on the capacity utilization rate in large-scale polluting enterprises than in small-scale polluting enterprises.
6. Conclusions and Suggestions
Green financial policies, as an important means for advancing China’s production method transition to a low-carbon, green economy, may help resolve overcapacity and, thus, promote the formation of a sustainable capacity structure and economic structure. The main purpose of this paper is to investigate the impact of green financial policies on polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rates, which provides a new perspective for studying the microeconomic effects of green financial policies and resolving the overcapacity in enterprises. We use the promulgation of the Guidelines in 2016 as a quasinatural experiment and employ the DID, a powerful tool for policy assessment, to examine the effect of green finance policies on polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate based on data of Chinese A-share listed companies on the SSE and SZSE from 2012 to 2020.
The empirical results verify the five hypotheses proposed in this paper; the following conclusions were drawn:
- (a)
Green financial policies can significantly increase the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises, which is supported by a series of robustness tests such as the parallel trend test;
- (b)
The test of the influence mechanism shows that green finance policies increase the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises through credit resource allocation mechanisms and technological innovation mechanisms;
- (c)
Heterogeneity analysis shows that green finance policies have a greater effect on the capacity utilization rate in state-owned and large-scale polluting enterprises.
Thus, we put up the following suggestions in conjunction with the previously stated conclusions.
First, the results show that the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises is significantly improved by the green finance policies. This conclusion provides a new idea and tool for China to further solve overcapacity. China’s green finance has developed rapidly but started relatively late. Currently, China still faces issues such as incomplete policy frameworks and inadequate incentive and constraint mechanisms. Therefore, the policy system should be further improved to protect the long-term development of green finance. Moreover, the clearance of overcapacity industries through green finance should be accelerated, supply-side reforms should be deepened, and policy and financial assistance for the sustainable development of the economy should be offered.
Second, we found that green financial policies increase the capacity utilization rate of polluting enterprises through the credit resource allocation mechanism. Therefore, relevant management departments should adopt measures to further strengthen the credit resource allocation role of green financial policies. First, financial institutions’ participation in green financial businesses should be increased. Only when financial institutions actively participate in green finance businesses can the financing “threshold” of polluting enterprises be truly raised. Improving relevant laws and regulations, clarifying the system of “exemption if due diligence” for financial institutions and environmental protection legal responsibilities, and strongly constraining the behavior of financial institutions are necessary. Also necessary is establishing and improving business statistical monitoring, assessing the evaluation system of green finance, and incentivizing financial institutions to actively participate by establishing corresponding reward systems. Furthermore, a green financial information disclosure system should be formulated as soon as possible to alleviate asymmetric information and improve the accuracy of financial institutions’ green financial business.
Third, the results show that green financial policies improve polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate by incentivizing technological innovation. Therefore, relevant management departments should adopt measures to further strengthen the role of green finance policies in stimulating technological innovation. Financial institutions should be inspired to provide “green funds” for the technological innovation and green transformation of polluting enterprises. Moreover, preferential taxation, subsidies for innovation, and risk insurance should be provided by the government to polluting enterprises engaged in technological innovation to stimulate their subjective initiative of technological innovation and improve product quality and product differentiation. By expanding high-quality incremental supply, we can better meet market demand.
Fourth, the heterogeneity analysis shows that green finance policies have a greater effect on state-owned and large-scale polluting enterprises. Based on this, we should formulate differentiated green finance policies and implement constraint and incentive policies for state-owned and large-scale polluting enterprises. Since nonstate-owned and small-scale polluting enterprises have relatively limited access to financing, they should be subject to a policy that focuses on incentives for innovation.
The limitations of this research are as follows: First, since the samples in this paper are limited to listed companies, it cannot reflect the impact of green finance policies on non-listed companies’ capacity utilization rate. Second, this paper solely focuses on the impact of green finance policies on polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate without exploring the impact of different types of green finance policies on polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate. Policies such as green credit and green bonds may have completely different impacts on polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate.
In the future, the research on this issue can be further developed from the following aspects: First, by collecting data from non-listed companies through questionnaires and other means, we can examine the impact of green finance policies on non-listed companies’ capacity utilization rate. Second, we can explore the mechanisms and effects of different types of green finance policies on polluting enterprises’ capacity utilization rate.