Next Article in Journal
An Agent-Based Modeling Framework for Simulating Human Exposure to Environmental Stresses in Urban Areas
Previous Article in Journal
A Framework for Understanding Sense of Place in an Urban Design Context
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Joint Costs in Electricity and Natural Gas Distribution Infrastructures: The Role of Urban Factors

1
Department of City and Regional Planning, Middle East Technical University, 06800 Ankara, Turkey
2
City and Regional Section, Knowlton School of Architecture, The Ohio State University, Columbus, OH 43210, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Urban Sci. 2018, 2(2), 35; https://doi.org/10.3390/urbansci2020035
Submission received: 23 February 2018 / Revised: 7 April 2018 / Accepted: 13 April 2018 / Published: 16 April 2018

Abstract

:
This paper analyzes the joint cost structure of electricity and natural gas distribution investments. Assessing the joint costs is critical for urban development and public policy regarding competition at the local level. The paper accounts for the urban and geographic factors at the local level, while the previous literature primarily used company-level data with a few or no site-specific variables in joint cost analyses. An empirical analysis of the multi-utility capital costs suggests that the local urban and geographic conditions affect such costs, with economies of scope present in electricity and natural gas both in terms of total costs and underground investment costs. Hence, the joint service provision makes economic and environmental sense for urban policy makers.

1. Introduction

The urban energy distribution infrastructure, which is composed of electricity and natural gas networks, is essential for sustaining daily life and economic activities. Energy infrastructure investments are expensive and often difficult to reverse, because it is costly to modify these systems once completed. Thus, understanding the cost structure of these systems is critical to make them sustainable and provide economical, safe and reliable energy to consumers. These costs can be expected to be related to the urban characteristics of the served areas and it is reasonable to consider such factors in cost analysis.
The urban utility companies provide either a single product (electricity, natural gas or water) or multiple products in different combinations. It is expected that there is an economic incentive for providing joint products in multi-product utilities, such as benefits and savings from sharing infrastructure and labor. These benefits are often termed as economies of scope and their analysis requires the definition and estimation of a utility cost model, with utility outputs, such as sales and numbers of customers, and input prices used as determinants. A few studies have examined the economics of multi-product utilities and utilized all data at the aggregate, company level [1,2]. However, it is very likely that the site-specific urban and geographic conditions have an impact on capital infrastructure costs, which are often neglected in the literature. The only factor that has been taken into account is density [2,3]. Some sites may be more suitable to joint provision due to soil conditions, topography and urban pattern, while other sites may present obstacles to the machinery operations needed for joint provision, such as excavation and filling. Another measure of the economic structure of utilities is the economies of scale, which are associated with the average costs declining with outputs. They are also critical for determining public policy in terms of competition at the local level and for understanding whether there are local urban and geographic conditions leading to diseconomies of scale.
The purpose of this study is to investigate the impact of local geographical factors on joint costs in multi-product utilities, making use of the detailed data on distribution investment costs for several gas and electric utilities in the state of New York. The total and underground capital investment costs are modeled separately, while the joint cost and economies of scale analyses are conducted. The basic spatial unit of observation is either a city, village or town. These data are used to estimate the distribution cost models with incorporation of sales, number of customers, input prices and local geographic and urban variables.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Relevant literature is reviewed in Section 2. The cost modeling approach is outlined in Section 3. The study area and data are described in Section 4. The empirical results and their implications are discussed in Section 5. Section 6 concludes the paper.

2. Literature Review

A few studies have investigated whether it is more economical to provide electricity, gas and water separately or jointly. There has been some evidence for joint cost savings, although this often depends on firm size. All studies use the distribution costs as the dependent variable. Various functional forms, such as the quadratic and translog forms, are used in the model estimations. The areas where the data have been collected and the related sample sizes are presented in Table 1. All studies use output and price variables, while only two studies consider density [2,3]. Mayo used a quadratic cost function to analyze the costs of providing electricity only; natural gas only; and combined electricity and natural gas [1]. This study highlighted the savings at lower outputs and losses at higher outputs due to the absence of competition.
Chapell et al. extended the findings of Mayo by adding a technology variable to characterize electricity firms using fossil fuels and nuclear power [1,4]. The results are similar and suggest that joint cost savings are related to both technology and firm size. Fraquelli et al. and Piacenza and Vannoni used the same Italian data to analyze utilities with various combinations of gas, water and electricity services [5,6]. Cost is taken as a function of the amounts of gas, electricity and water delivered as well as the prices of labor and other inputs. The comparison of four cost models (standard translog, generalized translog, quadratic and composite) showed that the composite model with output and price interactions was most suitable in both studies. The largest savings were obtained from gas–water combinations in small firms. Small to medium firms enjoy global and product-specific economies of both scale and scope, suggesting that small firms should be multi-utilities in order to reduce their costs.
Farsi et al. analyzed the Swiss utilities providing various combinations of gas, electricity and water using a quadratic cost function [2]. In addition to electricity, gas and water outputs and input prices, the customer density was introduced into their model. Customer density was found to be statistically significant, with the expected negative sign. The results provide evidence that the smaller utilities benefit most from joint cost savings. However, by analyzing a combination of gas and electric utilities, Sing obtained contradictory results as they discovered losses for the average combination firm [3].
Literature has considered different combinations of other utilities. Water and sewerage systems have been historically characterized by both monopoly and competition. Some studies have highlighted the economic benefits of vertical and/or horizontal integration, while other studies argued that separation is more efficient, particularly for large firms. With few exceptions, the geographic and environmental variables have been overlooked. Kim and Clark observed cost savings for joint residential and non-residential water services [7]. Fraquelli and Giandrone found savings that resulted from the vertical integration of wastewater treatment plants [8]. Some studies suggest that joint cost savings depend on firm size. Hayes and Martins et al. observed such savings for small firms, but not for the large ones [9,10]. Similarly, Garcia et al. discovered economic efficiencies from vertical integration only for small firms [11]. By focusing on the cost structure of water and sewerage systems, Saal and Parker reached a different conclusion: costs remain the same, whether water and sewerage systems are separate or joint [12]. In contrast, Bottasso et al. found diseconomies in water and sewerage combinations, leading them to suggest that the two services should be separated [13].
Joint costs have also been analyzed in transportation systems. Viton found that the provision of different transportation modes is more cost effective for small companies than for larger ones [14]. Farsi et al. estimated the cost of Swiss urban public transportation with three outputs: trolley-bus, motor-bus and tramway [15]. They observed savings at all levels of output combinations. In contrast, Walter found diseconomies in German transportation systems, concluding that there should be competition rather than consolidation of services [16]. Di Giacomo and Ottoz and Ottoz and Di Giacomo analyzed the urban and intercity bus systems, concluding that cost savings are sensitive to model specification [17,18].
In summary, both joint cost savings and losses have been observed in previous studies, with results highly dependent on the selected functional form and the data. Several studies suggest that the savings decrease with increasing firm size. This implies that small firms should consolidate, while service unbundling may be the better strategy for very large firms. Very few studies have taken geographical and environmental factors into account.

3. Methodology

The cost modeling approach is rooted in the microeconomic theory of the firm. The multi-utility firm considered here provides the two outputs of electricity and natural gas, which makes up the output vector Q. This output vector may be further disaggregated into sales and numbers of customers of electricity and natural gas in different sectors, such as residential, commercial, industrial, public authorities and street lighting. A transformation function summarizes all the feasible substitutions between the inputs and outputs. The inputs include labor (L), capital (K), and energy (E), which represents energy losses. Energy losses are an unavoidable feature of energy distribution systems, but they can be controlled by technological and capital investment choices to some extent. For instance, electricity losses are due to the resistance encountered by the electrons flowing along conductor lines and can be reduced by increasing the voltage of some lines at the cost of additional safety measures. Likewise, gas losses can take place along older gas pipes that may have leaks. In order to reduce these gas losses, new gas lines may be installed, which can sometimes occur by inserting the plastic pipes within the older pipes. The unit costs of these losses are the unit price of electricity as purchased from the electricity generating plant and the unit price of the gas purchased from interstate gas transmission companies. If these prices are higher, there is a subsequent stronger incentive to reduce the losses, hence leading to the trade-off between K and E. A vector of urban-specific variables (ST), such as street network, housing stock characteristics and soil characteristics, is also part of the final function, with:
F ( Q , L , K , E , S T ) = 0 .
Let PK, PL and PE be the prices of capital, labor and energy. The firm is assumed to minimize its input costs subject to providing all the customers in its service territory as represented by the output Q, with:
min C = PK K + PL L + PE E,
subject to the production constraint represented by Equation (1). Let K*, L*, E* be the optimal input values. The total cost function derived from the above cost minimization has the general form:
C ( Q ,   P , S T ) = P K K * + P L L * + P E E * ,
where P = (PK, PL, PE). The focus in this research is on the capital cost component, CK, with:
C K = P K K * = f K ( Q , P K , P L , P E , S T ) .
Although the multi-utility firm also incurs labor and fuel purchase costs, the capital costs are the only costs with data available at the local urban level, which is the reason for the focus on these costs in this present study. After this, the input prices computed with data aggregated for the whole firm are uniformly applied to all the localities served by the firm.
There is no agreed-upon functional form for the capital cost function. Therefore, both log-log and Box-Cox regressions are considered. The former implies the logarithmic transformations of both the dependent and independent variables, while the latter implies more flexibility with the consideration of a whole range of forms through the endogenous determination of the Box-Cox transformation parameters. When these parameters are equal to one, the transformation is equivalent to the linear model. When they are equal to zero, it is equivalent to the log-log model.
The Box-Cox regression is defined as:
y ( θ ) = α 0 + α 1 x 1 ( λ ) + α 2 x 2 ( λ ) + + α m x m ( λ ) + γ 1 z 1 + + γ l z l + ϵ ,
where the variables y ( θ ) and x m ( λ ) are defined by the transformations:
y ( θ ) = ( Y θ 1 ) / θ   and   x m ( λ ) = ( X m λ 1 ) / λ .
The variables Y and X represent the original dependent and independent variables in each observation, while y and x are the Box-Cox transformed versions of the original variables. The variables z 1 z l are not Box-Cox transformed, because the transformation is either not necessary or not possible as in the case of 0–1 dummy variables. In this study, all the variables are transformed.
Once estimated, the cost function may be used to assess the extent of the economies of scale. The cost elasticity with regard to the output Qi (εQi) measures the percent change in the cost (CK) with regard to a percent change in Qi and is calculated as follows:
ε Q i = ( C K / Q i ) ( Q i / C K ) .
The economies of scale in the multi-utility firm ( ε R ) are measured as the sum of the cost elasticities for the different outputs under the assumption of the same rate of expansion for all outputs. In the case of two outputs, we can obtain the following:
ε R = i = 1 2 ε Q i .
Joint cost savings take place if the outputs (Q1, Q2) are more cheaply provided together as compared to the costs of providing them separately through two distinct firms, which holds if:
C ( Q 1 , Q 2 , P K , P L , P E , S T ) < C ( 0 , Q 2 , P K , P L , P E , S T ) + C ( Q 1 , 0 , P K , P L , P E , S T ) .
The extent of joint cost savings may be measured by the following ratio:
S C = [ C ( 0 , Q 2 , P K , P L , P E , S T ) + C ( Q 1 , P K , P L , P E , S T , 0 ) ] C ( Q 1 , Q 2 , P K , P L , P E , S T ) C ( Q 1 , Q 2 , P K , P L , P E , S T ) .
Positive values of S C imply joint cost savings and negative values imply losses.

4. Data and Study Area

4.1. Data Sources

There are three categories of data used: company, census of population and geographic features. These are all available at the tax district level, which can be cities, villages or towns. The data of four electricity and natural gas companies (Central Hudson Gas and Electric Company, Long Island Lighting Company, Niagara Mohawk Power Company, and Orange and Rockland Companies) serving customers in the state of New York (NYS) in 1980 include sales, number of customers, distribution plant investment as well as capital labor and fuel prices. The data for 1980 were deemed acceptable because the distribution technologies have not so far changed significantly in contrast to telecommunications. The American Society of Civil Engineers (ASCE) indicated that the U.S. energy grid, which is composed of electricity and natural gas systems, has been aging considerably, with some areas still using components dating back to the 1880s [19]. This may change in the future if the electricity grid is entirely converted to a smart grid. However, this is not the case for now and the most significant recent change in some areas has been the replacement of electric meters with advanced metering infrastructure (AMI). However, the electric meters constitute a small share of distribution costs (e.g., only 4% in this study). Moreover, AMI has been implemented in less than 25% of the U.S. and the conversion in NYS has been even more limited, which has been estimated to be around 5% [20]. In any case, the metering equipment is a very small component of the total electric distribution plant. Electricity systems continue to operate with traditional system components (conductors, poles, transformers, etc.). The major changes in the electricity sector have been the relatively recent introduction of new generation technologies: dual gas turbines, wind generators and solar power plants. These technologies do not affect the layout of electricity distribution systems. However, changes could take place in the future if the whole system shifts from centralized power generation to distributed power generation, in which each end-user becomes capable of generating and trading electricity. However, such comprehensive changes will require much time and resources and are unlikely in the short- and medium-term. Innovations have been even more limited in natural distribution, which continues to operate with the same system components (pipes, services, pressure regulators, compressors and short-term gas holders) as in the past. Apart from petroleum gas containers distributed by trucks to isolated rural customers, pipelines will remain the only way to carry significant amounts of gas to residential, commercial and industrial end users in urban areas. In addition, it should be noted that most of the data that were available in 1980 are no longer available today due to competition and confidentiality concerns.
The census of Population and geographical data are available for the whole State of New York. The population and housing data for 1980 are used, which is consistent with the timeline of company data. The geographic data include land-use, soil, slope and street variables, which are all organized within Geographical Information Systems (GIS). The street map database is drawn from the Environmental Systems Research Institute (ESRI). Soil data are derived from the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s State Soil Geographic (STATSGO) database. After considering various combinations of variables, the best fitted capital investment cost model includes the share of old housing units as the socio-economic variable, while the number of street intersections and soil steel corrosivity is assigned as the geographical variable. The street and soil maps are presented in the Appendix A.
Among all the possible data, this paper will use joint distribution costs, annual electricity and natural gas sales, electricity and natural gas prices, the number of street intersections, the share of old houses and the steel corrosivity of the soil. The cost refers to the replacement cost of the whole capital stock. All the data are cross-sectional. Soil is a time-independent variable. The cross-sections are made of 246 tax districts for the total capital investment cost and 234 tax districts for the underground capital investment cost.

4.2. Overview of the Study Area

The basic spatial unit of analysis is the tax district, which can be a city, a village or a town. The company data are available for 246 tax districts out of the 1619 tax districts in NYS. Although only 15% of the tax districts are included, the data cover most of the highly populated areas in the State, except New York City. It is important to note that not all tax districts have data on both electricity and gas, which is illustrated in Figure 1.
There are 60 districts where electricity is served by one company and 186 where electricity and gas are jointly served. Out of the 246 tax districts, 25 are served by Central Hudson, 112 by Long Island Lighting, 56 by Niagara Mohawk and 53 by Orange and Rockland.
The detailed company historical plant (i.e., investment) data by vintage year (i.e., the year that a specific piece of equipment, such as a gas pipe, was installed for use in the company’s system) and tax districts were provided by the New York State Division of Equalization and Assessment (NYSDEA). These vintage data were weighted by the Handy-Whitman index, which is a commonly used index in the utility industry [21]. After this, these data were summed up into replacement plant values, which represents the cost of capital considered here. All natural gas plant investments are underground. However, this is not the case for electricity as it can be delivered through overhead or underground conductors. Underground investment is expected to be costlier due to excavation and filling. Therefore, not all districts prefer (or have) to invest in underground electricity lines. As a result, the tax district sample is smaller regarding underground investments. There are 48 districts with the underground system providing only electricity. The 186 tax districts providing both electricity and gas have both underground systems. The 234 tax districts with underground systems include 20 served by Central Hudson, 111 by Long Island Lighting, 54 by Niagara Mohawk and 49 by Orange and Rockland.

5. Results

5.1. Investment Cost Model

After extensive exploratory analyses accounting for multicollinearity, statistical significance and overall model performance (R2, log-likelihood), the following model was selected:
C = F(STE, STG, FUELE, FUELG, INT, AGE_P40, SOILSTEEL)
where:
  • STE = Total electricity sales (kWh)
  • STG = Total natural gas sales (mcf)
  • FUELE = Electricity fuel price ($/kwh)
  • FUELG = Natural gas fuel price ($/mcf)
  • INT = Number of street intersections (#)
  • AGE_P40 = Share of 40+ year-old houses (%)
  • SOILSTEEL = Steel corrosivity of the soil (%)
Following Mayo, a dummy variable was initially added to distinguish electricity-only firms, but this variable was found to be insignificant and was dropped from the final model [1]. The unit capital prices and wage rates were also insignificant, which was probably due to the small variations in such prices within a relatively small geographic area. The descriptive statistics for the above variables are presented in Table 2 for the total cost model and in Table 3 for the underground cost model. The regression results (Table 4) show that the Box-Cox form is superior to the log-log form for both the total and underground cost models based on the log-likelihood test. All the variables are significant, with the expected signs. All the above-mentioned variables are common in the total and underground investment cost models apart from the steel corrosivity of the soil. This variable did not have a statistically significant effect on total investment costs, but significantly affected underground investment costs. This is plausible because soil corrosivity increases the costs of underground gas pipes and electricity conductors as corrosion requires special precautions and extra coating.
As expected, the outputs (electricity and gas sales) and fuel prices have positive and significant effects on costs. The number of street intersections, reflecting the effect of urban form on costs, is significant. A larger number of street intersections complicates the construction of a distribution network, therefore increasing costs. The proportion of old houses (houses that are more than 40 years old) is positive and significant and can be considered a proxy for the concentration of densely built-up neighborhoods close to city centers. Older housing stocks increase distribution costs due to their central location, with pavements, narrow streets and requirement of more maintenance. Steel corrosivity is positive and significant in the underground cost model only, as increasing corrosivity requires more precautionary measures, such as the use of more durable materials or extra coating.

5.2. Analysis of Scale Effects

The cost elasticities at the sample mean for the total system are presented in Table 5, which have been calculated for all the independent variables using Equation (8). The price of natural gas has the strongest impact on total costs. When the price of natural gas increases by 1%, the total capital cost increases by 1.29%. Total electricity sales have the second greatest impact, with an increase in 1% resulting in an increase of 0.47% in cost. As the joint distribution system covers the two products of electricity and natural gas, the returns to scale with regard to both outputs are measured by the sum of the respective cost elasticities, which can be expressed as ε R = 0.469 + 0.143 = 0.612 . When both outputs increase by 1%, the total capital costs increase by 0.612%.
The cost elasticities were also computed for underground capital investments (Table 6). The results are similar to those in Table 5. The effect of natural gas fuel price has the greatest impact on underground costs, with an increase of 1% resulting in an increase of 1.97% in underground costs. The steel corrosivity has the smallest impact, with an increase of 1% in corrosivity leading to an increase of 0.02% in the underground capital investment cost.

5.3. Analysis of Joint Costs Effects

The joint cost savings indicator S defined by Equation (10) has been computed using the Box-Cox functions presented in Table 6. Positive values of S indicate the presence of savings, while the negative values indicate losses. The values of S were calculated for different combinations of electricity and natural gas outputs, STE and STG, using the mean values of all the other variables (Table 7 and Table 8). The ranges between the minimum and the maximum values of STE and STG, which are (83–3,113,865 kwh) and (0.14–13,035 mcf), respectively, are divided into 10 equal intervals and S was computed for each output combination. S is in the range of 0.352–0.859 when using the total cost function and in the range of 0.182–0.665 when using the underground cost function. These results provide evidence for joint cost savings. However, those savings decrease with increasing electricity and natural gas outputs (Figure 2, Table 7 and Table 8). The savings are higher for the total system as compared to the underground system.
The highest levels of savings (S = 0.859 and 0.665) are obtained when both sectors’ outputs are minimal (83 Mwh and 0.14 mmcf), while the lowest levels of savings (S = 0.352 and 0.182) are obtained when both sectors’ outputs are maximal (3,113,865 Mwh and 13,035 mmcf). The higher savings in smaller markets may be related to the easier coordination of investments in both distribution systems. These results are consistent with literature results that were reported in Section 2, while large economies are observed for smaller firms.
The values of S are calculated for the same output levels using the minimum and maximum values of the other variables: electricity fuel price, natural gas fuel price, number of street intersections and the proportion of houses that were 40 years old for both cost functions. The steel corrosivity was considered for the underground cost function only. The S values for the four combinations of outputs and at the minimum/maximum values of the other variables are presented in Table 9 and Table 10. The indicator surfaces are graphically represented in Figure 3 and Figure 4.
The results for the electricity and natural gas fuel prices are very close. The savings are higher when the fuel prices are maximal, which suggests that multi-utility investments are more feasible in areas where fuel is expensive. The savings are higher in areas where the proportion of older houses is maximal, which suggests that older neighborhoods with paved sidewalks may provide more opportunities for the efficient design of joint underground systems, hence leading to lower costs. The largest difference takes place when varying the number of street intersections. Higher savings are achieved for the maximum number of intersections, suggesting that such intersections facilitate the joint design of both networks, thus reducing costs. The overall lowest scores (0.242 and 0.182) are obtained for the maximal outputs and lowest number of street intersections. The S scores are higher in areas where the soil is more susceptible to steel corrosion, since joint underground design is more feasible in such areas.

6. Conclusions

This paper has analyzed the cost savings achieved through the joint distribution of gas and electricity. The results show that urban and geographical variables have significant impacts on the capital costs of electricity and natural gas distribution systems. In particular, the number of street intersections and the proportion of old housing stock both influence total and underground costs, while soil corrosivity is an additional factor that increases underground costs. In contrast to the earlier literature that focused only on company-level data, this study uses urban and geographic data at a detailed local level.
Overall, for the range of outputs considered, it is more cost-efficient to invest jointly in electricity and natural gas distribution networks than doing so separately. The savings indicator is in the range of 0.352–0.859 for the total cost and in the range of 0.182–0.665 for the underground cost at different levels of electricity and natural gas outputs. Furthermore, this decreases with increasing electricity and natural gas outputs. When different values of fuel prices and urban variables are considered, the number of street intersections was found to have the greatest impact. The savings in joint costs are the highest for a maximum number of street intersections, which suggests that joint capital investment is a rational economic approach in more densified and complex urban areas, such as city centers, apart from aesthetic and safety concerns. The joint construction of underground systems for both electricity and gas would reduce undergrounding costs. Therefore, we should encourage a shift from overhead to underground electricity distribution systems, especially when considering the safety and beautification advantages such a shift would entail.
In conclusion, urban policy makers and utility managers should consider both joint distribution costs and the role of site-specific urban factors when planning the construction of energy distribution infrastructure. Joint service provision was found to be economically more efficient than separate provision. The study can be expanded to other urban services, such as water and wastewater systems. Joint cost analysis of urban energy and water services at a detailed local level with the inclusion of urban and geographic factors can provide deeper insights into urban planning.

Author Contributions

Both authors contributed to the paper. Calculations and estimations are done by Muzeyyen Anil Senyel under the supervision of Jean-Michel Guldmann.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Street Network and Soil Groups Maps

Figure A1. Street Network Map in the State of New York.
Figure A1. Street Network Map in the State of New York.
Urbansci 02 00035 g0a1
Figure A2. Soil Groups Map in the State of New York.
Figure A2. Soil Groups Map in the State of New York.
Urbansci 02 00035 g0a2

References

  1. Mayo, J.W. Multiproduct Monopoly, Regulation, and Firm Costs. South. Econ. J. 1984, 52, 208–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Farsi, M.; Fetz, A.; Filippini, M. Economies of Scale and Scope in Multi Utilities. Energy J. 2008, 29, 123–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Sing, M. Are Combination Gas and Electric Utilities Multiproduct Natural Monopolies? Rev. Econ. Stat. 1987, 69, 392–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Chapell, H.W., Jr.; Wilder, R.P.; Mayo, J.W. Multiproduct Monopoly, Regulation, and Firm Costs: Comment. South. Econ. J. 1986, 52, 1168–1174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Fraquelli, G.; Piacenza, M.; Vannoni, D. Scope and Scale Economies in Multi-utilities: Evidence from Gas, Water and Electricity Combinations. Appl. Econ. 2004, 36, 2045–2057. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Piacenza, M.; Vannoni, D. Choosing Among Alternative Cost Function Specifications: An Application to Italian Multi-utilities. Econ. Lett. 2004, 82, 415–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Kim, H.Y.; Clark, R.M. Economies of Scale and Scope in Water Supply. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 1988, 18, 479–502. [Google Scholar]
  8. Fraquelli, G.; Giandrone, R. Reforming the Wastewater Treatment Sector in Italy: Implications of Plant Size, Structure, and Scale Economies. Water Resour. Res. 2003, 39, 1–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Hayes, K. Cost Structure of the Water Utility Industry. Appl. Econ. 1987, 19, 417–425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Martins, R.; Fortunato, A.; Coelho, F. Cost Structure of the Portugese Water Industry: A Cubic Cost Function Application; Grupo de Estudos Monetários e Financeiros: Coimbra, Portugal, 2006; pp. 1–26. Available online: http://gemf.fe.uc.pt/workingpapers/pdf/2006/gemf06_09.pdf (accessed on 6 March 2015).
  11. Garcia, S.; Moreaux, M.; Reynaud, A. Measuring Economies of Vertical Integration in Network Industries: An Application to the Water Sector. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2007, 25, 791–820. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Saal, D.S.; Parker, D. The Impact of Privatization and Regulation on the Water and Sewerage Industry in England and Wales: A Translog Cost Function Model. Manag. Decis. Econ. 2000, 21, 253–268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Bottasso, A.; Conti, M.; Piacenz, M.; Vannoni, D. The Appropriateness of the Poolability Assumption for Multiproduct Technologies: Evidence from the English Water and Sewerage Utilities. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 130, 112–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Viton, P.A. Consolidations of Scale and Scope in Urban Transit. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 1992, 22, 25–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Farsi, M.; Fetz, A.; Filippini, M. Economies of Scale and Scope in Local Public Transportation. J. Trans. Econ. Policy 2007, 41, 345–361. [Google Scholar]
  16. Walter, M. Economies of Scale and Scope in Germany’s Urban Public Transport. Presented at the 7th Conference on Applied Infrastructure Research, Berlin, Germany, 10–11 October 2008; pp. 1–18. Available online: http://www.infraday.tu-berlin.de/fileadmin/fg280/veranstaltungen/infraday/conference_2008/papers_presentations/paper---walter.pdf (accessed on 23 March 2015).
  17. Di Giacomo, M.; Ottoz, E. The Relevance of Scale and Scope Economies in the Provision of Urban and Intercity Bus Transport. J. Trans. Econ. Policy 2010, 44, 161–187. [Google Scholar]
  18. Ottoz, E.; Di Giacomo, M. Diversification Strategies and Scope Economies: Evidence from a Sample of Italian Regional Bus Transport Providers. Appl. Econ. 2012, 44, 2867–2880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. American Society of Civil Engineers (ASCE). Report Card for America’s Infrastructure, Energy. Last Retrieved in November 2015. 2013. Available online: http://www.infrastructurereportcard.org/a/#p/energy/overview (accessed on 3 November 2015).
  20. EIA. Today in Energy-November 1, 2012. Last Retrieved in November 2015; 2012. Available online: http://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.cfm?id=8590 (accessed on 3 November 2015).
  21. Whitman, Requardt and Associates. Handy-Whitman Index of Public Utility Construction Costs; Whitman, Requardt and Associates: Baltimore, MD, USA, 1979. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Tax Districts and Population Distribution.
Figure 1. Tax Districts and Population Distribution.
Urbansci 02 00035 g001
Figure 2. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Electricity and Natural Gas Outputs.
Figure 2. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Electricity and Natural Gas Outputs.
Urbansci 02 00035 g002
Figure 3. Savings Indicator for Different Values of Electricity and Natural Gas Sales and for Different Levels of Price and Urban Variables.
Figure 3. Savings Indicator for Different Values of Electricity and Natural Gas Sales and for Different Levels of Price and Urban Variables.
Urbansci 02 00035 g003
Figure 4. Savings Indicator for Different Values of Electricity and Natural Gas Sales for Different Levels of Steel Corrosivity in Underground Investment.
Figure 4. Savings Indicator for Different Values of Electricity and Natural Gas Sales for Different Levels of Steel Corrosivity in Underground Investment.
Urbansci 02 00035 g004
Table 1. Modeling Studies of Electricity–Gas Combinations.
Table 1. Modeling Studies of Electricity–Gas Combinations.
Author(s) and YearIndependent VariablesFunctional FormStudy Area and Sample Size
Mayo (1984)Electricity output,QuadraticUS
gas output, 200 utilities
dummies (electricity, gas) cross section
Chapell et al. (1986)Electricity output using fossil fuel,QuadraticUS
electricity output using all types 88 utilities
of fuels, gas output cross-section
Sing (1987)Electricity output,GeneralizedUS
gas output, prices (labor,translog108 utilities
capital, fuel), density, cost cross-section
shares (labor, fuel, capital)
Fraquelli et al. (2004)Electricity output,Translog,Italy
gas output, water output,Generalized90 utilities
prices (labor, other), cost sharestranslog,3-year pooled
(labor, other)Separable
quadratic,
Composite
Piacenza and Vannoni (2004)Electricity output,Translog,Italy
gas output, water output,Generalized90 utilities
prices (labor, other)translog,3-year pooled
Separable
quadratic,
Composite
Farsi et al. (2008)Electricity output,QuadraticSwitzerland
gas output, water output, 87 utilities
prices (labor, capital, electricity, 9-year panel
gas), density, dummies
(electricity, gas, water)
Table 2. Descriptive Statistics for the Total Investment Cost Model (n = 246).
Table 2. Descriptive Statistics for the Total Investment Cost Model (n = 246).
VariableMinimumMaximumMeanStd. Deviation
C ($)3236319,335,46016,713,21437,500,000
STE (kWh)83,4153,113,865,373135,749,892364,172,187
STG (mcf)14213,035,016719,0581,497,039
FUELE ($/kwh)2.073.633.140.59
FUELG ($/mcf)2.42.782.640.16
INT (#)1315,1147421665
AGE_P40 (%)0.0030.900.370.21
Table 3. Descriptive Statistics for the Underground Investment Cost Model (n = 234).
Table 3. Descriptive Statistics for the Underground Investment Cost Model (n = 234).
VariableMinimumMaximumMeanStd. Deviation
C ($)944159,542,6017,580,20818,100,000
STE (kWh)304,3363,113,865,373143,000,000364,172,187
STG (mcf)14213,035,016719,0581,497,039
FUELE ($)2.073.633.130.58
FUELG ($)2.42.782.650.15
INT (#)1315,1147691701
AGE_P40 (%)0.0030.900.370.20
SOILSTEEL (%)0.010.980.310.26
Table 4. Cost Functions for the Total Capital Investment (n = 246) and the Underground Capital Investment (n = 234).
Table 4. Cost Functions for the Total Capital Investment (n = 246) and the Underground Capital Investment (n = 234).
Total Capital Investment Cost
(n = 246)
Underground Capital Investment Cost
(n = 234)
CoefficientModelsModels
Log-logBox-Cox(λ, θ) aLog-logBox-Cox(λ, θ) a
Constant0.158−51.279−2.674−42.48
STE0.664 ***0.416 ***0.674 ***0.281 ***
STG0.025 ***0.388 ***0.059 ***0.293 ***
FUELE0.458 *9.915 **0.197 *7.74 **
FUELG1.682 **50.132 ***3.264 **37.77 **
INT0.309 ***4.437 ***0.249 **0.929 **
AGEP400.206 ***10.011 ***0.267 *3.051 **
SOILSTEEL0.028 *0.729 **
λ 0.213 *** 0.186 ***
θ 0.229 *** 0.173 ***
R20.8540.9240.6790.758
Log-likelihood−4009.96−3947.95−3688.47−3659.42
H0: θ = λ = 0 bChi-sq = 124.02 *** Chi-sq = 58.1 ***
H0: θ = λ = 1Chi-sq = 896.68 *** Chi-sq = 831.51 ***
a Selected model; b Log-likelihood test results;*** Significant at the 1% level; ** Significant at the 5% level; * Significant at the 10% level.
Table 5. Total Capital Investment Cost Elasticities (n = 246).
Table 5. Total Capital Investment Cost Elasticities (n = 246).
VariableElasticity
Total electricity sales (kWh)0.469
Total natural gas sales (mcf)0.143
Electricity fuel price ($/kWh)0.264
Natural gas fuel price ($/mcf)1.287
Number of street intersections (#)0.379
Share of 40+ year-old houses (%)0.169
Table 6. Underground Capital Investment Cost Elasticities (n = 234).
Table 6. Underground Capital Investment Cost Elasticities (n = 234).
VariableElasticity
Total electricity sales (kWh)0.402
Total natural gas sales (mcf)0.157
Electricity fuel price ($/kWh)0.416
Natural gas fuel price ($/mcf)1.970
Number of street intersections (#)0.139
Share of 40+ year-old houses (%)0.110
Steel corrosivity of the soil (%)0.026
Table 7. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Electricity and Natural Gas Outputs in the Total Cost Function.
Table 7. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Electricity and Natural Gas Outputs in the Total Cost Function.
Electricity (1000 kwh)
83346,061692,0391,038,0181,383,9961,729,9742,075,9522,421,9302,767,9083,113,865
Natural Gas (1000 mcf)0.140.8590.5220.4850.4640.4490.4370.4280.4200.4130.407
14480.7190.4670.4370.4200.4080.3980.3900.3840.3780.373
28960.6980.4580.4290.4130.4010.3910.3840.3770.3720.367
43450.6850.4520.4240.4080.3960.3870.3800.3740.3680.363
57930.6750.4480.4210.4050.3930.3840.3770.3710.3650.361
72410.6680.4440.4180.4020.3900.3820.3740.3680.3630.358
86900.6610.4420.4150.3990.3880.3800.3720.3660.3610.357
10,1380.6560.4390.4130.3970.3860.3780.3710.3650.3590.355
11,5860.6510.4370.4110.3960.3850.3760.3690.3630.3580.353
13,0350.6460.4350.4090.3940.3830.3750.3680.3620.3570.352
Table 8. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Electricity and Natural Gas Outputs in the Underground Cost Function.
Table 8. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Electricity and Natural Gas Outputs in the Underground Cost Function.
Electricity (1000 kwh)
83346,061692,0391,038,0181,383,9961,729,9742,075,9522,421,9302,767,9083,113,865
Natural Gas (1000 mcf)0.140.6650.3070.2800.2660.2550.2480.2410.2360.2320.228
14480.4560.2530.2350.2250.2170.2120.2070.2030.2000.197
28960.4330.2460.2290.2190.2120.2070.2020.1990.1950.193
43450.4200.2420.2250.2150.2090.2030.1990.1960.1930.190
57930.4100.2380.2220.2130.2060.2010.1970.1940.1910.188
72410.4030.2360.2200.2110.2040.1990.1950.1920.1890.186
86900.3960.2340.2180.2090.2030.1980.1940.1900.1880.185
10,1380.3910.2320.2160.2080.2010.1960.1920.1890.1860.184
11,5860.3860.2300.2150.2060.2000.1950.1910.1880.1850.183
13,0350.3820.2290.2140.2050.1990.1940.1900.1870.1840.182
Table 9. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Fuel Prices and Urban Variables at Different Output Combinations: Total Cost Function.
Table 9. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Fuel Prices and Urban Variables at Different Output Combinations: Total Cost Function.
Site-Specific VariablesOutput Levels (Electricity; Natural Gas)
(83; 0.14)(3,113,865; 13,035)(83; 13,035)(3,113,865; 0.14)
FUELELmin0.8550.3440.6380.398
max0.8610.3550.6490.410
FUELGASmin0.8550.3450.6390.400
max0.8630.3600.6540.415
INTRmin0.7810.2420.5170.287
max0.9040.4560.7380.514
AGEP40min0.8350.3100.6020.362
max0.8660.3650.6590.420
Table 10. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Fuel Prices and Site-specific Variables at Different Output Combinations: Underground Cost Function.
Table 10. Savings Indicator for Different Levels of Fuel Prices and Site-specific Variables at Different Output Combinations: Underground Cost Function.
Site-Specific VariablesOutput Levels (Electricity; Natural Gas)
(83; 0.14)(3,113,865; 13,035)(83; 13,035)(3,113,865; 0.14)
FUELELmin0.6290.1600.3460.201
max0.6760.1900.3950.237
FUELGASmin0.6230.1560.3400.197
max0.6820.1940.4020.242
INTRmin0.5350.1140.2640.146
max0.7460.2480.4790.305
AGEP40min0.5800.1340.3010.170
max0.6840.1960.4040.244
SOILSTEELmin0.6010.1440.3200.183
max0.6790.1920.3980.240

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Senyel, M.A.; Guldmann, J.-M. Joint Costs in Electricity and Natural Gas Distribution Infrastructures: The Role of Urban Factors. Urban Sci. 2018, 2, 35. https://doi.org/10.3390/urbansci2020035

AMA Style

Senyel MA, Guldmann J-M. Joint Costs in Electricity and Natural Gas Distribution Infrastructures: The Role of Urban Factors. Urban Science. 2018; 2(2):35. https://doi.org/10.3390/urbansci2020035

Chicago/Turabian Style

Senyel, Muzeyyen Anil, and Jean-Michel Guldmann. 2018. "Joint Costs in Electricity and Natural Gas Distribution Infrastructures: The Role of Urban Factors" Urban Science 2, no. 2: 35. https://doi.org/10.3390/urbansci2020035

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop