Next Article in Journal
Making Sustainable Consumption and Production the Core of Sustainable Development Goals
Previous Article in Journal
Education for Sustainability through a Photography Competition
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Scenarios Analysis of the Energies’ Consumption and Carbon Emissions in China Based on a Dynamic CGE Model

1
School of Economics and Management, Beijing University of Technology, Beijing 100022, China
2
School of Economics and Management, North China Electric Power University, Beinong Road 2, Changping District, Beijing 102206, China
3
School of Management, China University of Mining and Technology (Beijing), Beijing 100083, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2014, 6(2), 487-512; https://doi.org/10.3390/su6020487
Submission received: 19 November 2013 / Revised: 11 January 2014 / Accepted: 15 January 2014 / Published: 23 January 2014

Abstract

:
This paper investigates the development trends and variation characteristics of China’s economy, energy consumption and carbon emissions from 2007 to 2030, and the impacts on China’s economic growth, energy consumption, and carbon emissions under the carbon tax policy scenarios, based on the dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model. The results show that during the simulation period, China’s economy will keep a relatively high growth rate, but the growth rate will slow down under the benchmark scenario. The energy consumption intensity and the carbon emissions intensity per unit of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) will continually decrease. The energy consumption structure and industrial structure will gradually optimize. With the economic growth, the total energy consumption will constantly increase, and the carbon dioxide emissions are still large, and the situation of energy-saving and emission-reduction is still serious. The carbon tax is very important for energy-saving and emission-reduction and energy consumption structure optimization, and the effect of the carbon tax on GDP is small. If the carbon tax could be levied and the enterprise income tax could be reduced at the same time, the dual goals of reducing energy consumption and carbon emissions and increasing the GDP growth can be achieved. Improving the technical progress level of clean power while implementing a carbon tax policy is very meaningful to optimize energy consumption structure and reduce the carbon emissions, but it has some offsetting effect to reduce energy consumption.

1. Introduction

The computable general equilibrium (CGE) model provides a consistent framework to analyze the economic impacts of energy and environmental policy. It has sound micro-economic foundations and a complete description of the economy with both direct and indirect effects of policy changes. Since the 1980s, the CGE model has been more widely applied and became the mainstream of energy and environmental policy analysis.
Many developed CGE models, researching energy and environmental policy, are static (Akkemik and Oguz [1], Xie and Saltzman [2], Fraser and Waschik [3], Caron [4], Boccanfuso et al. [5]). Interest for forecast and analysis of trends has triggered the flourish of dynamic CGE models. Thus, there are growing numbers of literatur on dynamic CGE models for energy and environmental problems. Vennemo [6] discussed the nature of environmental feedbacks on the Norwegian economy by using the general equilibrium model DREAM (Dynamic Resource/Environment Applied Model). Wendner [7] analyzed environmental tax reforms, which use the revenues from CO2 taxation to partially finance the pension system within the framework of a dynamic computable general equilibrium model (DCGE). By using this DCGE model, Muto et al. [8] simulated the automobile and the related carbon tax needed to accomplish the objective in the transport sector in Japan. Fukiharu [9] used the dynamic general equilibrium approach to examine the effect of the greenhouse effect on the sustainability of human population, as well as the economic policies when the sustainability is in danger. By establishing a single-country (Japan) dynamic computable general equilibrium model with endogenous technological change, Matsumoto [10] evaluated the economic and environmental effects of climate change mitigation in a country scale considering various time horizons in the analysis. O’Ryan et al. [11] developed a dynamic CGE model for Chile and made a quantitative analysis of the socioeconomic and environmental impacts of different trade agreements. This study aimed to compare the consequences of unilateral liberalization and trade agreements from Chile with the performance from European Union (EU) and the United States (USA). Hermeling et al. [12] introduced a new method for stochastic sensitivity analysis for CGE model, based on Gauss Quadrature, and applied it to check the robustness of a large-scale climate policy evaluation before making an impact assessment of EU2020 climate policy.
Meantime, several energy and environment related studies with static CGE models can be found in China. He et al. [13] analyzed the influence of coal price adjustment on the electric power industry, and the influence of electricity price adjustment on the macroeconomy in China, based on a static CGE models. Lin and Jiang [14] applied the price-gap approach to estimate China’s energy subsidies and analyzed the economic impacts of energy subsidy reforms in China through a CGE model. The results showed that removing energy subsidies will result in a significant fall in energy demand and emissions, but will impact the macroeconomic variables negatively (See other relevant studies, such as Ren et al. [15], He et al. [16], Lu et al. [17], and Zhang et al. [18]).
Furthermore, some dynamic CGE models have also been proposed to assess the energy and environment problems in China. Zhang [19,20] analyzed the macroeconomic effects of limiting China’s CO2 emissions by using a time-recursive dynamic CGE model of the Chinese economy. The baseline scenario for Chinese economy over the period to 2010 is first developed under a set of assumptions about the exogenous variables. Garbaccio et al. [21] built a recursive dynamic CGE model and evaluated the impacts of carbon tax on the economy of China, whilst considering the coexistence of planned economy and market economy. Liang et al. [22] established a dynamic CGE model to simulate a carbon tax policy in China, and compared the macroeconomic effects of different carbon tax schemes as well as their impacts on the energy- and trade-intensive sectors. By constructing a dynamic recursive general equilibrium model, Lu et al. [23] explored the impact of carbon tax on Chinese economy, as well as the cushion effects of the complementary policies. Recently, based on a multi-sector dynamic CGE model, Tang et al. [24] examined the impacts of the proposed carbon-based border tax adjustments (BTAs) with different tax rates from $20 to $100 per ton of carbon emissions (tC) imposed by both USA and EU on China’s international trade. The simulation results suggested that BTAs would have a negative impact on China’s international trade, incurring large losses in both exports and imports.
Dynamic models obviously incorporate the accumulation processes of an economy (in particular, investment), and increase the mid/long term predictive capability of the simulations. Nevertheless, they also increase the complexity of the assessment by adding the trends of the economic variables to the inter-relations in a specific moment of time. In addition, the CGE model is more suitable for the counties and regions in which market economy system is relatively perfect. However, China is in a specific period of transition from a planned to a market economy, and the market equilibrium mechanism is not perfect. In this case, the simulation results of a dynamic CGE model may be quite different from the actual situation. When we plan to set a dynamic CGE model, it requires us to set the relevant parameters of dynamic scene as reasonable as possible to make sure the dynamic simulation results are in accordance with the objective reality of China’s economic development.
Therefore, this paper intends to develop a dynamic CGE model to study the development trend and the changing characteristics of economy, energies’ consumption and carbon emissions from 2007 to 2030, as well as to analyze the impact of carbon tax policy and clean energy technology progress on economy, energies’ consumption, and carbon emission.
This paper is organized as follows: Section 2 introduces the model structures and functions characteristics. Section 3 discusses how to divide the sectors, especially the energies sectors by the RAS (Bi-proportional Scaling Method) method. Section 4 depicts the detailed calculation and handling process of carbon emissions coefficients, and the setting of dynamic benchmark scenario parameters. Section 5 analyzes the variation characteristics of China’s gross domestic product, the total energy consumption, energy consumption intensity, carbon emissions, and carbon emissions intensity under the benchmark scenario. Section 6 studies the effects on GDP, energy consumption and carbon emissions under different scenarios of carbon tax policy. Finally, conclusions and suggestions are proposed in Section 7, based on the comprehensive analysis presented in Section 5 and Section 6.

2. Theoretical Framework of the CGE Model for China

2.1. Production Module

Production functions for each sector describe the ways in which capital, labor, energy, and intermediate inputs can be used to produce output. Overall, the production process is represented by a seven-layer nested Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) function (i.e., constant elasticity of substitute function) as depicted in Figure 1 (where is the elasticity of substitute). The top layer of the nest structure comprises the composite primary inputs of labor, capital, and energy, as well as intermediate inputs. Following Burniaux et al. [25] and Huang et al. [26], we assume that the relationship between energy and capital is quasi-complementary, while the substitute elasticity between capital/energy and labor is larger. Therefore, the second layer determines the producer’s demand for input of labor and the composite capital and energy. At the third layer, the composite capital and energy is disaggregated into capital and energy. As electricity is mainly generated by consuming fossil fuels, the substitution elasticity between electricity and fossil fuels should be smaller than those within fossil fuels (Wu and Xuan [27]). Therefore, energy is disaggregated into fossil energy and electric power at the fourth layer. At the fifth layer, the electric power is disaggregated into thermal power and clean power, and the fossil energy is disaggregated into coal and composite petroleum energy and gas energy. The composite petroleum energy and gas energy is disaggregated into petroleum energy and gas energy, and the coal energy is disaggregated into coal and coke in the sixth layer. At the bottom layer, the petroleum energy is constituted by crude oil and petroleum, and the gas energy is constituted by natural gas and gas.
Figure 1. Structure of the production function module.
Figure 1. Structure of the production function module.
Sustainability 06 00487 g001
The CES function is applied in the product functions. The optimal combination of input factors is based on the following assumptions:
Sustainability 06 00487 i001
Sustainability 06 00487 i002
where, Xi is the input factor i; Pi is the corresponding price; V is the output; βi is the share parameter of the factor i; A is the overall transformation parameter on all input factors; λi is the transformation parameter on input factor i; ρ is a coefficient related to the substitution elasticity.

2.2. International Trade Module

The substitutability between imported and domestically produced commodities is assumed to be imperfect in this study. Armington assumption, therefore, is applied to solve the problem. The domestically produced commodities and imported commodities are substitutable, they are not completely substitutable. The consumers can choose the best combination of imported and domestic commodities to minimize the costs. The function is shown as follows:
min (PDi · QDi + PMi · QMi)
Sustainability 06 00487 i003
where QDi refers to the domestic demand quantity of commodity i, PDi is the price; QMi refers to the imported quantity of commodity i, PMi refers to the domestic price, QQi refers to the total domestic demand quantity, βdi and βmi refer to the share parameters domestic and import commodity, λmi is the overall transportation parameter between domestic supply and import demand of commodity i, ρmi is related substitution elasticity of import demand and domestic supply.
We adopt a constant elasticity transformation (CET) function to allocate total domestic output between exports and domestic sales. The function describes the optimal combinations between domestic sales and exports under a certain restriction of production technology. The function is shown as follows:
max (PDi · QDi + PEi · QEi)
Sustainability 06 00487 i004
where QDi refers to the domestic sale quantity of commodity i, PDi is the price; QEi refers to the export quantity of commodity i, PEi refers to the domestic price, QXi refers to the total domestic output, αdi is the share parameter of domestic sales of commodity i, and αei is the share parameter of export of commodity i, λei is the overall transportation parameter between domestic sales and export of commodity i, ρei is related coefficient of the substitution elasticity.

2.3. Income and Expenditure

Household income is mainly from labor income, profit distribution from enterprises, and transfer payment from government and enterprises. Their income is used for consumption and saving. The consumption function complies with Stone-Geary utility function assumption. The specific functions are shown as below:
Sustainability 06 00487 i005
where, YH is the households total disposable income (After-tax income minus household savings); HDi is the households demand quantity of commodity i; θi is the minimum basic demand of commodity i; βi is the marginal propensity to consumption; PQi is the demand price of commodity i.
The enterprises’ income primarily comes from the capital revenue, and their expenditure mainly includes the transfer payment to the inhabitants and the income tax to the government. The left income is for enterprises’ savings. For the government, they get the income from indirect taxes, household and enterprises income tax, and tariff, while their expenditure includes transfer payment to the household and enterprises, government consumption, export rebate, and government savings.

2.4. Social Welfare Module

For the welfare function, we adopt Hicks Equivalent Variation. Based on commodity prices before the policy implementation, we calculate inhabitants’ utility through the demand changes by using the following formula:
Sustainability 06 00487 i006
where, EV is the equivalent variation of inhabitants’ welfare, and E(Us,PQb) is the utility after the policy implementation calculated by the payment function based on price before the policy implementation; E(Ub,PQb) is the utility before the policy implementation; Sustainability 06 00487 i007 is the price of commodity i before the policy implementation; Sustainability 06 00487 i008 and Sustainability 06 00487 i009 are the inhabitants’ consumption before and after the policy implementation, respectively. EV is calculated by the formal formulas. Positive EV means improvement in social welfare and the negative one means deterioration in social welfare after the implementation of the policy.

2.5. Carbon Tax Module

In this study, we assume that the carbon emissions mainly come from final consumption of coal, coke, crude oil, petroleum, natural gas, and gas. The carbon tax is calculated though multiplying the demand for various fossil energies by the rate of specific duty on each unit of carbon emissions, and the rate of specific duty on each unit of carbon emissions is endogenously decided under the given reduction target in this study. After converting the rate of specific duty into ad valorem tax rate, the demand price of the fossil energy will be (1+ ti) · PQi. ti is the ad valorem duty rate of fossil energy i, and PQi is the demand price of the fossil energy i. In doing so, the carbon tax will directly affect the input and demand cost of fossil energy, and, in turn, affect government revenue.

2.6. Model Closure and Market Clearing

The CGE model in this paper consider three principles of closure: government budget balance, foreign trade balance, and invest-saving balance. When considering the government budget balance, the government consumption is taken as exogenous variable, while government saving is endogenous. For the foreign trade balance, we assume exchange rate is designated endogenously while foreign savings is exogenous variable. The policy impacts on the exchange rate, and then the export and import are involved, even affects the whole economy. For the saving-investment balance, neo-classical closure principles are adopted. The investment is determined by the savings and all the savings in the economy system will be transferred to investment.
In this module, labor market, capital market, and commodity market are cleared by endogenous factor prices. The output of the model must be interpreted as a new equilibrium reached after the economy system has adjusted to the shock. The new equilibrium is the result of a mixture of different impacts, and the net effects of which cannot be derived analytically because the shock inevitably induce adjustments on several intertwined markets. Consequently, numerical simulations, therefore, are necessary in order to obtain the new equilibrium.

2.7. Dynamic Functions Model

The dynamic model mainly includes some functions related labor growth, technological progress level (Total Factor Productivity), and capital accumulation and allocation among sectors. In this paper, CET functions are applied to display the allocation of capital among sectors, and this allocation is determined by the sectoral capital revenue rate, the average rate of total capital, and the total supply of social capital. The functions of capital accumulation and allocation are shown as below.
Ki,t = αi−ρ · (Ri,t / ARt)ρ · KSt
KSt = sum(i, αi · Ki.t(1+ρ)/ρ)ρ/(1+ρ)
Sustainability 06 00487 i010
where, Ki,t is the capital demand of sector i in t period, KSt is total supply of social capital in t period, TINVt is the total investment in t period, Ri,t is the capital revenue of sector i in t period, ARt is the social capital average revenue in t period, depri is the capital depreciation rate of sector i, αi is the share parameter of capital requirement of sector i, ρ is the substitution parameter of capital among sectors.

3. Model Sectoral Structure

The CGE model in this paper is created by selecting 23 sectors, required for the carbon tax policy simulation. Most studies, which take the carbon tax policy of China as the research subject, usually integrate the mining and washing of coal sectors and coking sector into one sector, and integrate the petroleum extraction sector and refined oil sector into one sector. Factually, the energy consumption and carbon emissions are significantly different in the production process of those energy sectors. For example, the refined oil sector is unique in that it uses crude oil as a “feedstock” to produce refined oil products. The fuel combusted within petroleum refineries typically amounts to 6 to 10 percent of the total fuel input to the refinery, depending on the complexity and vintage of the technology (IPCC, 2006) [28]. Similarly, coal is the important raw material in the coking process. Therefore, if those sectors are integrated into one sector, the feedstock input of crude oil or coal will be taken as the energy input, which may skew the results of policy simulation. According to the energy characteristics of China, this paper further disaggregate energy sectors into eight departments of coal, coke, crude oil, petroleum products, natural gas, gas, thermal power, and clean electricity, it is of great benefit to simulate the carbon tax’s impact on China’s economic development more accurately. The basic data are compiled from the 2007 Input–Output Table of China [29].
In addition, the sector of extraction of petroleum and the sector of extraction natural gas are integrated into one sector, namely, the sector of extraction of petroleum and natural gas in the Input-Output Tables of China (the 1997 Input-Output Tables of China is an exception) [30]. Disaggregating the sector of extraction of petroleum and natural gas into two sectors (that is, the sector of extraction of petroleum and the sector of extraction natural gas) is require for simulating the carbon tax policy since the input structure of production process and the allocation structure output of extraction of petroleum and extraction of natural gas are significantly different.
This paper takes the sum of the intermediate input rows and columns of Basic Flow Table of 2007 Input-Output Table [29] as the control variables of row and column vectors, respectively. Then, we apply the RAS (Bi-proportional Scaling Method) method, which is an iterative method of bi-proportional adjustment to update the input-output table proposed by Stone in the 1960s, to compile the data of the sector of extraction petroleum and the sector of extraction natural gas. The data of inhabitants’ consumption, government consumption, investment, inventory, import, export, and value-added of Extraction of Petroleum and Natural Gas sectors, are obtained from the 2007 China Input-Output Table [29] and the China Energy Statistical Yearbook [31]. Thus, we adjust 42 and 135 sectors 2007 Input-Output Tables into 23 sectors according to the research need (see Table 1).

4. Setting of Related Date and Parameters

4.1. Carbon Emissions Date

The data of CO2 emissions is calculated by the consumption of fossil energy, as it is unavailable in China. In this paper, the fossil energy fuels include coal, crude oil, natural gas, petroleum products, coking, and gas. The average low-level calorific value of fossil energy fuels comes from the China Energy Statistics Yearbook [30]. The emission coefficients of fossil energy fuels are got from 2006 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories [27]. The sectoral energy consumption of each type is derived according to the proportion of sector input in total energy consumption. It is worth noting that the crude oil consumption used for petroleum refining is excluded, and the crude coal used for coking and coal gasification, are also excluded.
Table 1. The sectors definition in the computable general equilibrium (CGE) model and 2007 Input-Output (I/O) table.
Table 1. The sectors definition in the computable general equilibrium (CGE) model and 2007 Input-Output (I/O) table.
CodeSectors classification of 2007 I/O tableCodeSectors classification of CGE model
1Agriculture, Forestry, Farming of Animals and Fishing1Agriculture, Forestry, Farming of Animals and Fishing
2Mining and Washing of Coal2Mining and Washing of Coal
3Extraction of Petroleum and Natural Gas3Extraction of Petroleum
4Extraction of Natural Gas
4Mining and Processing of Metal Ores5Mining and Processing of others Ores
5Mining and Processing of Nonmetal Ores
6Manufacture and Processing of Foods and Tobacco6Manufacture and Processing of Foods and Tobacco
7Manufacture of Textile7Manufacture and Processing of Textile and Related Product
8Manufacture of Textile Wearing Apparel, Footwear, Caps, Leather, Fur, Feather and Related Product
9Processing Manufacture of Timber and Furniture8Processing Manufacture of Timber, Paper, Printing and Articles For Culture, Education and Sport Activity
10Manufacture of Paper, Printing and Articles For Culture, Education and Sport Activity
11Processing of Petroleum, Coking, Processing of Nuclear Fuel9Processing of Petroleum
10Coking
12Chemical Industry11Chemical Industry
13Manufacture of Non-metallic Mineral Products12Manufacture of Cement, Lime and Gypsum
13Manufacture of Non-metallic Mineral Products
14Smelting and Pressing of Metals14Smelting and Pressing and Manufacture of Metals and Related Product
15Manufacture of Metal Products
16Manufacture of General and Special Purpose Machinery15Manufacture of Machinery and Equipment
17Manufacture of Transport Equipment
18Manufacture of Electrical Machinery and Equipment
19Manufacture of Communication Equipment, Computers and Other Electronic Equipment16Manufacture of Communication Equipment,Measuring Instruments and Other Manufacturing
20Manufacture of Measuring Instruments and Machinery for Cultural Activity and Office Work
21Manufacture of Artwork and Other Manufacturing
22Recycling and Disposal of Waste
23Production and Distribution of Electric Power and Heat Power17Production and Distribution of thermal Power
18Production and Distribution of Clean Power
24Production and Distribution of Gas19Production and Distribution of Gas
26Construction20Construction
27Transport and Storage21Transport ,Storage and Post
28Post
29Information Transfer, Computer Services and Software22Service(1)
30Wholesale and Retail Trade
31Hotel and Restaurants
32Finance
33Real Estate
34Tenancy and Business Services
25Production and Distribution of Water 23Service(2)
35Research and Experimental Development
36Professional Technique Services
37Management of Water Conservancy, Environment and Public Establishment
38Resident Services and Other Services
39Education
40Sanitation, Social Security & Social Welfare
41Culture, Sports and Entertainment
42Public Management & Social Organization
Table 2. The substitute elasticities of production functions, Armington functions and constant elasticity transformation (CET) functions.
Table 2. The substitute elasticities of production functions, Armington functions and constant elasticity transformation (CET) functions.
SectorsSubstitute elasticities of production functionsArmington functionsCET functions
Sustainability 06 00487 i011 Sustainability 06 00487 i012 Sustainability 06 00487 i013 Sustainability 06 00487 i014 Sustainability 06 00487 i015 Sustainability 06 00487 i016 Sustainability 06 00487 i017 Sustainability 06 00487 i018 Sustainability 06 00487 i019 Sustainability 06 00487 i020σmiσei
Agriculture, Forestry, Farming of Animals and Fishing0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.25234
Mining and Processing of others Ores0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Manufacture and Processing of Foods and Tobacco0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Manufacture and Processing of Textile and Related Product0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Processing Manufacture of Timber, Paper, Printing and Articles For Culture, Education and Sport Activity0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Chemical Industry0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Manufacture of Cement, Lime and Gypsum0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Manufacture of Non-metallic Mineral Products0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Smelting and Pressing and Manufacture of Metals and Related Product0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Manufacture of Machinery and Equipment0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Manufacture of Communication Equipment, Measuring Instruments and Other Manufacturing0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Construction0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.25223
Transport ,Storage and Post0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.25223
Service(1)0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.25222.5
Service(2)0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.25222.5
Mining and Washing of Coal0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Coking0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Extraction of Petroleum0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Processing of Petroleum0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Extraction of Natural Gas0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Production and Distribution of Gas0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.2522.53.5
Production and Distribution of thermal Power0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.25223
Production and Distribution of Clean Power0.30.80.61.21.21.31.251.61.25223

4.2. Benchmark Scenario Parameters

The exogenous parameters in this model include the substitute elasticities of productive functions, Armington functions and CET functions, the growth rate of labor force, total factor productivity (TFP), structure coefficients of intermediate input and output, inhabitants’ savings rate, the trade surplus. The setting of the substitute elasticity of productive functions, Armington functions and CET functions refers to related research (He et al. [32], Wang [33], Xuan [34], Tan [35]), and with our own adjustment (see Table 2). The growth rates of labor force are presumed according to China’s actual employment situation and the some scholars’ predictions [36,37,38] (see Table 3).
Table 3. The estimate of labor force growth rates (%).
Table 3. The estimate of labor force growth rates (%).
Year2008–20102011–20152016–20202021–20252026–2030
Categories
Primary Industry−0.01−0.01−0.01−0.010
Secondary industry0.010.010.010.010
Tertiary Industry0.030.030.030.030.03
It is assumed TFP is the same in most sectors, as shown in Table 4, during simulation period, except for Extraction of Petroleum and Extraction of Natural Gas. China’s energy resources and sustainable supply capacity of conventional fossil energies are insufficient. Annual output of petroleum can only be maintained at around 200 million tons. New increased production of conventional natural gas can only meet about 30% of the new demand. The proved reserves and the output of unconventional gas resources of coal bed methane and shale gas will have relatively high growth rates, which will be an important growth pole of natural gas the supply. Therefore, it is assumed that the TFP growth rate of Extraction of Petroleum is 0 during the simulation period, because the extraction costs will gradually increase due to the limitation of reserves and extracted geological conditions. The TFP growth rate of natural gas is slightly higher than the national average due to the gradual exploitation of unconventional natural gas.
Table 4. The total factor productivity (TFP) during the Simulation period (%).
Table 4. The total factor productivity (TFP) during the Simulation period (%).
Year2008–20102011–20152016–20202021–20252026–2030
Category
TFP growth rate3–2.52.02.02.02.0
According to China Input-Output Table published, and with reference to the variation characteristics of intermediate input rate of the United States and Japan Input-Output Table, a certain setting to the intermediate inputs rate is made during the benchmark scenario. With the economic development and social progress it is projected that the inhabitants’ savings rate will gradually decline. Under the benchmark scenario, the inhabitants’ savings will drop from the current 38% to a level of around 20%. It is also assumed the trade surplus will gradually decrease, as well and achieve trade balance in the year of 2030.
Table 5. The analysis of GDP, energy consumption and carbon emissions (benchmark scenario).
Table 5. The analysis of GDP, energy consumption and carbon emissions (benchmark scenario).
YearGDPGDP growth rateTotal energy consumptionEnergy consumption intensityTotal carbon emissionsCarbon emissions intensity
109 Yuan104 tons standard coalton standard coal/104 Yuan104 tonstons/104 Yuan
2007266,043.81 265,583.000.9983615,148.722.3122
2008291,784.569.68%284,167.410.9739660,032.342.2621
2009319,534.139.51%304,393.760.9526708,488.252.2173
2010348,977.029.21%326,039.210.9343759,919.822.1776
2011378,873.578.57%347,990.110.9185811,920.902.1430
2012410,927.868.46%370,806.390.9024865,955.372.1073
2013445,106.898.32%394,372.070.8860921,761.502.0709
2014481,380.728.15%418,581.230.8695979,101.122.0339
2015519,724.507.97%443,339.810.85301,037,763.701.9968
2016560,095.267.77%468,451.980.83641,097,386.891.9593
2017602,500.847.57%493,936.920.81981,157,956.901.9219
2018646,938.827.38%519,737.190.80341,219,349.891.8848
2019693,416.107.18%545,808.600.78711,281,472.321.8481
2020741,949.057.00%572,119.500.77111,344,259.241.8118
2021790,685.526.57%596,432.420.75431,402,048.061.7732
2022841,039.576.37%620,529.750.73781,459,396.161.7352
2023893,030.586.18%644,412.300.72161,516,308.851.6979
2024946,688.136.01%668,090.310.70571,572,812.601.6614
20251,002,051.625.85%691,582.070.69021,628,951.831.6256
20261,058,592.065.64%714,867.830.67531,684,753.171.5915
20271,116,874.215.51%738,002.170.66081,740,281.051.5582
20281,176,958.195.38%761,019.990.64661,795,616.711.5256
20291,238,913.425.26%783,961.010.63281,850,851.711.4939
20301,302,818.495.16%806,869.010.61931,906,086.381.4630

5. Simulation Analyses of the Dynamic Benchmark Scenario

According to the parameter setting of benchmark scenario and the model simulation analyses, Table 5 presents the variation characteristics of China’s GDP, the total energy consumption, energy consumption intensity, carbon emissions, and carbon emissions intensity under the benchmark scenario. It is shown that, from 2007 to 2030, China’s GDP will still grow rapidly. The GDP will increase from 26,604.381 billion Yuan in 2006 to 130,281.849 billion Yuan in 2030, but its growth rate will slow down. The economic growth rate mainly depends on the labor input, capital accumulation, and TFP. The main reason why the economic growth rate gradually decreases is that the capital accumulation is increasing compared with the labor input, leading to the gradual decrease of the marginal product of capital and the decrease of the GDP growth rate.
At the same time, the energy consumption and carbon emissions increase significantly during the simulation period. The energy consumption will increase by 3.04 times from 265.58 million tons standard coal in 2007 to 806.87 in 2030. The carbon emissions of fossil energy will rise by 3.01 times from 615.15 billion tons in 2007 to 1906.07 billion tons in 2030. However, the energy consumption intensity per unit of GDP, and carbon emissions intensity per unit of GDP gradually decline. The energy consumption intensity per unit of GDP will reduce form 0.9983 tons standard coal/104 Yuan in 2007 to 0.61933 tons standard coal/104 Yuan in 2030. The carbon emissions intensity per unit of GDP will reduce form 2.3122 tons/104 Yuan in 2007 to 1.4631 tons/104 Yuan in 2030. In a word, although the energy consumption intensity and carbon emissions intensity decrease significantly, the total energy consumption continues growing. Large amounts of carbon emissions, caused by energy consumption, will bring great environmental pressure.
Table 6 reveals China’s total primary energy consumption and its composition under the benchmark scenario. China’s primary energy consumption continues to increase with the increase of GDP. But the structure of primary energy consumption has been improved apparently. The proportion of coal in China’s total primary energy consumption will reduce from 69.50% in 2007 to 58.17% in 2030. The proportion of natural gas, hydropower, nuclear power, and wind power in China’s total primary energy consumption will go up significantly. The proportion of natural gas will increase from 3.50% in 2007 to 7.03% in 2030, and the proportion of hydropower, nuclear power, and wind power will increase from 7.30% in 2007 to 12.69% in 2030. The proportion of petroleum in China’s total primary energy consumption will rise slightly.
Under the benchmark scenario, the energy consumption intensity and carbon emission intensity decrease gradually. The optimization and upgrading of industrial structure in China is a major reason for gradual decline of energy consumption intensity. Table 7 shows the development characteristics of China’s GDP and its composition under the benchmark scenario. From the simulation, we can see the proportion of China’s first industry in GDP will obviously reduce with a distinct increase for the proportion of China’s third industry from 38.88% in 2007 to 50.57% in 2030. For the proportion of the second industry with high-energy-consumption in GDP, it gradually drops from 50.35% in 2007 to 44.81% in 2030. Therefore, the energy consumption intensity per unit of GDP in China will gradually reduce due to the optimization of the industrial structure. Apart from this, the other reason is, during the simulation period, with the reduction of the output proportion of the second industry, the proportion of the output of capital goods sectors in the total output of the second industry will be unchanged or slightly higher because of the increased demand. As the energy industry being important sectors of the second industry, the proportion of its output in the total output will reduce gradually. Due to the relatively reduced supply, the cost of the energy input will, relatively, go up in the production process. Therefore, enterprises will increasingly improve the efficiency of energy inputs.
Table 6. China’s total primary energy consumption and its composition (Benchmark scenario).
Table 6. China’s total primary energy consumption and its composition (Benchmark scenario).
YearTotal energy consumptionThe proportion in total primary energies’ consumption
104 tons standard coalCoalPetroleumNatural gasHydro power, nuclear power, and wind power
2007265,583.0069.50%19.70%3.50%7.30%
2008284,167.4169.18%19.75%3.57%7.50%
2009304,393.7668.82%19.81%3.65%7.71%
2010326,039.2168.44%19.88%3.74%7.95%
2011347,990.1168.01%19.99%3.84%8.16%
2012370,806.3967.56%20.10%3.96%8.38%
2013394,372.0767.09%20.22%4.08%8.61%
2014418,581.2366.61%20.34%4.22%8.84%
2015443,339.8166.11%20.45%4.37%9.07%
2016468,451.9865.63%20.58%4.49%9.30%
2017493,936.9265.14%20.70%4.62%9.54%
2018519,737.1964.65%20.82%4.76%9.77%
2019545,808.6064.16%20.93%4.91%10.01%
2020572,119.5063.66%21.04%5.06%10.24%
2021596,432.4263.11%21.17%5.23%10.50%
2022620,529.7562.56%21.30%5.40%10.75%
2023644,412.3062.01%21.42%5.58%11.00%
2024668,090.3161.45%21.54%5.77%11.24%
2025691,582.0760.90%21.65%5.96%11.49%
2026714,867.8360.36%21.75%6.16%11.73%
2027738,002.1759.81%21.85%6.37%11.98%
2028761,019.9959.26%21.94%6.58%12.22%
2029783,961.0158.72%22.03%6.80%12.45%
2030806,869.0158.17%22.12%7.03%12.69%
During the simulation period, the carbon emissions intensity decreases gradually. The main reasons are listed as follows: (1) the energy efficiency gradually increases; (2) the structure of primary energy consumption is gradually optimized with the decline of the proportion of coal in China’s total primary energy consumption and the increase of the proportion of clean power; and (3) the industrial structure is optimized and upgraded.
Generally speaking, under the benchmark scenario, China will keep a relatively high growth rate in economy, but the growth rate will slow down. The energy consumption structure and industrial structure will be optimized step by step. Through the energy consumption intensity per unit of GDP and carbon emissions intensity per unit of GDP decrease, total energy consumption will increase, and total CO2 emissions caused by a large amount of energy consumption will pose huge pressure on the environment in the future. The situation of energy-saving and emission-reduction will be grim.
Table 7. Analysis of GDP and its composition (Benchmark scenario).
Table 7. Analysis of GDP and its composition (Benchmark scenario).
YearGDPThe proportion of three industries
109 YuanThe primary industryThe secondary industryThe tertiary industry
2007266,043.8110.77%50.35%38.88%
2008291,784.5610.36%50.30%39.34%
2009319,534.139.95%50.23%39.82%
2010348,977.029.56%50.15%40.30%
2011378,873.579.11%50.08%40.81%
2012410,927.868.69%49.98%41.33%
2013445,106.898.30%49.87%41.83%
2014481,380.727.93%49.74%42.33%
2015519,724.507.59%49.59%42.82%
2016560,095.267.28%49.42%43.30%
2017602,500.846.99%49.24%43.77%
2018646,938.826.72%49.04%44.24%
2019693,416.106.48%48.83%44.69%
2020741,949.056.25%48.61%45.14%
2021790,685.526.05%48.26%45.69%
2022841,039.575.87%47.90%46.23%
2023893,030.585.71%47.52%46.77%
2024946,688.135.55%47.14%47.31%
20251,002,051.625.41%46.74%47.85%
20261,058,592.065.23%46.37%48.40%
20271,116,874.215.07%45.99%48.94%
20281,176,958.194.91%45.60%49.49%
20291,238,913.424.76%45.21%50.03%
20301,302,818.494.63%44.81%50.57%

6. Simulation Analysis of Carbon Tax Policy

According to simulation analysis under the benchmark scenario, with China’s economic growth, energy consumption and carbon emissions will continue to increase and the situation of energy-saving and emission-reduction will be very serious in future. The carbon tax policy can be an effective tool to address climate changes, energy-saving, and emission-reduction. Therefore, we will analyze how the carbon tax and technical progress impact the energy consumption and carbon emissions in China. Three assumptions are adopted in the following scenarios.
Carbon tax scenario I: It is assumed that the carbon tax is implemented as of 2016. The annual carbon dioxide emissions will be reduced by 10% than under the benchmark scenario.
Carbon tax scenario II: It is assumed that the carbon tax is implemented as of 2016. The annual carbon dioxide emissions will be reduced by 10% than under the benchmark scenario. The enterprise income tax will be reduced accordingly, and the annual government revenue during the simulation period will be consistent with that in the benchmark scenario.
Table 8. The analysis of GDP, energy consumption and carbon emission intensity (Scenario I).
Table 8. The analysis of GDP, energy consumption and carbon emission intensity (Scenario I).
YearGDPPercentage change of GDPTotal energy consumptionPercentage of change total energy consumptionEnergy consumption intensityPercentage change of energy consumption intensityCarbon emissions intensityPercentage change of carbon emissions intensity
109 Yuan104 tons standard coalton standard coal/104 Yuantons/104 Yuan
2016559,532.02−0.1006%428,062.91−8.62%0.7650−8.53%1.7814−9.08%
2017601,896.78−0.1003%451,532.57−8.58%0.7502−8.49%1.7502−8.93%
2018646,293.14−0.0998%475,313.45−8.55%0.7354−8.46%1.7192−8.79%
2019692,726.81−0.0994%499,365.23−8.51%0.7209−8.41%1.6884−8.64%
2020741,212.83−0.0992%523,659.03−8.47%0.7065−8.38%1.6580−8.49%
2021789,908.34−0.0983%546,172.81−8.43%0.6914−8.33%1.6252−8.34%
2022840,217.98−0.0977%568,512.56−8.38%0.6766−8.29%1.5929−8.20%
2023892,159.56−0.0975%590,678.54−8.34%0.6621−8.25%1.5610−8.06%
2024945,761.04−0.0979%612,679.65−8.29%0.6478−8.20%1.5296−7.93%
20251,001,060.16−0.0989%634,532.26−8.25%0.6339−8.16%1.4988−7.80%
20261,057,523.87−0.1009%656,218.28−8.20%0.6205−8.11%1.4699−7.64%
20271,115,717.24−0.1036%677,786.79−8.16%0.6075−8.07%1.4417−7.48%
20281,175,698.62−0.1070%699,269.55−8.11%0.5948−8.02%1.4140−7.31%
20291,237,535.64−0.1112%720,702.76−8.07%0.5824−7.97%1.3870−7.16%
20301,301,305.14−0.1162%742,126.52−8.02%0.5703−7.91%1.3605−7.00%
Carbon tax scenario III: It is assumed that the carbon tax policy is implemented as of 2016. The annual carbon dioxide emissions will be reduced by 10% than under the benchmark scenario. Technology of clean power is promoted, and total factor productivity will be one time higher than that under the benchmark scenario.
Thus, we analyze the influence of different policy scenarios on GDP, energy consumption, energy consumption structure, carbon emissions, and carbon emissions intensity.
Carbon tax scenario I: Due to the levy on carbon tax, GDP drops slightly from that in the benchmark scenario (see Table 8). Specifically, due to the carbon tax, the input cost of fossil energy fuels increases, and the energy input of sectors reduces, leading to the reduction of the output and GDP to a certain extent. In another aspect, GDP will be equal to the final demand, because the increased prices of fossil energy fuels will cause the increase of the demand prices of the goods, resulting in the decrease of final demand. Due to the carbon tax, the cost of fossil energy fuels will rise. As a consequence, the total energy consumption decreases significantly by 8% of that under the benchmark scenario. For the total primary energy consumption and its composition (see Table 9), coal carbon emission coefficient is big, thus, the carbon tax has an obvious influence on coal consumption, decreasing the proportion of coal in the total energy consumption significantly compared with under the benchmark scenario. However, the proportions of oil and natural gas increase slightly, and the proportion of clean power increases significantly, thus, the primary energy consumption structure is optimized to some extent. Accordingly, energy consumption intensity decreases about 8% than that under the benchmark scenario. Due to the decline of the total energy consumption and the coal proportion in primary energy structure, carbon emissions intensity reduces about 7%–9% above that in the benchmark scenario.
Table 9. The total primary energy consumption and its composition (scenario I).
Table 9. The total primary energy consumption and its composition (scenario I).
YearTotal energy consumptionThe proportion in total primary energies’ consumption
104 tons standard coalCoalPetroleumNatural gasHydro power, nuclear power, and wind power
2016428,062.9162.52%22.34%4.76%10.38%
2017451,532.5762.01%22.46%4.89%10.64%
2018475,313.4561.51%22.57%5.03%10.89%
2019499,365.2361.00%22.68%5.18%11.15%
2020523,659.0360.50%22.78%5.33%11.40%
2021546,172.8159.93%22.91%5.49%11.67%
2022568,512.5659.37%23.03%5.66%11.94%
2023590,678.5458.81%23.14%5.84%12.21%
2024612,679.6558.25%23.25%6.02%12.48%
2025634,532.2657.69%23.36%6.21%12.74%
2026656,218.2857.14%23.45%6.41%13.00%
2027677,786.7956.59%23.54%6.61%13.26%
2028699,269.5556.05%23.62%6.82%13.52%
2029720,702.7655.50%23.70%7.03%13.77%
2030742,126.5254.95%23.78%7.25%14.02%
Table 10. The analysis of GDP, energy consumption and carbon emission intensity (Scenario II).
Table 10. The analysis of GDP, energy consumption and carbon emission intensity (Scenario II).
YearGDPPercentage change of GDPTotal energy consumptionTotal energy consumptionEnergy consumption intensityPercentage change of energy consumption intensityCarbon emissions intensityPercentage change of carbon emissions intensity
109 Yuan104 tons standard coalton standard coal/104 Yuantons/104 Yuan
2016576,714.992.97%430,573.33−8.09%0.7466−10.74%1.7309−11.66%
2017621,837.283.21%454,412.63−8.00%0.7308−10.86%1.6968−11.71%
2018668,995.263.41%478,559.94−7.92%0.7153−10.96%1.6637−11.73%
2019718,216.273.58%502,975.72−7.85%0.7003−11.03%1.6315−11.72%
2020769,148.523.67%527,602.03−7.78%0.6860−11.04%1.6008−11.65%
2021820,314.533.75%550,428.38−7.71%0.6710−11.04%1.5681−11.56%
2022872,682.853.76%573,046.91−7.65%0.6566−11.00%1.5368−11.43%
2023926,439.403.74%595,459.85−7.60%0.6427−10.93%1.5064−11.28%
2024981,437.003.67%617,670.27−7.55%0.6294−10.82%1.4771−11.09%
20251,038,455.603.63%639,712.61−7.50%0.6160−10.75%1.4480−10.93%
20261,097,026.703.63%661,586.46−7.45%0.6031−10.70%1.4202−10.76%
20271,156,619.503.56%683,339.10−7.41%0.5908−10.59%1.3938−10.55%
20281,217,649.903.46%704,981.02−7.36%0.5790−10.46%1.3684−10.31%
20291,280,167.403.33%726,545.53−7.32%0.5675−10.31%1.3437−10.05%
20301,344,204.803.18%748,071.28−7.29%0.5565−10.14%1.3199−9.78%
Carbon tax scenario II: Compared with the benchmark scenario, GDP rises to a certain degree (see Table 10). The reason is that although the carbon tax results in the improvement of production cost and the slight decrease of GDP, the carbon tax also leads to the reduction of enterprise income tax, which is then directly used for investment, directly boosting economy growth. Therefore, GDP even rises more than 3% under the benchmark scenario rather than decrease. At the same time, the total energy consumption decreases by 7%–8% than under the benchmark scenario. The energy consumption structures (see Table 11) are obviously optimized, and the changes are consistent with those in scenario I. Compared with the benchmark scenario, the energy consumption intensity decreases nearly 10%–11%. Due to the growth of GDP, the energy consumption intensity drops more dramatically than in scenario I. The carbon emissions intensity also decreases significantly, compared with under the benchmark scenario. Generally speaking, reducing the enterprise income tax, when levying the carbon tax, will not only facilitate energy-saving and emission-reduction, but also bring certain growth of the GDP.
Table 11. The total primary energy consumption and its composition (scenario II).
Table 11. The total primary energy consumption and its composition (scenario II).
YearTotal energy consumptionThe proportion in total primary energies’ consumption
104 tons standard coalCoalPetroleumNatural gasHydro power, nuclear power, and wind power
2016430,573.3361.23%22.91%4.90%10.97%
2017454,412.6360.64%23.06%5.03%11.26%
2018478,559.9460.07%23.21%5.18%11.54%
2019502,975.7259.51%23.34%5.33%11.82%
2020527,602.0358.98%23.46%5.48%12.08%
2021550,428.3858.38%23.60%5.65%12.37%
2022573,046.9157.82%23.72%5.82%12.64%
2023595,459.8557.26%23.84%6.00%12.90%
2024617,670.2756.73%23.94%6.18%13.15%
2025639,712.6156.19%24.03%6.37%13.41%
2026661,586.4655.65%24.12%6.56%13.68%
2027683,339.1055.12%24.20%6.76%13.92%
2028704,981.0254.61%24.27%6.96%14.16%
2029726,545.5354.11%24.33%7.17%14.39%
2030748,071.2853.61%24.38%7.39%14.62%
Table 12. The analysis of GDP, energy consumption and carbon emission intensity (Scenario III).
Table 12. The analysis of GDP, energy consumption and carbon emission intensity (Scenario III).
YearGDPPercentage change of GDPTotal energy consumptionPercentage change of total energy consumptionEnergy consumption intensityPercentage change of energy consumption intensityCarbon emissions intensityPercentage change of carbon emissions intensity
109 Yuan104 tons standard coalton standard coal/104 Yuantons/104 Yuan
2016559,655.80−0.08%428,901.61−8.44%0.7664−8.37%1.7811−9.10%
2017602,166.88−0.06%453,356.92−8.22%0.7529−8.16%1.7495−8.97%
2018646,732.90−0.03%478,281.46−7.98%0.7395−7.95%1.7182−8.84%
2019693,360.41−0.01%503,645.91−7.72%0.7264−7.71%1.6871−8.71%
2020742,065.340.02%529,432.47−7.46%0.7135−7.48%1.6564−8.58%
2021791,003.220.04%553,621.21−7.18%0.6999−7.21%1.6234−8.45%
2022841,580.260.06%577,830.18−6.88%0.6866−6.94%1.5908−8.32%
2023893,815.020.09%602,068.79−6.57%0.6736−6.65%1.5587−8.20%
2024947,736.480.11%626,355.50−6.25%0.6609−6.35%1.5272−8.08%
20251,003,383.660.13%650,716.71−5.91%0.6485−6.04%1.4962−7.96%
20261,060,225.750.15%675,141.16−5.56%0.6368−5.70%1.4672−7.81%
20271,118,828.930.18%699,691.21−5.19%0.6254−5.36%1.4388−7.66%
20281,179,253.820.20%724,410.48−4.81%0.6143−5.00%1.4110−7.51%
20291,241,570.720.21%749,348.09−4.42%0.6035−4.62%1.3838−7.37%
20301,305,859.570.23%774,558.14−4.00%0.5931−4.22%1.3573−7.22%
Carbon tax scenario III: When the carbon tax is levied and energy technology of clean power is improved, GDP grows slightly compared with that under the benchmark scenario, and the growth rate rises gradually (see Table 12). We explain this as, although the costs of fossil energy fuels will rise, and enterprises’ energy inputs and outputs will fall due to carbon tax, the technology of clean power will be improved, and output of clean energy will increase, which is helpful for lowering the energy prices and promoting the use of clean power, therefore, GDP grows slightly compared with that under benchmark scenario, and the growth rate rises gradually. Table 13 analyzes the total primary energy consumption and its composition, the proportion of coal in the primary energy consumption will drop to 52.58% by 2030, while the proportion of hydro power, nuclear power, and wind power will rise to 17.77% and the proportions of petroleum and natural gas are lower than those under the benchmark scenario. At the same time, compared with the benchmark scenario, the total energy consumption reduces slightly but in a decreased reduction rate, so does the trend of energy consumption intensity. In addition, due to the optimization of energy consumption structure, the carbon emissions intensity decreases more than 7%–9% each year compared with the benchmark scenario. Therefore, the improvement of clean power technology is significant to the optimization of energy consumption structure and carbon emission reductions. However, the cost reduction of the fossil energy fuels caused by the improvement of clean power technology partly improves the total energy demand.
Table 13. The total primary energy consumption and its composition (scenario III).
Table 13. The total primary energy consumption and its composition (scenario III).
YearTotal energy consumptionThe proportion in total primary energies’ consumption
104 tons standard coalCoalPetroleumNatural gasHydro power, nuclear power, and wind power
2016428,901.6162.39%22.29%4.75%10.56%
2017453,356.9261.76%22.35%4.87%11.01%
2018478,281.4661.12%22.41%5.00%11.47%
2019503,645.9160.47%22.46%5.13%11.94%
2020529,432.4759.82%22.50%5.27%12.41%
2021553,621.2159.11%22.56%5.42%12.91%
2022577,830.1858.39%22.61%5.58%13.43%
2023602,068.7957.67%22.65%5.74%13.94%
2024626,355.5056.94%22.68%5.90%14.47%
2025650,716.7156.22%22.71%6.07%15.00%
2026675,141.1655.49%22.72%6.24%15.54%
2027699,691.2154.77%22.72%6.42%16.09%
2028724,410.4854.04%22.71%6.60%16.64%
2029749,348.0953.31%22.70%6.79%17.20%
2030774,558.1452.58%22.68%6.97%17.77%

7. Conclusions and Policy Suggestions

Overall, under the benchmark scenario, China will continue a relatively high growth rate in the economy, but the growth rate will slow down. Although the energy consumption intensity per unit of GDP and carbon emissions intensity per unit of GDP continually decrease, energy consumption structure and the industrial structure will be gradually optimized, total energy consumption will rise with economic growth, the carbon dioxide emissions will still be large, and the situation of energy-saving and emission-reduction will be grim. The carbon tax is vital for energy-saving, emission-reduction, and energy consumption structure optimization. Meanwhile, the effect of carbon tax on GDP is not great. If enterprise income tax can be reduced, while levying carbon tax, not only can we reduce energy consumption and carbon emissions, but also increase the GDP to a certain degree. Furthermore, the improvement of clean power technology is very important for optimizing energy consumption structure and reducing carbon emission when the carbon tax is implemented, but this will partly offset the reduction of energy consumption. Therefore, we make the following suggestions for future economic development in China.
(1)
It is suggested to strengthen the optimization and adjustment of industrial structure. We should suppress excessive growth of the high energy demand and high emission industries, and promote the optimization and upgrading of traditional industries by means of new technologies and advanced applicable technologies. In the meantime, development of service industries and strategic new industries should be promoted productive service industries and life service industries should be accelerated.
(2)
We propose to optimize the production and consumption structure of energies. We should improve the efficiency of coal processing and conversion, and the utilization level of clean energy. It is necessary to establish large-scale coal and electricitybases, and develop thermal power efficiently and cleanly. Actively develop a new coal chemical industry, relying on technological progress. Great importance should be attached to the development of renewable energy with the utilization of wind energy, solar energy, and biomass energy as the focus, and hydropower should also be developed actively and orderly. At the same time, we should actively explore and develop the coal-bed methane and shale gas.
(3)
It is urgent to implement the carbon tax policy and other effective policies for energy-saving and emission-reduction. An effective carbon tax policy for reducing carbon emissions needs to be carried out, and the mode of levying a carbon tax, and how to recycle the carbon tax, needs to be studied. In order to reduce energy consumption and carbon emissions, it is also required to improve laws and regulations, economic policies, and administrative measures.

Acknowledgments

The authors gratefully acknowledge the financial support from the National Science Foundation of China (Grant NO. 71173075), Program for New Century Excellent Talents in University (NCET-12-0850) and China Postdoctoral Science Foundation (Grant NO. 2012M520222). We would also like to thank the editors and anonymous reviewers.

Author Contributions

Zhengquan Guo and Yuhua Zheng established the CGE model and made the analysis results together. Yuanying Chi completed the papers in English. Xingping Zhang gave many good research advices.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Akkemik, K.A.; Oguz, F. Regulation, efficiency and equilibrium: A general equilibrium analysis of liberalization in the Turkish electricity market. Energy 2011, 36, 3282–3292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Xie, J.; Saltzman, S. Environmental policy analysis: An environmental computable general-equilibrium approach for developing countries. J. Policy Model. 2000, 22, 453–489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Fraser, I.; Waschik, R. The double dividend hypothesis in a CGE model: Specific factors and the carbon base. Energy Econ. 2013, 39, 283–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Caron, J. Estimating carbon leakage and the efficiency of border adjustments in general equilibrium—Does sectoral aggregation matter? Energy Econ. 2012, 34, S111–S126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Boccanfuso, D.; Savard, L.; Estache, A. The distributional impact of developed countries’ climate change policies on senegal: A macro-micro CGE application. Sustainability 2013, 5, 2727–2750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Vennemo, H. A dynamic applied general equilibrium model with environmental feedbacks. Econ. Model. 1997, 14, 99–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Wendner, R. An applied dynamic general equilibrium model of environmental tax reforms and pension policy. J. Policy Model. 2001, 21, 25–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Muto, S.; Morisugi, H.; Ueda, T. Measuring Market Damage of Automobile Related Carbon Tax by Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model. In Proceedings of the 2003 ERSA Conference, Jyväskylä, Finland, 27–30 August 2003; European Regional Science Association: Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium, 2003. No.ersa03p257. [Google Scholar]
  9. Fukiharu, T. The global warming, sustainability and environmental tax: A dynamic general equilibrium model. Environ. Softw. Syst. Framew. Environ. 2011, 359, 566–573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Matsumoto, K. Economic analysis of CO2 emission abatement applying a dynamic CGE model with endogenous technological change: Impacts of the time horizon. J. Environ. Sci. Eng. 2011, 5, 1454–1463. [Google Scholar]
  11. O’Ryan, R.; de Miguel, C.J.; Miller, S.; Pereira, M. The socioeconomic and environmental effects of free trade agreements: A dynamic CGE analysis for Chile. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2011, 16, 305–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Hermeling, C.; Loschel, A.; Mennel, T. A new robustness analysis for climate policy evaluations: A CGE application for the EU 2020 targets. Energy Policy 2013, 55, 27–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. He, Y.X.; Zhang, S.L.; Yang, L.Y.; Wang, Y.J.; Wang, J. Economic analysis of coal price–electricity price adjustment in China based on the CGE model. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 6629–6637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Lin, B.Q.; Jiang, Z.J. Estimates of energy subsidies in China and impact of energy subsidy reform. Energy Econ. 2011, 33, 273–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Ren, S.; Yuan, Y.; Wang, H.; Ji, F. Research on the influence of sulfur tax on the industrial structure of liaoning province under CGE model. Energy Procedia 2011, 5, 2405–2409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. He, Y.X.; Yang, L.F.; He, H.Y.; Luo, T.; Wang, Y.J. Electricity demand price elasticity in China based on computable general equilibrium model analysis. Energy 2011, 36, 1115–1123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Lu, C.Y.; Zhang, X.L.; He, J.K. A CGE analysis to study the impacts of energy investment on economic growth and carbon dioxide emission: A case of Shanxi Province in western China. Energy 2010, 35, 4319–4327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Zhang, Z.K.; Guo, J.E.; Qian, D.; Xue, Y.; Cai, L.P. Effects and mechanism of influence of China’s resource tax reform: A regional perspective. Energy Econ. 2013, 36, 676–685. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Zhang, Z.X. Macroeconomic Effects of CO2 Emission Limits: A Computable General Equilibrium Analysis for China; 1996 Mansholt Working Papers; Wageningen University: Wageningen, The Netherlands, 1996; No. 01–96. [Google Scholar]
  20. Zhang, Z.X. Macroeconomic effects of CO2 emission limits: A computable general equilibrium analysis for China. J. Policy Model. 1998, 20, 213–250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Garbaccio, R.F.; Ho, M.S.; Jorgenson, D.W. Controlling carbon emissions in China. Environ. Dev. Econ. 1999, 4, 493–518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Liang, Q.M.; Fan, Y.; Wei, Y.M. Carbon taxation policy in China: How to protect energy- and trade-intensive sectors? J. Policy Model. 2007, 29, 311–333. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Lu, C.Y.; Tong, Q.; Liu, X.M. The impacts of carbon tax and complementary policies on Chinese economy. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 7278–7285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Tang, L.; Bao, Q.; Zhang, Z.X.; Wang, S.Y. Carbon-based Border Tax Adjustments and China’s International Trade: Analysis Based on a Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model; 2013 Working Papers; Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei: Milan, Italy, 2013; Volume 17. [Google Scholar]
  25. Burniaux, J.-M.; Martin, J.P.; Nicoletti, G.; Martins, J.O. GREEN a Multi-Sector, Multi-Region General Equilibrium Model for Quantifying the Costs of Curbing CO2 Emissions: A Technical Manual; 1992 OECD Economics Department Working Papers; IDEAS: Paris, France, 1992; No. 116. [Google Scholar]
  26. Huang, Y.N.; Zhang, W.; Wang, X.J. An econometric estimation and selection on the production function in an environmental CGE model. ACTA Sci. Circumst. 2003, 23, 350–354. [Google Scholar]
  27. Wu, Y.J.; Xuan, X.W. The Economic Theory of Environmental Tax and Its Application in China; Economic Science Press: Beijing, China, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  28. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. The 2006 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories. Available online: http://www.ipcc-nggip.iges.or.jp/public/2006gl/index.html (accessed on 19 November 2013).
  29. National Bureau of Statistics PR China. China Statistical Yearbook 2010; China Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 2010.
  30. National Bureau of Statistics PR China. China Statistical Yearbook 1999; China Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 1999.
  31. National Bureau of Statistics PR China. China Energy Statistical Yearbook 2008; China Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 2008.
  32. He, J.H.; Shen, K.T.; Xu, S.L. CGE model of the carbon tax and carbon dioxide emission reduction. Quant. Tech. Econ. 2002, 10, 39–47. [Google Scholar]
  33. Wang, C. Climate Change Policy Simulation and Uncertainty Analysis: A Dynamic CGE Model of China. Ph.D. Thesis, Tsinghua University, Beijing, China, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  34. Xuan, X.W. Analysis the Effect of Sulfur-Tax on the CHINESE Economy Based on CGE Model. Ph.D. Thesis, Peking University, Beijing, China, 1998. [Google Scholar]
  35. Tan, X.D. Modeling and Application of Electric Power Computable General Equilibrium Model. Ph.D. Thesis, North China Electric Power University, Beijing, China, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  36. Wang, D.W. Changes in the relationship between labor supply and labor demand and China’s economic growth in the low fertility era. Chin. J. Popul. Sci. 2007, 1, 44–52. [Google Scholar]
  37. Wang, J.Y.; Lin, L.L. Analysis on labor force participation rate and future labor supply in China. Popul. J. 2006, 4, 19–24. [Google Scholar]
  38. Wang, G.X. Study on the transfer of rural surplus labor in China-the quantity estimate of rural surplus labor and the forecast of its transfer scale. J. Shanxi Univ. 2007, 30, 19–24. [Google Scholar]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Chi, Y.; Guo, Z.; Zheng, Y.; Zhang, X. Scenarios Analysis of the Energies’ Consumption and Carbon Emissions in China Based on a Dynamic CGE Model. Sustainability 2014, 6, 487-512. https://doi.org/10.3390/su6020487

AMA Style

Chi Y, Guo Z, Zheng Y, Zhang X. Scenarios Analysis of the Energies’ Consumption and Carbon Emissions in China Based on a Dynamic CGE Model. Sustainability. 2014; 6(2):487-512. https://doi.org/10.3390/su6020487

Chicago/Turabian Style

Chi, Yuanying, Zhengquan Guo, Yuhua Zheng, and Xingping Zhang. 2014. "Scenarios Analysis of the Energies’ Consumption and Carbon Emissions in China Based on a Dynamic CGE Model" Sustainability 6, no. 2: 487-512. https://doi.org/10.3390/su6020487

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop